Penrosian Learning Confronts the Neoclassical Fallacy
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
The Struggle to Redevelop a Jim Crow State, 1960–2000
Educating for a New Economy: The Struggle to Redevelop a Jim Crow State, 1960–2000 by William D. Goldsmith Department of History Duke University Date:_______________________ Approved: ___________________________ Nancy MacLean, Supervisor ___________________________ Edward J. Balleisen ___________________________ Adriane Lentz-Smith ___________________________ Gary Gereffi ___________________________ Helen Ladd Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of History in The Graduate School of Duke University 2018 ABSTRACT Educating for a New Economy: The Struggle to Redevelop a Jim Crow State, 1960–2000 by William D. Goldsmith Department of History Duke University Date:_______________________ Approved: ___________________________ Nancy MacLean, Supervisor ___________________________ Edward J. Balleisen ___________________________ Adriane Lentz-Smith ___________________________ Gary Gereffi ___________________________ Helen Ladd An abstract of a dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of History in the Graduate School of Duke University 2018 Copyright by William D. Goldsmith 2018 Abstract This dissertation shows how an array of policymakers, invested in uprooting an unequal political economy descended from the plantation system and Jim Crow, gravitated to education as a centerpiece of development strategy, and why so many are still disappointed in its outcomes. By looking at state-wide policymaking in North Carolina and policy effects in the state’s black belt counties, this study shows why the civil rights movement was vital for shifting state policy in former Jim Crow states towards greater investment in human resources. By breaking down employment barriers to African Americans and opening up the South to new people and ideas, the civil rights movement fostered a new climate for economic policymaking, and a new ecosystem of organizations flourished to promote equitable growth. -
NAME: LOUIS A. FERLEGER Address: Department of History Boston University 226 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02215 (617) 353-8305 Emai
NAME: LOUIS A. FERLEGER Address: Department of History Boston University 226 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02215 (617) 353-8305 Email: [email protected] Education: Temple University (B.B.A., 1971) Temple University (MA, Economics, 1973) Temple University (Ph.D., Economics, 1978) Teaching and Professional Employment: Professor, Department of History, Boston University, 1999-present. Executive Director, The Historical Society, 1999-2008. Associate Director, Honors Program, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1997-99. Adjunct Professor, Department of History, Boston College, Spring 1997. Associate Director, Massachusetts Institute for Social and Economic Research, 1994-97. Chair, Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1992-93. Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1991-1999. Associate Dean of Academic Affairs, College of Arts and Sciences, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1989-1991. Associate Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1984-1991. Assistant Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1978-84. Academic Honors: Honored for Excellence in Teaching, University of Massachusetts Boston, March 1988. Outstanding Achievement Award, University of Massachusetts Boston, 1984-85. Grants and Fellowships: National Endowment for the Humanities Chairman’s Grant, 2008 Earhart Foundation Fellowship, 2005-06 1 Research Grant, Twentieth Century Fund, jointly with Jay Mandle, Spring, 1992 Charles Warren Fellowship, Charles Warren Center for Studies in American History, Department of History, Harvard University, Spring 1992. Arthur H. Cole Grant-in-Aid, Economic History Association, Summer 1988. National Endowment for the Humanities Fellowship, 1988. Research Grant, Joseph P. Healey Endowment Grant, University of Massachusetts Boston, Spring, 1986. Research Grant, American Association for State and Local History, 1985. Faculty Development Research and Travel Grants, University of Massachusetts Boston: 1979, 1981, 1982-1984, 1996-98. -
William Lazonick
