Max Peter Leitterstorf IPO Financing of Family Firms

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Max Peter Leitterstorf IPO Financing of Family Firms Max Peter Leitterstorf IPO Financing of Family Firms Dissertation for obtaining the doctor degree of economic science (Dr. rer. pol.) at WHU – Otto Beisheim School of Management Date of submission: January 31, 2013 First Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Sabine Rau Second Supervisor: Prof. Dr. Markus Rudolf ACKNOWLEDGMENT This thesis is a result of my work as a doctoral student at the WHU – Otto Beisheim School of Management in Vallendar, Germany, between February 2011 and January 2013. I would like to express my deepest appreciation to everybody who supported me during this time. I would like to especially thank my first supervisor, Prof. Dr. Sabine Rau, who encouraged me throughout my time as a doctoral student and always provided very constructive feedback. Special thanks also go to my second supervisor, Prof. Dr. Markus Rudolf. I would like to express my warmest gratitude to my parents and my wife, who always supported me unconditionally. In addition, I am very grateful to The Boston Consulting Group for kindly supporting my leave of absence. Max Leitterstorf I CONTENTS TABLES ...................................................................................................................... II ABBREVIATIONS ................................................................................................... III INTRODUCTION TO THE THESIS .......................................................................... 1 ESSAY 1: CAPITAL STRUCTURE OF FAMILY FIRMS: A SYSTEMATIC LITERATURE REVIEW .......................................................................................... 11 Introduction ............................................................................................................ 11 Literature selection ................................................................................................. 13 Literature analysis .................................................................................................. 16 Discussion and conclusion ..................................................................................... 30 ESSAY 2: SEW AND IPO UNDERPRICING OF FAMILY FIRMS ...................... 42 Introduction ............................................................................................................ 42 Theoretical background and hypotheses ................................................................ 46 Methods .................................................................................................................. 58 Discussion and conclusion ..................................................................................... 72 ESSAY 3: AGENCY COSTS AND IPO VALUATIONS OF FAMILY FIRMS .... 78 Introduction ............................................................................................................ 78 Theoretical background and hypotheses ................................................................ 81 Methods .................................................................................................................. 89 Discussion and conclusion ..................................................................................... 96 DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION OF THE THESIS ........................................ 100 REFERENCES ......................................................................................................... 108 AFFIRMATION – STATUTORY DECLARATION ............................................. 120 II TABLES Introduction to the thesis Table 0-1: Overview of different types of agency costs 4 Table 0-2: Overview of the three essays in this thesis 6 Table 0-3: Number of family and non-family firm IPOs from 2004 to 2011 9 Essay 1 Table 1-1: Overview of included articles and journals 15 Table 1-2: Family firm variables and leverage aspects 39 Essay 2 Table 2-1: IPO underpricing explanations 50 Table 2-2: Descriptive statistics and correlations 65 Table 2-3: Hierarchical regression results 67 Table 2-4: Model 2 differentiated by family firm definition 68 Table 2-5: Model 2 differentiated by different sub-groups of family firms 70 Table 2-6: Different closing prices employed in the calculation of underpricing 71 Essay 3 Table 3-1: Descriptive statistics and correlations 94 Table 3-2: Hierarchical regression results 95 Discussion and conclusion of the thesis Table 4-1: Overview of topics addressed in this thesis 101 III ABBREVIATIONS CEO Chief executive officer CSR Corporate social responsibility e.g. Exempli gratia; for example FFS Family firm status F-PEC Family influence scale (power, experience, and culture) i.e. Id est; that is IPO Initial public offering ln Natural logarithm n Number of observations n/a Not applicable OLS Ordinary least square p P-value Prof. Professor R2 Coefficient of determination SD Standard deviation SEW Socioemotional wealth SIC Standard industrial classification TMT Top management team U.K. United Kingdom U.S. United States WHU Wissenschaftliche Hochschule für Unternehmensführung Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION TO THE THESIS Background and motivation: Why are family firm IPOs important? Family firms are an increasingly popular topic both for society in general and for academic scholars in particular. Public opinion on family firms often has a positive bias because family firms focus on long-term objectives and account for a large part of employment in many countries around the world (Klein, 2000; Le Breton-Miller & Miller, 2006). Scholars are interested in family firms because they are distinctly different from non-family firms in particular with respect to firm goals and interactions between