Supplementary Appendix: Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle Since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Supplementary Appendix: Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle Since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today Supplementary Appendix: Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today Hylton Hollander∗ and Lars Christenseny August 8, 2018 ∗Corresponding author: Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University, Stellenbosch, 7602, South Africa. E-mail address: hylton@sun.ac.za. yResearch Associate, Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University. Founder and owner of Markets and Money Advisory. Senior Fellow at London's Adam Smith Institute. 1 A Implications of the `liquidity trap' hypothesis and the FTPL In the current economic state of low interest rates and ineffective monetary policy some notable hypotheses have gained traction. One strand of literature, in particular, posits a theory of price level determination based on the interaction between fiscal policy and monetary policy. Cochrane (2014) and Leeper(2016) form the argument by identifying three basic approaches to monetary policy and price level determination: money supply and demand in the spirit of the monetarist MV≡PY tradition; interest-rate controlling New-Keynesian models; and the fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL). Their important critique, as previously raised by Sargent and Wallace(1985), is that the economy is satiated with money when the return on money (or reserves) equals the return on risk-free assets (e.g., Treasury bills). That is, any amount of money will be held at this point, and exchanging treasuries for money has no effect on the economy|the price level is therefore indeterminant. In response to this state of the world, Cochrane(2014) and Leeper(2016) show that a determinant equilibrium necessitates an \active" fiscal policy.1 Indeed, Cochrane(2014) correctly emphasizes that this holds only in the current international monetary system of fiat money and central banks. But if the price level is the price of goods in terms of nominal (government) liabilities (money plus bonds), the question then begs: what determines the price level in a world of free banking with un-backed, de-centralized fiat money? Is there a more fundamental theory of price-level determination that precludes fiscal debt management and present discounted government deficits and surpluses? Understanding the interaction between fiscal and monetary policy certainly needs more atten- tion. Cochrane(2014, p. 78) emphasises the fiscal theory of the price level as follows: \In this way, the Treasury and the Fed acting together do, in fact, institute a system in which the government as a whole sets the interest rate it−1 and then sells whatever facevalue of the debt Bt−1 that [is demanded] . even though the Fed does not directly change the overall quantity of debt, and even though the Treasury seems to sell a fixed quantity, not at a fixed price." The model developed here could easily be extended to incorporate fiscal policy and the government budget (see, e.g., Schmitt-Groh´eand Uribe, 2007), but under the assumption that fiscal policy is \passive" it is not necessary: in Leeper's (1991; 2016) \Regime M" monetary policy controls inflation and fiscal pol- icy ensures government solvency (see also, Cochrane, 2014, p. 91). That said, Leeper's framework falls into the same trap identified by McCallum(1986, p. 156) in relation to Sargent and Wallace (1982), namely that the model \neglects the medium-of-exchange role of money, thereby negating 1\The aggregate price level is a relative price: it measures how much a basket of goods is worth in terms of nominal government liabilities|money plus bonds. This relative price must be determined by the interaction of supply and demand for these government liabilities." (Leeper, 2016, p. 2) 2 the possibility of distinguishing between monetary and non-monetary assets." In contrast, the model developed in Belongia and Ireland(2014) and Ireland(2014), based on Barnett's (1978; 1980) user cost of money and monetary aggregation theory, emphasizes the role of the true aggregate of monetary (liquidity) services demanded. Their shopping time model maintains the core New-Keynesian (IS-LM) framework and ensures that the opportunity cost on this true monetary aggregate is always positive|provided the risk-free rate is not zero. With regards to the zero lower bound, it is not immediately evident that money demand has no satiation point. While the threshold appears to be currently rather high in the market for reserves, Ireland(2009) shows