Housing Policy in Developing Countries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Housing Policy in Developing Countries 1 HOUSING POLICY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES THE IMPORTANCE OF THE INFORMAL ECONOMY Richard Arnott* January 21, 2008 Abstract: All countries have a formal economy and an informal economy. But, on average, in developing countries the relative size of the informal sector is considerably larger than in developed countries. This paper argues that this has important implications for housing policy in developing countries. That most poor households derive their income from informal employment effectively precludes income-contingent transfers as a method of redistribution. Also, holding fixed real economic activity, the larger is the relative size of the informal sector, the lower is fiscal capacity, and the more distortionary is government provision of a given level of goods and services, which restricts the desirable scale and scope of government policy. For the same reasons, housing policies that have proven successful in developed countries may not be successful when employed in developing countries. Please do not cite or quote without the permission of the author. *Department of Economics University of California, Riverside Riverside, CA 92521 951-827-1581 [email protected] 2 Housing Policy in Developing Countries The Importance of the Informal Economy1 1. Introduction In the foreword to The Challenge of Slums (2003), published by the United Nations Settlements Programme, Kofi Annan wrote: Almost 1 billion, or 32 percent of the world’s urban population, live in slums, the majority of them in the developing world. Moreover, the locus of global poverty is moving to the cities, a process now recognized as the ‘urbanization of poverty’. Without concerted action on the part of municipal authorities, national governments, civil society actors and the international community, the number of slum dwellers is likely to increase in most developing countries. And if no serious action is taken, the number of slum dwellers worldwide is projected to rise over the next 30 years to 2 billion. While one may dispute the numbers and question the use of the word slum, with its socio-pathological connotations, there is no doubt of the magnitude of the housing problems in developing countries. The ideal would be massive redistribution from the over-consuming haves to the have-nots, eliminating poverty. But that is not about to happen. Given their scarce resources, what policies should developing countries employ to best deal with their housing problems, and, ruling out massive redistribution from rich to poor countries, what can the international community do to help? Though the pace of economic research on housing in developing countries has increased rapidly in recent years2, there is still very little empirical work analyzing housing policy 1 I would like to thank Patricia Annez for very helpful comments on an earlier draft. In the past I have criticized “armchair development economists”. With this essay I join their ranks. 3 in developing countries that is persuasive by modern standards in applied econometrics. Either the data are unreliable or insufficiently rich, or the empirical analysis suffers from obvious pitfalls. Case studies are suggestive but not conclusive. The housing policy experience of developed countries is considerably better documented and analyzed. Apart from adjustments that need to be made to reflect the income differences between the two classes of countries, can the received wisdom in developed countries on what constitutes good housing policy be applied to developing countries? Would housing policies that have been successful in developed countries necessarily be successful when applied to developing countries? This paper will argue that the large size of the informal sector relative to the economy in developing countries, as well as the high proportion of housing that is informal, substantially alter the housing policy design problem, so that policies that have succeeded in developing countries may not work well in developing countries. Table 1, which reproduces part of Table 6.1 of United Nations Habitat (2003), presents data on the extent of informal employment3 by City Development Index (CDI) quintile. In the two lowest quintiles about 50% of workers are informally employed, which is 2 See Buckley and Kalarickal (2005) for an enlightening and informed review. 3 “Informal employment” is not precisely defined. The imprecise definition is that an informal employee is “an employee in an unregistered enterprise”. A note to Table 6.1 states: “There is no clear distinction between informally employed and unemployed, which relates to actively seeking work in the formal sector. Quite often, officially unemployed people will work in the informal sector.” The data were collected by the Housing Indicators Program, which was initiated by Stephen Mayo and Shlomo Angel at the World Bank, and has been continued by the World Bank and UN-Habitat. The data were collected for one of the largest cities in each of the 57 countries in the sample. 