different stakeholder groups (e.g., Chrisman, Chua, & Litz, 2004; Gómez-Mejía, Haynes, Nuñez-Nickel, Jacobson, & Moyano-Fuentes, 2007). These distinct differences are caused by strong family influence relative to the influence of non-family shareholders. Thus, although there is still no widely accepted definition of family firms (e.g., Astrachan, Klein, & Smyrnios, 2002; Klein, Astrachan, & Smyrnios, 2005; Chrisman & Patel, 2012), most definitions of family firms focus on whether a family controls a certain percentage of the respective firm's equity. The threshold of required family ownership to fulfill the various definitions usually ranges from 5% (Anderson, Mansi, & Reeb, 2003) to 50% (Coleman & Carsky, 1999). The European Commission (2009) defines family firms as firms in which 'the person who established or acquired the firm or their families or descendants possess 25% of the decision-making rights'. I follow this definition because under German law 25% equity ownership allows families to block major firm decisions (Franks & Mayer, 2001). Financing of family firms is important because the availability of financial resources is one of the main determinants of long-term survival of family firms Introduction 2 (Romano, Tanewski, & Smyrnios, 2000). In particular, small family firms find it difficult to obtain financial resources (e.g., Coleman & Carsky, 1999; Harvey & Evans, 1995; Maherault, 2000). In recent years, the introduction of Basel II and the financial crisis starting in 2008 have reduced the availability of bank loans which traditionally were the main source of capital for many family firms (Heid, 2007; Ivashina & Scharfstein, 2010; Romano et al., 2000). The link between the availability of financial resources and family firm survival is even more important given that only 30% of family firms survive past the first generation and only 15% of family firms survive past the third generation (Davis & Harveston, 1998; Handler, 1990). An initial public offering (IPO) is a potential solution to the financing difficulties of many family firms. Compared to bank loans and other forms of financial debt, an IPO allows a family firm to raise capital while reducing its leverage and thus its bankruptcy risk (Baker & Wurgler, 2002). Compared to external equity from private equity investors, an IPO allows a family firm to better protect family control (Cronqvist & Nilsson, 2005). Previous studies have shown that even ten years after an IPO, many families continue to control their respective firms (Ehrhardt & Nowak, 2003). Options for ensuring prolonged family control of the respective firm after an IPO include issuing non-voting shares, bundling the family's shares in a holding, and ensuring a disproportionate representation of family members on the supervisory board of the firm (Cronqvist & Nilsson, 2005; Gorton & Schmid, 2000; Holmén & Högfeldt, 2004; Masulis, Pham, & Zein, 2011; Villalonga & Amit, 2008). In summary, family firms are a crucial part of our economy, their survival depends (among other factors) on the availability of financial resources, and an IPO Introduction 3 offers the potential to raise financial resources while maintaining family control. A better understanding of family firm IPOs might convince more family members to consider an IPO and more non-family investors to invest in family firms. In this context, it is important to understand the goals of both family members and non- family investors in order to reconcile potentially diverging goals. Theoretical foundation: Agency theory and socioemotional wealth (SEW) An IPO can strongly impact a family firm because the family normally has to partly cede control to non-family investors. Thus, an additional stakeholder group is introduced to the firm, which can result in additional conflicts between different stakeholder groups. Moreover, family-specific non-economic goals such as creating and sustaining a family dynasty (Casson, 1999) are more difficult
Recommended publications
  • Chapter 10 the Pecking Order, Trade-Off, Signaling, and Market
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by AMH International (E-Journals) Journal of Education and Vocational Research Vol. 3, No. 11, pp. 353-369, Nov 2012 (ISSN 2221-2590) Managers versus Students: New Approach in Improving Capital Structure Education Anton Miglo School of Business, University of Bridgeport, Bridgeport [email protected] Abstract: According to Graham and Harvey (2001), an immense gap exists between capital structure theories and practice. By analyzing students’ perception of capital structure theories and the differences between their opinion and that of the current CEO’s and managers this paper argues that this can be partially explained by current educational practices. Educators mostly focus on one or maybe two most popular theories and students have much smaller knowledge about other theories. Secondly educational practices favor trade-off theory to asymmetric information based theories. The paper provides some suggestions regarding capital structure education and future research. Keywords: Capital structure education, trade-off theory, pecking-order theory, shareholders-bondholders conflict, life cycle theory, flexibility theory, debt, and discipline 1. Introduction The modern theory of capital structure began with the famous proposition of Modigliani and Miller (1958) that described the conditions of capital structure irrelevance. Since then, many theories of capital structure have been developed including trade off theory, pecking order theory, agency cost theory, life cycle theory and flexibility theory. After so many innovations, capital structure remains one of the most controversial and debatable issue in corporate finance. The key issues are as follows. First, an immense gap exists between theories and practice.