evidence of a finite satiation point for broader monetary aggregates (also illustrated in Figure 1). As this is likely true, then even at zero nominal interest rates the true monetary aggregate| whether currency or highly liquid, risk-free assets|commands some positive finite transactions value (Yeager, 1986). In effect, all perfectly substitutable, perfectly liquid assets will inherit this valuable attribute. In the context of macroeconomic models, the demand for fiat money depends on whether we expect it will hold its exchange value in the future: its discounted present value. By backward induction, money would be valueless today if we knew with certainty that money will be valueless at some given date in the future. But if money has positive value in all future periods we can proceed. This is basically illustrated by assuming all wealth (assets) are in the households utility function, and their corresponding rate of return has some implicit transactions value, no matter the illiquidity or riskiness|someone, somewhere is willing to trade for that asset. This is effectively Say's Law: the supply of any good, including fiat money and specie, generates a demand for all other goods (see, e.g., Yeager(1986)). Further, I am essentially proposing some measure of \moneyness" attached to any item of value, to which, as it approaches perfect substitutability with money it will approach the finite value of liquidity (transactions) services. 3 B Descriptive statistics .20 .12 RR/TCD .08 RR/(TCD+CURR) .16 RR/M1 .04 RR/MZM .00 .12 -.04 -.08 .08 -.12 -.16 .04 -.20 -.24 .00 -.28 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure B.1: Left panel: Effective reserve ratio (RRt=Mt = rrt). Right panel: Log-difference effective reserve ratio (RRt=MZMt = rrt). Sample: 1959Q1−2016Q03. C Simulation IRFs −3 m x 10 v p y 0.06 2 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.04 0 0.02 0.02 0.02 −2 0 0 0 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 −4 r int x 10 int_T pii 4 0 0 0.04 2 −0.02 −0.02 0.02 0 0 −0.04 −0.04 −0.02 −2 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 ytilde h fr 10 0.04 0.1 5 0.02 0.05 0 0 0 −5 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 Interest targeting (GM) regime (ν = 11; ν =12) Interest sensitive regime (ν = ν =1) Flexible prices (ν =ν =1) h fr h fr h fr Figure C.2: Positive money supply shock. 4 −3 m x 10 v p y 0.015 1 0 0.01 0.01 0 0 −0.01 0.005 −1 −0.01 0 −2 −0.02 −0.02 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 −3 −4 r x 10 int x 10 int_T pii 0.01 6 1 0.01 4 0 0 0.005 2 −1 −0.01 0 0 −2 −0.02 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 ytilde h fr 0.01 0 0 0 −0.01 −1 −0.01 −0.02 −0.02 −0.03 −2 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20 Interest targeting (GM) regime (ν = 11; ν =12) Interest sensitive regime (ν =ν =1) Flexible prices (ν =ν =1) h fr h fr h fr Figure C.3: Positive money demand shock. −3 −3 −3 x 10 m x 10 v p x 10 y 10 −1 0.015 −2 8 −1.5 −4 0.01 6 −2 −6 4 −2.5 0.005 −8 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 −3 −4 x 10 r x 10 int pii rmc 2 4 0.02 0.02 3 0 0.01 0.01 2 −2 0 0 1 −4 0 −0.01 −0.01 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 −4 −3 x 10 h x 10 fr z n 0 −0.5 −0.005 0.01 −1 −1 −0.01 0.005 −2 −3 −1.5 −0.015 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 2 4 6 8 10 12 Interest sensitive money rule Interest insensitive money rule Flexible prices Figure C.4: Negative technology shock. 5 D Estimation results D.1 Historical decompositions 0.4 2.5 Initial values Initial values 2 0.3 1.5 epsil_md epsil_md 0.2 1 epsil_ms epsil_ms 0.1 0.5 0 0 epsil_i epsil_i −0.5 −0.1 epsil_z epsil_z −1 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 Figure D.5: Historical decomposition (1959Q1−2007Q3): Output (left panel); Price-level (right panel). D.2 Estimation diagnostic statistics 6 SE_epsil_z SE_epsil_i SE_epsil_ms SE_epsil_md 2300 2260 2300 2300 2200 2200 2200 2240 2100 2100 2100 2000 2220 2000 2000 0.04 0.06 0.08 2.5 3 3.5 4 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 −3 x 10 eta_c eta_m eta_n alppha 2260 2260 2260 2260 2250 2250 2250 2250 2240 2240 2240 2240 2230 2230 2230 4 4.5 5 4 5 6 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 theta_p nu_h nu_fr rho_h 2400 2253 2300 2500 2200 2252 2200 2000 2000 2251 2100 1800 2250 2000 1500 0.85 0.9 0.95 0.4 0.6 0.8 30 40 50 60 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 rho_fr kapa_pi kapa_y rho_z 2255 2255 2254 2260 2250 2252 2250 2240 2245 2250 2245 2240 2248 2220 0.120.140.160.18 0.2 1 1.5 2 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.7 0.75 0.8 rho_i rho_ms rho_md 2255 2260 2255 2250 2250 2250 2240 2245 2230 2245 