4 more than double that for the two highest quintiles. In developing countries, the bulk of the poor work in the informal sector. Table 1: GNP per capita and informal employment by City Development Index, 1998 CDI quintile 1 2 3 4 5 GNP per 606 1571 2087 3230 11822 capita, US$ Informal 49 51 40 26 19 empl., % Informal employment is one aspect of the informal economy. Informal housing is another. Angel (2000) defines unauthorized housing to be housing that is not in compliance with current regulations concerning land ownership, land use and zoning, [or] building construction, and squatter housing to be housing that is currently occupying land illegally4. This paper will use the term informal housing as synonymous with Angel’s definition of unauthorized housing. Table 2, which reproduces part of Table 23.2 of Angel (2000), presents data related to housing tenure type for four sets of countries, grouped by income. The most striking result in the table is that in 1990 about two-thirds of housing units in low-income countries were unauthorized, while essentially none in high-income countries were. 4 To this definition of squatter housing, Angel adds the following footnote: “This definition fail[s] to include structures occupied illegally by squatters. Squatter settlements that are recognized by authorities as permanent settlements and that are provided with documentation to this effect have been excluded from the definition.” 5 Table 2: Rates of owner-occupancy, unauthorized housing, and squatter housing by country income group, 1990 Country type Low-income Low-mid-inc Upp-mid-inc High-income Owner 33 59 57 59 occupancy, % Unauthorized 64 27 9 0 housing, % Squatter 17 16 4 0 housing, % The main theme of this paper is that the larger relative size of the informal economy in developing countries imposes important constraints on government policy that are not present in developed countries. These constraints significantly influence the form of sound housing policy in developing countries and undermine the effectiveness of many housing policies that have been successful in developed countries. The gist of the argument runs as follows: 1. Since the bulk of the poor in developing countries work in the informal sector, government cannot accurately measure their incomes. This severely compromises the effectiveness of broad income-related transfer programs and more generally limits the scope for redistribution. 2. At least in low-income countries, most households, and probably therefore the bulk of the most needy households, live in unauthorized housing. Since governments are reluctant to subsidize unauthorized housing, their housing programs, with the exception of public housing, are biased towards authorized housing and therefore against the neediest households. Furthermore, the inability to measure household incomes accurately effectively precludes broad housing assistance programs that are geared to income. 6 3. Holding constant the real income of an economy, the larger is the informal sector, the lower is its fiscal capacity – the maximum amount its governments can collect in tax revenue on a sustained basis. To meet the demand for public services in the face of reduced fiscal capacity, governments in developing countries impose high tax rates on formal sector income and turn to other revenue sources that are inherently inefficient, resulting in highly distortionary fiscal systems. The diminished revenue-raising capabilities relative the size of the economy restrict the scale and scope of expenditure programs that governments can and should undertake, and encourage the use of regulation, both to direct the economy and to collect fee revenue. 4. The consensus is that redistribution in developed countries is best undertaken by the central government since doing so reduces welfare-induced migration. In developing countries, however, local governments and community organizations are better able than the central government to identify the truly needy, which argues for more decentralized redistribution. The above line of argument is static and takes the degree of informality as exogenous. Over the medium and long terms, however, the size of the informal economy relative to the formal economy, as well as the proportion of housing that is informal, are endogenous. Both firms and individuals decide whether to participate in the informal or the formal economy on the basis of perceived self-interest. All else equal, the government would like to increase the proportions of the economy and of the housing market that are formal, and recognizes that this can be achieved by making formal participation more attractive or informal participation less. This may entail some sacrifice of short-run 7 efficiency. For example, in the short run the government would like to regularize informal housing not only to collect more in tax revenue and to extend its control over the economy, but also to facilitate public service provision to the poor. Doing so however encourages new unauthorized settlements, which conflicts with its goal of increasing the housing sector’s degree of formality. One can pose this tradeoff as a conflict between short-run and long-run objectives.