September 2010 WILLIAM LAZONICK Center for Industrial Competitiveness University of Massachusetts Lowell One University Avenue, Lowell, MA 01854 Phone: 1 617 576-0880 Fax: 1 425 491-4964 Email: [email protected] Personal website: http://www.uml.edu/centers/CIC/lazonick.html Date and Place of Birth: June 8, 1945 at Toronto, Ontario, Canada Countries of Citizenship: USA, Canada Current Principal Academic Positions: Professor, University of Massachusetts Lowell, Department of Economics (1993-1997 Policy & Planning; 1997-2010 Regional Economic and Social Development) Director, Center for Industrial Competitiveness, University of Massachusetts Lowell Previous Principal Academic Positions: Research Professor, INSEAD 1996-2007 Professor of Economics, University of Tokyo 1996-1997 Professor of Economics, Barnard College, Columbia University 1985-1993 Research Fellow, Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration 1984-1986 Associate Professor of Economics, Harvard University 1980-1984 Assistant Professor of Economics, Harvard University 1975-1980 Academic Honors: Schumpeter Prize, International Schumpeter Society 2010 Honorary Doctor of Philosophy, Uppsala University 1991 President, Business History Conference 1990-1991 Visiting Member, Social Sciences, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton 1989-1990 German Marshall Fund of the United States Research Fellow 1985-1986 Harvard-Newcomen Business History Research Fellow 1984-1985 Newcomen Award in Business History for the outstanding article in Business History Review in 1983 1984 -
The Financialization of the US Corporation: What Has Been Lost, and How It Can Be Regained
The Financialization of the US Corporation: What Has Been Lost, and How It Can Be Regained William Lazonick University of Massachusetts Lowell The Academic-Industry Research Network [email protected] Revised, July 2012 Background paper for a presentation to the Seattle University School of Law Berle IV Symposiun, “The Future of Financial/Securities Markets,” London June 14-15, 2012. The research in this paper has been funded by the Ford Foundation project on Financial Institutions for Innovation and Development, the INET project on the Stock Market and Innovative Enterprise, the European Commission project on Finance, Innovation, and Growth, and the Connect Innovation Institute project on Innovation and Production: Reviving U.S. Prosperity. Mustafa Erdem Sakinç, has coordinated the development and maintenance of the stock-buyback database, and Dongxu Li, Qiaoling Ma, Xiahui Xia, and Yue Zhang have provided research assistance. Lazonick: The Financialization of the US Corporation 1 What Happened to Economic Prosperity? Many of us know what a prosperous economy looks like. People who want to work have no problem finding jobs. People who want to build careers can accumulate the necessary work experience over time. People who want to start their own businesses can tap into sources of committed finance that can enable them to get their firms up and running. When the work has been done, careers have been built, and businesses have become going concerns, the prosperous economy yields a distribution of income that most people regard as fair. The prosperous economy has a large and stable middle class, with hard-working and dedicated people finding opportunities to climb up the economic ladder. -
Edith Penrose's Legacy to Economics
Edith Penrose’s Legacy to Economics, Management and Political Economy Kofi Adjepong-Boateng and Christine Oughton Academics have seldom shaped their discipline to the extent that their name becomes a byword for theory, practice and policy. Keynes is a noteworthy example, leaving a legacy of Keynesian economics and policy that shaped the international economic order, underpinned the golden age of economic growth, helped to create a central bank in India and led a US President to declare himself a ‘Keynesian’ in 1971. Even fewer academics have achieved such acclaim across two disciplines. Edith Penrose, however, is one of them, her influence spanning the disciplines of economics and management. Her achievement is all the more remarkable given the lack of representation and recognition of women in economics, both then and now. The absence of women in the economics profession has not gone unnoticed, at least by the Financial Times (FT), The Economist and other media outlets. Both Diane Coyle (August 2017) and Gemma Tetlow (April 2018) have highlighted this problem in the FT. In her article, Gemma Tetlow point out that Elinor Ostrom is still the only woman to have been awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics; and that this year Rachel Griffith, Professor of Economics at Manchester University, has become only the second female president of the Royal Economic Society since its creation in 1890. Moreover, a list of influential economists in The Economist attracted much attention, a fair bit of which was critical. One of the criticisms was the total absence of any women. A more recent article in the same publication argues that the gender problem in economics results in fewer ideas to benefit the discipline and the consequent disadvantage of a skewed point of view. -