0.99750.9980.99850.9990.9995 0.82 0.84 0.86 0.88 0.9985 0.999 0.9995 log−post log−lik kernel SE_epsil_z SE_epsil_i SE_epsil_ms SE_epsil_md 1000 200 50 50 500 100 0 0 0 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 eta_c eta_m eta_n alppha 2 2 1 5 0.5 1 1 0 0 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 4 5 6 0 1 2 0.4 0.6 0.8 theta_p nu_h nu_fr rho_h 50 5 1 0.1 0 0 0 0 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 0 5 10 20 40 60 80 100 120 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 rho_fr kapa_pi kapa_y rho_z 10 2 20 5 1 1 10 0 0 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 0 0.5 1 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 rho_i rho_ms rho_md 400 20 500 200 10 0 0 0 0.98 0.99 1 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 0.98 0.99 1 Figure D.6: Top panel: log-data density.
Recommended publications
  • Culture and Materialism : Raymond Williams and the Marxist Debate
    CULTURE AND MATERIALISM: RAYMOND WILLIAMS AND THE MARXIST DEBATE by David C. Robinson B.A. (Honours1, Queen's University, 1988 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS (COMMUNICATIONS) in the ,Department of Communication @ David C. Robinson 1991 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY July, 1991 All rights reserved. This work may not be reproduced in whole or in part, by photocopy or other means, without permission of the author. APPROVAL NAME: David Robinson DEGREE: Master of Arts (Communication) TITLE OF THESIS: Culture and Materialism: Raymond Williams and the Marxist Debate EXAMINING COMMITTEE: CHAIR: Dr. Linda Harasim Dr. Richard S. Gruneau Professor Senior Supervisor Dr. Alison C. M. Beale Assistant Professor Supervisor " - Dr. Jerald Zaslove Associate Professor Department of English Examiner DATE APPROVED: PARTIAL COPYRIGHT LICENCE I hereby grant to Simon Fraser University the right to lend my thesis or dissertation (the title of which is shown below) to users of the Simon Fraser University Library, and to make partial or single copies only for such users or in response to a request from the library of any other university, or other educational institution, on its own behalf or for one of its users. I further agree that permission for multiple copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by me or the Dean of Graduate Studies. It is understood that copying or publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission. Title of Thesis/Dissertation: Culture and Materialism: Raymond Williams and the Marxist Debate Author : signature David C.
    [Show full text]
  • Getting It Wrong
    Getting It Wrong Getting It Wrong How Faulty Monetary Statistics Undermine the Fed, the Financial System, and the Economy William A. Barnett The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England © 2012 Massachusetts Institute of Technology All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher. MIT Press books may be purchased at special quantity discounts for business or sales promotional use. For information, please email special_sales@mitpress.mit.edu or write to Special Sales Department, The MIT Press, 55 Hayward Street, Cambridge, MA 02142. This book was set in Palatino by Graphic Composition, Inc., Bogart, GA. Printed and bound in the United States of America. Library of Congress Cataloging- in- Publication Data Barnett, William A. Getting it wrong : how faulty monetary statistics undermine the Fed, the financial system, and the economy / William A. Barnett ; foreword by Apostolos Serletis. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978- 0- 262- 01691- 9 (hbk. : alk. paper) — ISBN 978- 0- 262- 51688- 4 (pbk. : alk. paper) 1. Monetary policy—United States. 2. Finance—Mathematical models. 3. Financial crises. 4. Econometrics. 5. United States—Economic policy—2009– I. Title. HB139.B3755 2012 332.401'5195—dc23 2011021050 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Dedicated to the memory of the great econometrician, Henri Theil, 1924–2000 Contents Foreword: Macroeconomics
    [Show full text]
  • Theology, Economics, and Economic Development