Recommended publications
  • UN-HABITAT Housing Unit - Housing and Slum Upgrading Branch, UN-Habitat, Nairobi, Kenya
    DRAFT Suggestions and comments received by UN-HABITAT Housing Unit - Housing and Slum Upgrading Branch, UN-Habitat, Nairobi, Kenya 1 DRAFT Guidelines for the implementation of the right to adequate housing Special Rapporteur on the right to adequate housing, Ms. Leilani Farha Draft for Consultation Deadline for written comments: 18 November 2019 Table of Contents I. Introduction .................................................................................................................................... 3 Deleted: 2 II. Guidelines for the implementation of the right to adequate housing ........................................... 5 Deleted: 4 Guideline No. 1 ................................................................................................................................... 5 Deleted: 4 Recognize the right to housing as a fundamental human right in national law and practice ........ 5 Deleted: 4 Guideline No. 2 ................................................................................................................................... 7 Deleted: 5 Design, implement and regularly monitor comprehensive strategies for the realization of the right to housing ............................................................................................................................... 7 Deleted: 5 Guideline No. 3 ................................................................................................................................... 8 Deleted: 7 Ensure the progressive realization of the right to adequate
    [Show full text]
  • Housing Policy in Developing Countries the Importance
    1 HOUSING POLICY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES THE IMPORTANCE OF THE INFORMAL ECONOMY Richard Arnott* March 9, 2008 Abstract: All countries have a formal economy and an informal economy. But, on average, in developing countries the relative size of the informal sector is considerably larger than in developed countries. This paper argues that this has important implications for housing policy in developing countries. That most poor households derive their income from informal employment effectively precludes income-contingent transfers as a method of redistribution. Also, holding fixed real economic activity, the larger is the relative size of the informal sector, the lower is fiscal capacity, and the more distortionary is government provision of a given level of goods and services, which restricts the desirable scale and scope of government policy. For the same reasons, housing policies that have proven successful in developed countries may not be successful when employed in developing countries. Please do not cite or quote without the permission of the author. *Department of Economics University of California, Riverside Riverside, CA 92521 951-827-1581 [email protected] 2 Housing Policy in Developing Countries The Importance of the Informal Economy1 1. Introduction In the foreword to The Challenge of Slums (2003), published by the United Nations Settlements Programme, Kofi Annan wrote: Almost 1 billion, or 32 percent of the world‟s urban population, live in slums, the majority of them in the developing world. Moreover, the locus of global poverty is moving to the cities, a process now recognized as the „urbanization of poverty‟. Without concerted action on the part of municipal authorities, national governments, civil society actors and the international community, the number of slum dwellers is likely to increase in most developing countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Settlements' Planning Theories
    Cyril Fegue, Int. J. Sus. Dev. Plann. Vol. 2, No. 4 (2007) 445–460 INFORMAL SETTLEMENTS’ PLANNING THEORIES AND POLICY-MAKING IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA – FROM ‘SITE’ TO ‘PEOPLE’: A CRITICAL EVALUATION OF OPERATIONS ‘MURAMBATSVINA’ AND ‘GARIKAI’ IN ZIMBABWE CYRIL FEGUE New York University Wagner, New York, USA. ABSTRACT This article explores the theoretical debates on informal settlements and presents a critical overview of the related planning strategies. Operations Murambatsvina and Garikai have been the response of the Zimbabwean government to the rapid growth of uncontrolled and spontaneous settlements in major cities. This response sparked an avalanche of criticism throughout the international community. The article’s fundamental research question is to assess whether that response was structured in accordance with the ideal and recommended plan- ning practices for informal settlements. Operations Murambatsvina and Garikai were gigantic failures; they were confi gured for humanitarian crisis. The proposal for remedial action in the long term is to take decentrali- zation, good local governance, and community participation seriously. The article suggests that the revamp of the institutional and legal framework is hereby the conditio-sine-qua-non pathway. Keywords: African context, civil society, community participation, decentralization, development administration, informal settlement planning, rapid urbanization, slum, squatter settlement, urban poor. The poor are just rational as the middle and upper-income classes in terms of their response to a situation, but the squatter shack is a rational step on the way to self-improvement. Charles Abrams Give the poor security of land and he will progressively transform the shack into a respectable house. John F.C.
    [Show full text]
  • São Paulo a Tale of Two Cities
    cities & citizens series bridging the urban divide são paulo a tale of two cities Study cities & citizens series bridging the urban divide são paulo a tale of two cities Image: Roberto Rocco - [email protected] iv cities & citizens series - bridging the urban divide Copyright © United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-HABITAT), 2010 São Paulo: A Tale of Two Cities All rights reserved UNITED NATIONS HUMAN SETTLEMENTS PROGRAMME P.O. Box 30030, GPO, Nairobi, 00100, Kenya Tel.: +254 (20) 762 3120, Fax: +254 (20) 762 4266/4267/4264/3477/4060 E-mail: [email protected] www.unhabitat.org DISCLAIMER The designations employed and the presentation of material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the United Nations concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries or regarding its economic system or degree of development. The analysis, conclusions and recommendations of this publication do not necessarily reflect the views of the United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-HABITAT), the Governing Council of UN-HABITAT or its Member States.Excerpts may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated. HS Number: HS/103/10E ISBN Number:(Volume) 978-92-1-132214-9 ISBN Number(Series): 978-92-1-132029-9 This book was prepared under the overall guidance of the Director of MRD, Oyebanji Oyeyinka and the direct coordination of Eduardo Moreno, Head of City Monitoring Branch. The book primarily uses data prepared by the São Paulo-based, Fundação Sistema Estadual de Análise de Dados (SEADE) in collaboration with UN-HABITAT under the technical coordination of Gora Mboup, Chief of the Global Urban Observatory .