    [Show full text]
  • Testing the Trade Off and Pecking Order Models of Capital Structure
    IOSR Journal of Economics and Finance (IOSR-JEF) e-ISSN: 2321-5933, p-ISSN: 2321-5925.Volume 5, Issue 6. Ver. I (Nov.-Dec. 2014), PP 08-14 www.iosrjournals.org Testing the Trade Off and Pecking Order Models of Capital Structure Mr. Ashiqur Rahman 1, S.M. Arifuzzaman2 1 (Lecturer, Dept. of Business Administration, Northern University Bangladesh) 2(Assistant Professor, BRAC Business School) Abstract: In this paper, we test two-models of capital structure by using Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) approach for finding the capital structure behaviour of U.K. firms, whether firms follow pecking order or trade off model. Sample size consists of 60 firms and 51 firms; observation period ranges from 1992 - 2012 and 1995 - 2012. By using panel data regression in the two-sample size and periods, empirical results show that neither model is appropriate for giving any conclusive result for the capital structure behaviour of U.K. firms. Keywords: capital structure, pecking order, trade off model, empirical, behaviour of U.K. firms. I. Introduction "How do firms choose their capital structures?" The answer is, "We don't know." Stewart. C. Myers (1984) How do firms should choose their capital structures to maximise the value of the firm it is one of the most debatable topics in the field of corporate finance for more than 50 years. Modigliani and Miller (1958) find that capital structures do not matter for maximising the value of the firm in a perfectly competitive market.1 From that onwards, capital structure issue has been a rising concern among corporations as well as for many academicians.
    [Show full text]
  • Evidence from the Prague Stock Exchange
    2019, Vol. 7, No. 1 10.15678/EBER.2019.070110 Why Do Companies Go Public? Evidence from the Prague Stock Exchange Martina Skalická, Marek Zinecker, Adam P. Balcerzak, Tomáš Meluzín A B S T R A C T Objective: In this article, we intend to contribute evidence in regard to going public motivation on a sample of companies that launched an IPO at the Prague Stock Ex- change between 2004 and 2017. Research Design & Methods: In order to evaluate the prevailing motives for the IPO launch, we design and apply a set of composite indicators the values of which may be understood as an indication of the extent to which IPO launch motives originate in the zone of the issuing company’s needs or in the zone of interest of its owner (owners). Findings: Our main conclusion is that the dominant going public motivation is to allow current shareholders to cash out and to enhance the company´s publicity and image. Implications & Recommendations: Since the study disclosed that the prevailing motive of primary issues at the Prague Stock Exchange was the exit of investors and enhancing publicity and image we suggest that companies launching the Prague Stock Exchange in recent years were predominantly determined by non-financial aspects. Thus, the re- search findings represent substantial implications for issuers, investment bankers, the stock exchange, and macroeconomic policy makers when the concept of incentive schemes how to increase the attractiveness of the local capital market will be proposed. Contribution & Value Added: Our set of composite indicators allows to assess not only the predominant IPO motive zone, but also measure the intensity of the motives.
    [Show full text]
  • A Test of the Pecking Order Theory of Capital Structure in Corporate Finance
    Accounting & Taxation Vol. 7, No. 2, 2015, pp. 43-49 ISSN: 1944-592X (print) www.theIBFR.com ISSN: 2157-0175 (online) A TEST OF THE PECKING ORDER THEORY OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE IN CORPORATE FINANCE Ali Shakil Khan, Swinburne University of Technology Sarawak Awang Yusop Adom, Swinburne University of Technology Sarawak ABSTRACT This paper utilises a cross section of 12,244 publicly traded corporations in the U.S. from the time period 1999 to 2009 to test the pecking order theory of capital structure. Applying the methodology of Frank and Goyal (2003), limited evidence to support pecking order theory is found. Consistent with Frank and Goyal (2003), a much stronger relationship between net equity issued and financing deficit is observed than net debt issuance and financing deficit. Whereas, the pecking order theory suggests that firms should exhaust all debt issuing capacity before they issue any equity and equity should only be used as a last resort. JEL: G3 KEYWORDS: Pecking Order Theory, Capital Structure, Financing Deficit INTRODUCTION ecking order theory is a prominent hypothesis put forward to explain corporate financing flows. The main purpose of this paper is to test how well the pecking order theory can actually explain the P corporate financing patterns during the testing period. The data is obtained from the Compustat database which contains all financial statements of US public-listed companies for 1999-2009. The formal tests are based on the methodologies used by Frank and Goyal (2003), and the dataset begins at the approximate time at which theirs concluded. The correlation coefficients between net equity, debt financing and firm financing deficit are examined and it is found that equity financing is highly correlated with financing deficit (0.87).