    Theology, Economics, and Economic Development Peter N. Ireland* Boston College November 2010 Nothing to me the life of Gyges and his glut of gold. I neither envy nor admire him, as I watch his life and what he does. I want no pride of tyranny; it lies far off from where I look. Archilochus of Paros1 Introduction In my work as an economist, I rarely consider what anyone might call the “big picture.” Instead, my research focuses on very specific aspects of very specific problems, most having to do with the details of Federal Reserve policy and how it has affected the United States economy during the post-World War II period. It deals, that is, with the activities of one particular government agency within one particular country during one particular historical episode. And since economists are social scientists who, for the most part, lack the ability to conduct controlled experiments, I spend most of my time collecting and analyzing statistically data in attempts to find support for ceteris paribus theoretical arguments based on actual events in which the ceteris are definitely not paribus.2 Implications, conclusions, and recommendations must therefore be * I would like to thank participants in Boston College’s Seminar on Catholic Intellectual Traditions for numerous conversations that helped clarify my thoughts on these and many related issues. Please address correspondence to: Peter N. Ireland, Boston College, Department of Economics, 140 Commonwealth Avenue, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467-­‐3859. Tel: (617) Greek 552 Lyrics-­‐3687. Fax: (617) -­‐ 552 2308. Email: peter.ireland@bc.edu. 1http://www2.bc.edu/~irelandp.
    [Show full text]
  • Heterodox Economics Newsletter Issue 209 — February 13, 2017 — Web1 — Pdf2 — Heterodox Economics Directory3
    Heterodox Economics Newsletter Issue 209 — February 13, 2017 — web1 — pdf2 — Heterodox Economics Directory3 ”What I am worried about most of all, is what we don’t see. So, I am worried about the analysis that is never seen, that never becomes a paper and it doesn’t become a paper, because it can’t become a paper. And it can’t become a paper, because that’s not what a paper in economics is all about. I am quite worried about and we know such vacuums exist.” These wise words resemble a sentiment familiar to many heterodox economists as they give a shallow description of the paradigmatic constraints encountered within the eco- nomics discipline. However, they are taken from a statement by George A. Akerlof, which he happened to give at the recent ASSA-convention in Chicago. Specifically, Ak- erlof took part in a session comprised of leading mainstream ”active senior scholars” (quoting James Heckman’s introduction) discussing the ”curse of the top 5”, that is, the dominance of a set of five leading mainstream journals (QJE, JPE, AER, Econometrica and Review of Econ Studies) in terms of prestige and intellectual recognition (you can watch it here4 ). For once, this statement and the associated session indicate that there is still some reflexivity within the dominant economic approach - even if embracing this kind of reflexivity seems restricted to ”Bank of Sweden”-prize winners. Although there is, of course, no direct reference to heterodox or pluralist economics and no mentioning of the history of economic thought, most participants show a honest concern for the narrowing impact of the incentive structure within the discipline, which is reinforced by the general trends for metric-based evaluation in scientific institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle Since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today
    Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today Hylton Hollander∗ and Lars Christenseny May 23, 2017 Preliminary Draft Abstract To justify the operational procedures of central banks since the 2008 global financial crisis, reputable academics and practitioners proclaim the independence of interest rate policy from all things monetary. This policy debate can be traced as far back as Thorn- ton (1802), Pigou(1917), Tinbergen(1939, 1951), and Poole(1970). Central to this debate is the effect of the choice by the monetary authority between reserves and in- terest rate manipulation. Using U.S. data spanning 50 years, we estimate a dynamic general equilibrium model and show that the type of monetary policy regime has sig- nificant implications for the role of monetary aggregates and interest rate policy on the U.S. business cycle. The interaction between money supply and demand and the type of monetary regime in our model does remarkably well to capture the dynamics of the U.S. business cycle. The results suggest that the evolution toward a stricter interest rate targeting regime renders central bank balance sheet expansions superfluous. In the context of the 2007−09 global financial crisis, a more flexible interest rate targeting regime would have led to a significant monetary expansion and more rapid economic recovery in the U.S. JEL codes: E32, E41, E42, E52, E58, N12 Keywords: monetary regimes, monetary policy, money demand, US business cycle ∗Corresponding author: Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University, Stellenbosch, 7602, South Africa. E-mail address: hylton@sun.ac.za.