    [Show full text]
  • The Right to the City in the Informal Sector: Claiming Rights Or Gaining
    The Right to the City in the ABSTRACT Informal Sector: Claiming In the developing world, the vast majority of Rights or Gaining Access urban poor have been marginalized from their in Kampala, Uganda? cities, denying them what Henri Lefebvre called the right to the city . In response to this denial, many turn to the informal sector as a means to Matthew F. Pietrus claim access to space and to the economy . How- Department of Geography ever, using interviews from citizens participat- DePaul University ing in the informal sector in Kampala, Uganda, Chicago, IL 60614 this paper argues that while the informal sec- E-mail: [email protected] tor provides access to socioeconomic benefits (which is positive), it cannot guarantee them as rights because all activity taking place within it is unprotected and therefore easily and often challenged . This essay then argues that the informal sector cannot and does not confer the right to the city . Finally, it advances that those participating in the informal sector can only achieve the right to the city if they are 1) able to claim rights to shelter and to the economy and 2) able to successfully challenge laws that infringe upon their pursuit of self- improvement . Key Words: right to the city, informality, rights, urban development INTRODUCTION Before the warm, equatorial sun peaks and dries the red dirt road, a shoe vendor lays out his blue tarp, carefully displaying an immacu- late array of used and counterfeit shoes . Con- sidering the sandstorm of dust vehicles kick up as they speed by, the shoes gleam surprisingly brightly; an obvious image of constant care .
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Housing in Cairo: Are Ashwa’Iyyat Really the Problem?
    Informal Housing in Cairo: Are Ashwa’iyyat Really the Problem? Shawn O’Donnell A map of the informal settlements of Greater Cairo Source: Sims (2003, p.5) Page 2 Informal settlements are widely viewed as a contemporary urban ‘problem’ in the Global South. Moreover, their production and proliferation, a widespread global phenomenon, has become the urban ‘problem’ of the 21st century to be solved. Few recognize informal settlements as producing housing solutions for the vast majority of urban residents in the Global South or acknowledge the economic and social contributions, as well as participation, of those who live there. Furthermore, those who live in informal settlements, areas blamed for producing social ills, are commonly viewed as marginal to mainstream society and as unproductive citizens in a modern city. Cairo is one city that has experienced tremendous urbanization in the form of informal settlements, labeled ashwa’iyyat; 1 over half of the city’s residents live in informal areas (70%).2 Similar to informal settlements in other cities, the ashwa’iyyat in Cairo are commonly viewed by the state and non‐settlement residents as a problem; in their view, these settlements produce social ills and violate the modern, cosmopolitan image they hold for Cairo. Problems are solved based on how they are framed. Employing a new perception of informal housing, which relies on particular understandings of the ‘city,’ urbanization, and what it means to be ‘modern’ and ‘cosmopolitan,’ the 1 Ashwa’iyyat is the Arabic word used in Egypt for informal housing settlements or slums. It literally means ‘random’ or ‘haphazard.’ The Egyptian government uses the terms aswha’iyyat, informal settlements/areas, and slums interchangeably, and U.N.