    [Show full text]
  • How Do Cfos Make Capital Budgeting and Capital Structure
    HOW DO CFOS MAKE by John Graham and Campbell Harvey, CAPITAL BUDGETING Duke University* AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS? e recently conducted a comprehensive survey that analyzed the current practice of corporate finance, with particular focus on the W areas of capital budgeting and capital structure. The survey results enabled us to identify aspects of corporate practice that are consistent with finance theory, as well as aspects that are hard to reconcile with what we teach in our business schools today. In presenting these results, we hope that some practitioners will find it worthwhile to observe how other companies operate and perhaps modify their own practices. It may also be useful for finance academics to consider differences between theory and practice as a reason to revisit the theory. We solicited responses from approximately 4,440 companies and received 392 completed surveys, representing a wide variety of firms and industries.1 The survey contained nearly 100 questions and explored both capital budgeting and capital structure decisions in depth. The responses to these questions enabled us to explore whether and how these corporate policies are interrelated. For example, we investigated whether companies that made more aggressive use of debt financing also tended to use more sophisticated capital budgeting techniques, perhaps because of their greater need for discipline and precision in the corporate investment process. More generally, the design of our survey allowed for a richer under- standing of corporate decision-making by analyzing the CFOs’ responses in the context of various company characteristics, such as size, P/E ratio, leverage, credit rating, dividend policy, and industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Nguyen Quang Diep
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Waseda University Repository AY 2011 SEASONED EQUITY OFFERINGS IN VIETNAM Examining investors’ capability in assessing long-run operating performance of the issuers NGUYEN QUANG DIEP Major in Business Administration 35092313-7 GRADUATE SCHOOL OF COMMERCE WASEDA UNIVERSITY PROF.NAGAI TAKESHI C.E. PROF.HIGASHIDE HIRONORI D.E. PROF.TAKIGUCHI TADASHI Table of Contents CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION................................................................................... 1 1.1 The concept of Seasoned equity offering ............................................................................ 1 1.2 Overview of Seasoned equity offerings in Vietnam............................................................ 3 1.3 Scope of Objectives........................................................................................................... 10 1.4 Outline of research methodology ...................................................................................... 10 1.5 Thesis structure.................................................................................................................. 11 CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW..................................................................... 13 2. 1 Capital structure theories and implications on SEO......................................................... 13 2.2 SEOs and long-run post-issue operating performance of the issuers ................................ 22 2.3 The twenty SEOs-assessing criteria
    [Show full text]
  • Asymmetric Information and the Pecking (Dis)Order∗
    Asymmetric information and the pecking (dis)order∗ Paolo Fulghieriy Diego Garc´ıaz Dirk Hackbarthx January 23, 2020 Abstract We study the classical problem of raising capital under asymmetric information. Following Myers and Majluf (1984), we consider firms endowed with assets in place and riskier growth opportunities. When asymmetric information is concentrated on assets in place (rather than growth opportunities), equity-like securities are more likely to be optimal. In contrast, when asymmetric information falls on growth options, debt is optimal. Intuitively, this happens because when the asset with greater volatility is less affected by asymmetric information, issuing a security with greater exposure to upside potential (such as equity) can be less dilutive than issuing a security lacking such exposure (such as debt). Our results suggest that equity is more likely to dominate debt for younger firms with larger investment needs, endowed with riskier, more valuable growth opportunities. Thus, our model can explain why high-growth firms may prefer equity over debt, and then switch to debt financing as they mature. JEL classification: D82, G32. Keywords: debt-equity choice, pecking order, asymmetric information, security design. ∗We would like to thank an anonymous referee, Rajesh Aggarwal, David Brown, Miguel Cantillo, Alex David, David Dicks, Alex Edmans (the editor), Nick Gantchev, Nicolae Garleanu, Christopher Hennessy, Preetesh Kantak, Andrew Karolyi, Stewart Myers, Roni Michaely, Tom Noe, Jacob Sagi, Martin Schmalz, Merih Sevilir, Matt
    [Show full text]
  • The Consequences of Post-Merger & Acquisition Performance in Listed