    [Show full text]
  • An Interview with William A. Barnett
    CENTER FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY . An Interview with William A. Barnett By Apostolos Serletis 1120 Avenue of the Americas, 4th Floor New York, NY 10036 T 212.626.2660 www.centerforfinancialstability.org -0- CENTER FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY NEW YORK An Interview with William A. Barnett By Apostolos Serletis University of Calgary February, 2017 Copyright 2017 by Center for Financial Stability. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced or transmitted without the author’s written permission. Layout by Kurt Schuler and Lauren Cooper Published 2017 by the Center for Financial Stability 1120 Avenue of the Americas, 4th Floor, New York, NY 10036 http://www.centerforfinancialstability.org Keywords: Divisia monetary aggregates, Minflex Laurent model, Generalized Barnett model, Asymptotically Ideal Model (AIM), bifurcation, chaos and nonlinear dynamics. The Center for Financial Stability (CFS) is a private, nonprofit institution focusing on global finance and markets. Its research is nonpartisan. This publication reflects the judgments and recommendations of the author(s). They do not necessarily represent the views of members of the Advisory Board or Trustees, whose involvement in no way should be interpreted as an endorsement of the report by either themselves or the organizations with which they are affiliated. Table of Contents About William A. Barnett…………………………………………………………..….......………....p. 1 1. Work before Economics…………………………..……………...……………….....…….…...…..p. 4 2. Graduate Study……………………………………...……………………..……..…………….….p. 5 3. Early Research at the Federal Reserve Board……………………………………….......………p. 8 4. Monetary and Financial Aggregation……..………………………………………..…………...p. 13 5. Demand Systems and Flexible Functional Forms……............................................…..……….p. 18 6. Nonlinear and Complex Dynamics………………………..………………….…..……………..p. 23 7. Founding of Journals, Monograph Series, and Societies……………………………………....p.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol
    Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 2 pp. 1101-1115 1. Introduction The mainstream approach to monetary policy in the last thirty years is focusing on short term interest rates and downplays the significant role of monetary aggregates. The reason for the abandonment of monetary aggregates was not theoretical but empirical: the established link between money and inflation was severed in recent decades when capital and financial markets’ innovation produced new interest bearing assets that rendered monetary aggregates inaccurate and less relevant. These empirical findings put money and its growth rate in the backstage of empirical macroeconomic forecasting. The failure of money to forecast macroeconomic variables though may be explained by the “Barnett critique”1: the use so far, by central banks and economists in general, of the traditional simple-sum monetary aggregates. Barnett (1997) linked the deserved decline in the policy-importance of monetary aggregates to the specific restrictions of simple sum aggregation: the various monetary components are assigned an equal and intertemporally constant weight. Central banks facing inaccuracies and paradoxes using simple-sum aggregates as their key policy variable, abandoned money all together. Barnett (1978, 1980) developed and advocates the use of the theoretically correct in terms of economic aggregation and index number theory Divisia2 monetary aggregates. The simple sum aggregation method used widely by central banks, economists and investors even today, has been criticized heavily in the literature since Fisher (1922), Moroney and Wilbratte (1976), the seminal paper of Barnett (1980) and also Barnett (1997), Boughton (1981), Batten and Thornton (1985), Fisher and Fleissig (1995), Schunk (2001), Darrat et al.