Emerging Economies
Asia Pac J Manag (2018) 35:829–857 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-018-9599-3 REVIEWS The growth of the firm in (and out of) emerging economies Mike W. Peng1 & Sergey Lebedev2 & Cristina O. Vlas3 & Joyce C. Wang1 & Jason S. Shay4 Published online: 2 October 2018 # Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018 Abstract Starting with Peng and Heath (Academy of Management Review, 21: 492– 528, 1996), the growth of the firm in emerging economies (EE) has received increasing attention in the literature in the last two decades. This line of research has not only extended our knowledge on firms’ strategic choices to the context of EE, but also proposed new perspectives on the growth of the firm. Leveraging prior research, this article focuses on three major modes for firm growth—organic, acquisitive, and network-based. For each mode, we identify new themes and insights emerging from the last two decades of research. They center on (1) compositional capabilities and frugal innovations for organic growth, (2) business groups and cross-border acquisi- tions for acquisitive growth, and (3) network capitalism and institutional transitions for * Mike W. Peng [email protected] Sergey Lebedev [email protected] Cristina O. Vlas [email protected] Joyce C. Wang [email protected] Jason S. Shay [email protected] 1 Jindal School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, 800 West Campbell Road, SM 43, Richardson, TX 75080, USA 2 College of Business, San Francisco State University, 1600 Holloway Avenue, San Francisco, CA 94132, USA 3 University of Massachusetts Amherst, 121 President’sDrive,Amherst,MA01003,USA 4 Aviall – Boeing Global Services, 2750 Regent Blvd., Dallas, TX 75261, USA 830 M. -
The Value-Extracting CEO: How Executive Stock-Based Pay Undermines Investment in Productive Capabilities
The Value-Extracting CEO: How Executive Stock-Based Pay Undermines Investment in Productive Capabilities William Lazonick∗ Working Paper No. 54 December 3, 2016 ABSTRACT The business corporation is the central economic institution in a modern economy. A company’s senior executives, with the advice and support of the board of directors, are responsible for the allocation of corporate resources to investments in productive capabilities. Senior executives also advise the board on the extent to which, given the need to invest in productive capabilities, the company can afford to make cash distributions to shareholders. Motivating corporate resource- William Lazonick is Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts Lowell; President, The Academic- Industry Research Network; Visiting Professor, University of Ljubljana; Distinguished Research Associate, Institut Mines-Télécom, Paris; Professorial Research Associate, SOAS University of London. (email: [email protected]). This paper reflects research being carried out under grants from the Institute for New Economic Thinking (Collective and Cumulative Careers project through the Academic-Industry Research Network) and the European Commission (Innovation-Fuelled Sustainable and Inclusive Growth through the University of Ljubljana). It also builds on research done on previous grants from the Institute for New Economic Thinking and from the Ford Foundation (Financial Institutions for Innovation and Development through UMass Lowell). Some of the material in this paper draws on Matt Hopkins and William Lazonick, “The Mismeasure of Mammon,” Uses and Abuses of Executive Pay Data,” Institute for New Economic Thinking Working Paper No. 49, August 29, 2016, at https://www.ineteconomics.org/ideas-papers/research-papers/the-mismeasure-of-mammon-uses-and-abuses-of- executive-pay-data Lazonick: The Value-Extracting CEO allocation decisions are the modes of remuneration that incentivize and reward the top executives of these companies. -
THE MIT JAPAN I PROGRAM