    [Show full text]
  • Uganda Housing Market Mapping and Value Chain Analysis
    UGANDA HOUSING MARKET MAPPING AND VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 2013 1 2 Contents ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS .............................................................................................................. 5 ACRONYMS ................................................................................................................................. 6 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ................................................................................................................ 8 1. INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................ 13 2. MARKET MAPPING METHODOLOGY ................................................................................... 15 2.1 Methodological Approach .............................................................................................. 15 2.2 The Target Population .................................................................................................... 18 3. COUNTRY CONTEXT .............................................................................................................. 20 3.1 Access to Housing ........................................................................................................... 20 3.2 The Policy Environment .................................................................................................. 21 3.3 Overview of the Land Market in Uganda ........................................................................ 23 4. HOUSING VALUE CHAIN MARKET MAPS .............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Settlers Deprivations: (A) Lack of Access to Drinking Water and (B) Sanitation Facilities; (C) Non- MIGUEL A
    Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Orum eurs0160.tex V1 - 03/05/2018 1:15 P.M. Page 1 Informal Settlers deprivations: (a) lack of access to drinking water and (b) sanitation facilities; (c) non- MIGUEL A. MARTÍNEZ durable structures; (d) overcrowded houses; Uppsala University, Sweden and (e) tenure insecurity that facilitates SONIA ROITMAN forced evictions. Slum sites seldom comply University of Queensland, Australia with planning and building regulations, and areoftensituatedingeographicallyandenvi- ronmentally hazardous areas. It is estimated “Informal settlers” is a broad concept that that“inourworld,oneineightpeoplelivein refers to individuals and groups who estab- slums” (UN-Habitat 2016, 2). Although mil- lish their principal residence in mostly urban areas and types of dwellings considered illegal lions of slum-dwellers are subject to numer- or in discord with the dominant social norms. ous violations of human rights, not all lack Informal settlers are the main producers of title deeds, fear evictions, are poor, are undoc- the city in the Global South, but they are also umentedmigrants,orareinvolvedincriminal found in the Global North. activities (Davis 2006; Neuwirth 2004). Many To settle in a territory implies an act of slum-dwellers work in the formal economy, foundation of a site for dwelling and collective run legal businesses, and pay taxes. If they life – villages and towns, originally. “Settler” are internal migrants, they can enjoy partial applies generally to all new arrivals in urban or full citizenship rights; for instance, in the agglomerations. This embodies connotations example of the hukou regime in China and ofcolonizerswhotakeoverlandpreviously war-driven displacement in Colombia. Slums held by indigenous populations, who thus may be upgraded or regularized by local k become dispossessed or displaced – some governments, and residents may be granted k native tribes in Australian and American permanency.
    [Show full text]
  • Housing and Informal Settlements
    11 Housing and Informal Settlements Coordinating Lead Authors Nathalie Jean-Baptiste (Leipzig/Dar es Salaam), Veronica Olivotto (Rotterdam) Lead Authors Emma Porio (Manila), Wilbard Kombe (Dar es Salaam), Antonia Yulo-Loyzaga (Manila) Contributing Authors Ebru Gencer (New York/Istanbul), Mattia Leone (Naples), Oswaldo Lucon (São Paulo), Mussa Natty (Dar es Salaam) This chapter should be cited as Jean-Baptiste, N., Olivotto, V., Porio, E., Kombe, W., and Yulo-Loyzaga, A. (2018). Housing and informal settlements. In Rosenzweig, C., W. Solecki, P. Romero-Lankao, S. Mehrotra, S. Dhakal, and S. Ali Ibrahim (eds.), Climate Change and Cities: Second Assessment Report of the Urban Climate Change Research Network. Cambridge University Press. New York. 399–440 399 ARC3.2 Climate Change and Cities Housing and Informal Settlements • Access to safe and secure land is a key measure for reduc- ing risk in cities. Groups that are already disadvantaged with Addressing vulnerability and exposure in the urban hous- regard to housing and land tenure are especially vulnerable ing sector is critical in informal settlements where extreme to climate change. climate events present multiple risks for millions of people. Understanding the impacts of mitigation and adaptation strat- • In informal settlements, successful adaptation depends upon egies on the housing sector will help decision-makers make addressing needs for climate related expertise and resources choices that improve quality of life and close development and at different government levels as well as risk-reducing phys- equity gaps in cities. ical infrastructure and social structures Major Findings Key Messages • The effects of climate hazards, people’s exposure and vul- City managers should work with the informal sector to improve nerability to them collectively determine the types and levels safety in relation to climate extremes.