    [Show full text]
  • Bifurcation of Macroeconometric Models and Robustness of Dynamical Inferences
    SAE./No.32/April 2015 Studies in Applied Economics Bifurcation of MacroeconoMetric Models and roBustness of dynaMical inferences William A. Barnett and Guo Chen Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and Study of Business Enterprise !Bifurcation!of!Macroeconometric!Models!and!Robustness!of!Dynamical!Inferences! William!A.!Barnett!! University!of!Kansas,!Lawrence,!and!Center!for!Financial!Stability,!New!York!City! Guo!Chen!! University!of!Kansas,!Lawrence,!Kansas! April!20,!2015! ! About!the!Series! The!Studies(in(Applied(Economics!series!is!under!the!general!direction!of!Prof.!Steve!H.!Hanke,!CoMDirector!of! the!Institute!for!Applied!Economics,!Global!Health!and!the!Study!of!Business!Enterprise!(hanke@jhu.edu).!! ! About!the!Authors! Dr.!William!A.!Barnett!(williamabarnett@gmail.com)!is!an!eminent!economic!scientist!and!originator!of!the! Divisia!monetary!aggregates!and!the!“Barnett!Critique.”!He!is!Oswald!Distinguished!Professor!of! Macroeconomics!at!the!University!of!Kansas!Department!of!Economics!and!Core!Faculty!Member!of!the! Center!for!Global!and!International!Studies!at!the!University!of!Kansas,!as!well!as!Senior!Fellow!of!the!IC2! Institute!at!the!University!of!Texas!at!Austin!and!Fellow!of!the!Institute!for!Applied!Economics!at!Johns! Hopkins!University.!He!is!Founder!and!Editor!of!the!Cambridge!University!Press!journal,!Macroeconomic( Dynamics,!and!Founder!and!Editor!of!the!Emerald!Press!monograph!series,!International(Symposia(in( Economic(Theory(and(Econometrics.!Dr.!Barnett!recently!founded!the!Society!for!Economic!Measurement!and!
    [Show full text]
  • Chinese Divisia Monetary Index and GDP Nowcasting William A. Barnett and Biyan Tang1 October 17, 2015
    Chinese Divisia Monetary Index and GDP Nowcasting William A. Barnett and Biyan Tang1 October 17, 2015 Abstract Since China’s enactment of the Reform and Opening-Up policy in 1978, China has become one of the world’s fastest growing economies, with an annual GDP growth rate exceeding 10% between 1978 and 2008. But in 2015, Chinese GDP grew at 7 %, the lowest rate in five years. Many corporations complain that the borrowing cost of capital is too high. This paper constructs Chinese Divisia monetary aggregates M1 and M2, and, for the first time, constructs the broader Chinese monetary aggregates, M3 and M4. Those broader aggregates have never before been constructed for China, either as simple-sum or Divisia. The results shed light on the current Chinese monetary situation and the increased borrowing cost of money. GDP data are published only quarterly and with a substantial lag, while many monetary and financial decisions are made at a higher frequency. GDP nowcasting can evaluate the current month’s GDP growth rate, given the available economic data up to the point at which the nowcasting is conducted. Therefore, nowcasting GDP has become an increasingly important task for central banks. This paper nowcasts Chinese monthly GDP growth rate using a dynamic factor model, incorporating as indicators the Divisia monetary aggregate indexes, Divisia M1 and M2 along with additional information from a large panel of other relevant time series data. The results show that Divisia monetary aggregates contain more indicator information than the simple sum aggregates, and thereby help the factor model produce the best available nowcasting results.