THE MIT JAPAN i PROGRAM ) 7 j AeA N I Science, Technology, Management 0 'Y NNIP 0 N-1-T-111 i i -6 Indigenous Innovation and Industrialization: Foundations of Japanese Development and Advantage William Lazonick and William Mass i MITJP 95-03 Center for International Studies Massachusetts Institute of Technology i----- Indigenous Innovation and Industrialization: Foundations of Japanese Development and Advantage William Lazonick and William Mass MITJP 95-03 Distributed Courtesy of the MIT Japan Program Science * Technology * Management Center for International Studies Massachusetts Institute of Technology Room E38-7th Floor Cambridge, MA 02139 phone: 617-253-2839 fax: 617-258-7432 © MIT Japan Program About the MIT Japan Program and its Working Paper Series The MIT Japan Program was founded in 1981 to create a new generation of technologically sophisticated "Japan-aware" scientists, engineers, and managers in the United States. The Program's corporate sponsors, as well as support from the government and from private foundations, have made it the largest, most comprehensive, and most widely emulated center of applied Japanese studies in the world. The intellectual focus of the Program is to integrate the research methodologies of the social sciences, the humanities, and technology to approach issues confronting the United States and Japan in their relations involving science and technology. The Program is uniquely positioned to make use of MIT's extensive network of Japan-related resources, which include faculty, researchers, and library collections, as well as a Tokyo-based office. Through its three core activities, namely, education, research, and public awareness, the Program disseminates both to its sponsors and to the interested public its expertise on Japanese science and technology and on how that science and technology is managed. -
Edith Penrose's 'The Theory of The
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Edith Penrose’s ‘The Theory of the Growth of the Firm’ Fifty Years Later Pitelis, Christos 13 March 2009 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/23180/ MPRA Paper No. 23180, posted 10 Jun 2010 05:46 UTC Edith Penrose’s ‘The Theory of the Growth of the Firm’ Fifty Years Later∗∗∗ Christos N. Pitelis Judge Business School and Queens’ College University of Cambridge Trumpington Street Cambridge CB2 1AG UK Tel: 0044 1223 339618 Fax: 0044 1223 766815 Email: [email protected] 13 March 2009 ∗ This paper draws and builds upon earlier work by Penrose and Pitelis (1999) and Pitelis (2004, 2005, 2007a, 2007b). am grateful to Edith Penrose for discussion and numerous colleagues for comments on earlier drafts, especially Mie Augier, (ohn Dunning, (oe Mahoney, Robin Marris, Perran Penrose, David Teece and Alain ,erbeke. Errors are mine. 1 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1477885 I. INTRODUCTION 2009 marks the 50th anniversary of Edith Penrose’s The Theory of the Growth of the Firm (TGF thereafter). In a review of the book in the Economic Journal, Robin Marris (1961) predicted that TGF would prove one of the most influential of the decade. In his 1987 entry to the New Palgrave he added that “this proved an understatement” (p831). Marris’ statements were referring mainly to the economic theory of the firm, especially the literature on ‘managerial theories’, which were popular in the 1960s and in which he himself was a major contributor (Marris 1964). Neither Marris nor Penrose herself could foresee what appears to be the case 50 years on; this is a situation where the influence of TGF in mainstream economics has been rather limited (also Marris, 1987 and below). -
Economic Democracy at Work: Why (And How) Workers Should Be Represented on US Corporate Boards
Lenore Palladino, University of Massachusetts, Amherst∗ Economic Democracy at Work: Why (and How) Workers Should be Represented on US Corporate Boards Abstract: Workers should have representation on corporate boards of directors in the United States. Employees are key stakeholders whose contribution is necessary for the success of innovative enterprises. In contrast to the “shareholder primacy” theory of corporate governance, which claims that only shareholders should have decision-making authority, the argument made here is that also granting employees a voice on the corporate board will have positive effects for employees and the company as a whole. Yet implementing such a reform in the twenty-first-century US context is not simply a matter of importing a European model. Effective policy design requires consideration of the US workforce structure and the important prohibition on employer-dominated organizations in US labor law, and developing appropriate mechanisms for worker-director election, representation, and