    [Show full text]
  • Mechanism and Effect of Shantytown Reconstruction Under Balanced
    sustainability Article Mechanism and Effect of Shantytown Reconstruction under Balanced and Full Development: A Case Study of Nanjing, China Yaqi Yuan 1 and Weixuan Song 2,* 1 School of Geographic and Oceanographic Sciences, Nanjing University, Nanjing 210093, China; [email protected] 2 Nanjing Institute of Geography and Limnology, Key Laboratory of Watershed Geographic Sciences, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Nanjing 210008, China * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +86-137-7669-6030 Received: 26 August 2020; Accepted: 22 September 2020; Published: 26 September 2020 Abstract: Shantytown is a type of urban residential space with a long history in populated areas; it is a negative and stark space with a gradual decline in function and poverty. It is also a concentrated reflection of an unbalanced and inadequate development of the urban social space, which restricts the development of a high-quality and sustainable social economy. Taking shantytown reconstruction in Nanjing as an example, based on the information of 434 shantytown plots dating from 2008 to 2020, it combines the two typical cases of state-owned land: Xijie and collective land—Nanhe, and the questionnaire data regarding the removal and resettlement of residents, the driving mechanism and the effect of social space reconstruction of shantytown. Reconstruction is mainly discussed based on the overall understanding of the space–time characteristics of shantytown reconstruction in Nanjing. It is found that the top-down policy which transfer from the central government to the local government, the value orientation of urban growth alliance in pursuit of asset appreciation, and the interest demands and game attitude of shantytown residents from the bottom up are all important forces to promote shantytown reconstruction.
    [Show full text]
  • Mechanics of Informal Land and Housing Markets: a Theoretical Exposition
    Mechanics of Informal Land and Housing Markets: A Theoretical Exposition by Elaine A. Tinsley A.B. Economics Wellesley College, 1993 SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF URBAN STUDIES AND PLANNING IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER IN CITY PLANNING AT THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY JUNE 1997 @ 1997 Elaine A. Tinsley. All rights reserved. The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. Signature of Author: -Department of Urban Studies and Planning May 22, 1997 Certified by: Omar M. Razzaz Assistantfrofessor of.Jrbad Studi and Planning uesis Supervisor Accepted by: J. Mark Schuster Associate Professor of Urban Studies and Planning Chair, Master in City Planning Committee JUN 2 5 1997 o LI;F ~ 3 Mechanics of Informal Land and Housing Markets: A Theoretical Exposition by Elaine A. Tinsley Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning on May 22, 1997 in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master in City Planning. ABSTRACT Most of the theoretical literature on housing has focused on formal housing markets, whereas the literature on informal housing has mainly been descriptive. This thesis attempts to extend the implications of the theoretical approach to informal housing markets. A formal housing model is adapted to explain market forces in the informal housing market. Issues such as low income household constraints, tenure security, cross-market infiltration, are discussed and how they impact the supply and demand of informal housing. Low income households determine their demand for housing on factors based on household productivity, which differs from higher income households who have greater flexibility in determining housing attributes based on preferences.
    [Show full text]
  • Informal Settlements and Housing Markets
    POLICY BRIEF Informal settlements and housing markets Paul Collier, Edward Glaeser, Tony Venables, Michael Blake and Priya Manwaring Across the developing world, over one billion people live in informal settlements, and this number is set to double in the next 15 years. This brief explores options for policymakers both to address existing informal settlements, and to ensure that future urban growth provides affordable formal housing for its residents. DIRECTED BY FUNDED BY Photograph: Nadir Hashmi/flickr Informal settlements and housing markets Across the developing world, many governments 1 Providing core infrastructure around which have inherited broken, ex-colonial housing the city can expand is a more realistic policies that do not work for ordinary residents. policy aim than constructing public While most households in African cities struggle housing for everyone. to afford a house for $15,000i, the cost of Providing core infrastructure before people constructing a basic house that meets all legal settle is three times cheaper than retrofitting it requirements is over $42,000ii. in existing unplanned settlements, and avoids disruptive and unpopular slum clearance Large-scale ‘public housing’ schemes have policies. not helped matters. The cost of providing this housing means that it is unable to keep up with 2 Small regulatory changes can have a big demand, and often built on less expensive but impact on house prices, and bring ordinary disconnected urban peripheries. Kigali’s public residents into the formal sector. housing units are cheap compared to other Making housing affordable for ordinary cities, but still cost upwards of $30,000; this is residents means re-writing old colonial housing for the elite, not for ordinary citizens.
    [Show full text]