    [Show full text]
  • Studies in Applied Economics
    SAE./No.91/October 2017 Studies in Applied Economics FINANCIAL FIRM PRODUCTION OF INSIDE MONETARY AND CREDIT CARD SERVICES: AN AGGREGATION THEORETIC APPROACH William A. Barnett and Liting Su Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and Study of Business Enterprise FINANCIAL FIRM PRODUCTION OF INSIDE MONETARY AND CREDIT CARD SERVICES: AN AGGREGATION THEORETIC APPROACH1 William A. Barnett University of Kansas, Lawrence, and Center for Financial Stability, NY City Liting Su University of Kansas, Lawrence, and Center for Financial Stability, NY City October 18, 2017 About the Series The Studies in Applied Economics series is under the general direction of Prof. Steve H. Hanke, Co-Director of the Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health and the Study of Business Enterprise (hanke@jhu.edu). About the Authors Dr. William A Barnett (williamabarnett@gmail.com) is an eminent economic scientist and originator of the Divisia monetary aggregates and the ‘Barnett Critique.” He is the Oswald Distinguished Professor of Macroeconomics at the University of Kansas Department of Economics and Core Faculty Member of the Center for Global and International Studies at the University of Kansas, as well as Senior Fell of the IC2 Institute at the University of Texas at Austin and Fellow of the Institute for Applied Economic, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise at The Johns Hopkins University. He is Founder and Editor of the Cambridge University Press journal Macroeconomic Dynamics, and Founder and Editor of the Emerald Press monograph series, International Symposia in Economic Theory and Econometrics. Dr. Barnett recently founded the Society for Economic Measurement and serves as president.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Monetary Aggregation
    The Theory of Monetary Aggregation Edited by WILLIAM A. BARNETT Washington University St. Louis, Missouri and APOSTOLOS SERLETIS University of Calgary Calgary, Canada CONTENTS vii Contents Preface xxiii W. Erwin Diewert Editors' Introduction xxix William A. Barnett and Apostolos Serletis PART 1: MONETARY INDEX NUMBER THEORY AND THE PRICE OF MONEY SECTION 1.1: EDITORS' OVERVIEW OF PART 1 3 William A. Barnett and Apostolos Serletis SECTION 1.2: DERIVATION OF THE USER COST OF MONETARY SERVICES 6 Chapter 1: The User Cost of Money 6 William A. Barnett 1 Introduction . 6 2 Assumptions and Notation . 7 3 Derivation . 9 SECTION 1.3: THE PRICE OF MONETARY SERVICES AND ITS USE IN MONETARY INDEX NUMBER THEORY 11 Chapter 2: Economic Monetary Aggregates: An Application of Index Number and Aggregation Theory 11 William A. Barnett 1 Introduction . 12 2 Objectives . 13 viii CONTENTS 3 The Consumer's Decision . 16 3.1 Intertemporal Allocation . 16 3.2 The User Cost of Monetary Assets . 20 3.3 Supernumerary Quantities . 20 3.4 Conditional Current Period Allocation . 22 4 Preference Structure over Financial Assets . 23 4.1 Blocking of the Utility Function . 23 4.2 Multi-stage Budgeting . 23 5 Recursive Estimation Approach . 25 6 Passbook Savings . 26 6.1 C.E.S. Specification . 26 6.2 Theoretical Index Number Properties . 28 6.3 Results with Passbook Savings . 29 7 Transaction Balances . 31 7.1 Specification . 31 7.2 Estimates . 33 7.3 Functional Index Numbers . 34 8 Implications of Estimates . 34 9 Empirical Selection of Blocking . 35 9.1 Conditions on Elasticities of Substitution .
    [Show full text]
  • The Demand for Money for EMU: a Flexible Functional Form Approach
    The Demand for Money for EMU: A Flexible Functional Form Approach William A. Barnett University of Kansas, Lawrence, and Center for Financial Stability, NY City and Neepa B. Gaekwad University of Kansas, Lawrence September 19, 2017 Monetary aggregates have a special role under the "two pillar strategy" of the ECB. Hence, the need for a theoretically consistent measure of monetary aggregates for the European Monetary Union (EMU) is needed. This paper analyzes aggregation over monetary assets for the EMU. We aggregate over the monetary services for the EMU-11 countries, which include Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Slovakia, and Slovenia. We adopt the Divisia monetary aggregation approach, which is consistent with index number theory and microeconomic aggregation theory. The result is a multilateral Divisia monetary aggregate in accordance with Barnett (2007). The multilateral Divisia monetary aggregate for the EMU-11 is found to be more informative and a better signal of economic trends than the corresponding simple sum aggregate. We then analyze substitutability among monetary assets for the EMU-11 within the framework of a representative consumer's utility function, using Barnett’s (1983) locally flexible functional form, the minflex Laurent Indirect utility function. The analysis of elasticities with respect to the asset’s user-cost prices shows that: (i) transaction balances (TB) and deposits redeemable at notice (DRN) are income elastic, (ii) the DRN display large variation in price elasticity, and (iii) the monetary assets are not good substitutes for each other within the EMU-11. Simple sum monetary aggregation assumes that component assets are perfect substitutes.
    [Show full text]