worker organization. Worker representation on boards will not be effective in a vacuum, but is an important component of overall reform efforts to strengthen the US economy. Keywords: Boards of directors; corporate governance; stakeholders; worker representation on corporate boards I. Introduction For the past four decades, US corporate governance has followed a “shareholder primacy” model (Lazonick and O’Sullivan 2000; van der Zwan 2014). The Law and Economics theory of shareholder primacy claims that the shareholder is the sole corporate stakeholder who makes a risky investment; therefore, the maximization of shareholder value is defended as the sole goal of corporations, and management “agents” owe allegiance only to the shareholder “principals” (Jensen and Meckling 1976). -
William Lazonick*+
The Functions of the Stock Market and the Fallacies of Shareholder Value William Lazonick*+ Working Paper No. 58 June 3, 2017 (revised July 20, 2017) ABSTRACT Conventional wisdom has it that the primary function of the stock market is to raise cash for companies for the purpose of investing in productive capabilities. The conventional wisdom is wrong. Academic research on sources of corporate finance shows that, compared with other sources of funds, stock markets in advanced countries have been insignificant suppliers of capital for corporations. The purpose of this essay is to build a rigorous and relevant conception of the evolving role of the stock market in the U.S. corporate economy. In fact, the functions of the stock market go well beyond “cash” to include four other functions, which can be summarized as “control,” “creation,” “combination,” and “compensation.” In this paper, I argue, based on historical evidence, that in the growth of the U.S. economy the key function of the stock market was control. Specifically, the stock market enabled the separation of managerial control over the allocation of corporate resources from the ownership of the company’s shares. Yet, assuming that the key function of the stock market * University of Massachusetts Lowell and the Academic-Industry Research Network. [email protected] + This paper has been prepared for a volume What Next for Corporate Governance? edited by Ciaran Driver and Grahame Thompson. Funding for this research came from the Institute for New Economic Thinking, the European Union Horizon 2020 Project No. 649186 on Innovation-Fuelled Sustainable and Inclusive Growth, and the Korea Economic Research Institute. -
Business History and Economics
PRESIDENTIAL ADDRESS Business History and Economics William Lazonick Barnard College,Columbia University The presidentialaddress is traditionallyheavily auto-biographical. As your typicalegotistical, white, male academic,I am in principlequite happy to perpetuatethe tradition. But for practicalreasons, I havesecond thoughts about tellingyou the storyof my life. Normally the presidentialaddress at the BusinessHistory Conferencehas been part of a banquetformat that has createda captiveaudience. With the receptionand the eveningstill aheadof you rather thanbehind you, I fear that if I try to take thishour to recountthe life and times of William H. Lazonickyou might all start headingfor the doors. It alsohappens that, despitemy still valid Canadianpassport, I am not the presidentof the CanadianBusiness History Conference. In view of the joint sponsorshipof thesemeetings, my "presidential"address is beingbilled as a "keynoteaddress". ! havestrong doubts about the wisdomof offeringmy life storyas the keynotetheme of thesemeetings. I shall, therefore,refrain from tellingyou that I wasborn and bred in the very city where we are havingthese meetings. And I won't let you know that just a ten minutewalk from where we standright now, my father has for overforty years run a businessthat bearsmy name(but just in caseanybody is interestedyou can look for a sign that saysH. WILLIAMS & CO. on ChurchStreet, north of Queen). Nor shallI bothertelling you that overtwo decadesago the Universityof Toronto awardedme a Bachelorof Commerce degree. Surely,you haveno interestin suchdetails of my personallife, so I shalloblige you by keepingthem to myself. But I mustwarn you that I won't spareyou completely. What I shall talk about is how an economistcame to the studyof businesshistory. In relatingthis tale, my purposeis to ask not what the economistcan do for businesshistory but what businesshistory can do for the economist.For, as manyof you may know,the academicdiscipline that callsitself economicsis in a sorrystate.