    The Consequences of Post-Merger & Acquisition Performance in Listed and Non-Listed Companies in Sweden A Case Study for AstraZeneca AB, Cybercom Group AB, Grant Thornton Sweden AB and PayEx Authors: Emmanuel Kwaasi Adjei and Kelvin Ubabuko Subject: Master Thesis in Business Administration 15 ECTS Program: Master of International Management Gotland University Autumn semester 2011 Supervisor: Adri de Ridder Abstract Empirical research findings on the consequences of post-M&A performance have generated several result, although most of which are inconsistent. The relation of such post-M&A performances to non-listed and listed companies can be relative especially when considering the companies economic and financial structure and other prevailing factors associated to the host country. However, most of these have been attributed to the choice of performance measurement indicators. This paper analyses and evaluates existing performance indicators that have been employed in the literature. It is argued that to overcome the limitations found in financial indicators of performance, a need to pursue multiple measures of performance in post-M&A research is needed. It also argues that the motives for the transaction should also be included as performance indicators. This hybrid approach will allow researchers and practitioners to measure the overall success of merger and acquisitions. Keywords: Post-Merger and Acquisition Performance; Synergy Rationales; Return on Equity; Return on Capital Employed Contents 1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................................1
    [Show full text]
  • The Pecking Order, Debt Capacity, and Information Asymmetry
    The Pecking Order, Debt Capacity, and Information Asymmetry Mark T. Leary and Michael R. Roberts* This Version: December 18, 2008 *Leary is from the Finance Department, Johnson Graduate School of Management, Cornell Uni- versity, Ithaca, NY 14853-6201. Email: [email protected]. Roberts is from the Finance Depart- ment, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104-6367. Email: mr- [email protected]. This study originated as part of an earlier working paper, \Financial Slack and Tests of the Pecking Order's Financing Hierarchy". We are especially grateful to Michael Lemmon for his continuous feedback. We also thank Lincoln Berger, Philip Bond, Michael Brandt, Alon Brav, Omer Brav, Peter DeMarzo, Adlai Fisher, John Graham, Christopher Hennessy, Peter Mackay, An- drew Metrick, Roni Michaely, Nathalie Moyen, Mitchell Petersen, Ilya Strebulaev, Michelle Vosko, Bilge Yilmaz, Jaime Zender, Ian Zuckerman, Je®rey Zwiebel, seminar participants at Cornell University, Uni- versity of California at Berkeley, Duke University, Stanford University, Stockholm School of Economics, The University of North Carolina-Chapel Hill, Utah University, and The University of Pennsylvania, and conference participants at the 2005 Eastern Finance Association meetings, the UBC Summer Fi- nance Conference, and the 2005 HKUST Finance Conference for helpful comments. Roberts gratefully acknowledges ¯nancial support from the Rodney L. White Center and an NYSE Research Fellowship. The Pecking Order, Debt Capacity, and Information Asymmetry Abstract We quantify the empirical relevance of the pecking order hypothesis using a novel empirical model and testing strategy that addresses statistical power concerns with previous tests. While the classi¯catory ability of the pecking order varies signif- icantly depending on whether one interprets the hypothesis in a strict or liberal (e.g., \modi¯ed" pecking order) manner, the pecking order is never able to accu- rately classify more than half of the observed ¯nancing decisions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effect of Firm and Country Specific Factors on the Capital Structure
    The effect of firm and country specific factors on the capital structure Abstract This paper takes into consideration the major theories about capital structures and evaluates these ideas to determine which of them relate to corporate financing choices. What unique is in this paper is that it examines the influence the financial crisis had on the capital structure several years after it occurred in 2008. The main results and conclusions are that the tax rate has a significantly negative relationship with the leverage level, however, this relationship was expected to be positive because of the tax benefits. This research finds that the size of firms is significantly positive related to the leverage ratio. Furthermore, this research finds that profit is significantly negative related to the leverage ratio. These results are matching with the theories. However, the relationship between the age and the leverage ratio does not yield a significant outcome, most likely owed to the large time frame of the data sample. The financial crisis had, as was expected, a significant positive relationship with the leverage ratio. In this research, the relation of debt maturity with leverage ratio remains unexplained. Student number: s2972298 Name: Maudy Nijhuis Study program: MSc Finance Date: June 6th, 2018 1. Introduction Corporate financing choices can be determined by different factors that are related to firm and country specific characteristics. Since the paper of Modigliani and Miller (1958), which will be taken a look at in the literature review, there has been a lot of research about corporate financing choices. Studies such as Rajan and Zingales (1995), Wald (1999), and De Jong, Kabir and Nguyen (2008) examined the corporate financing choices of firms.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Existence of an Optimal Capital Structure
    California State University, San Bernardino CSUSB ScholarWorks Theses Digitization Project John M. Pfau Library 2003 The capital structure puzzle: On the existence of an optimal capital structure Mohamed Lahiani Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.lib.csusb.edu/etd-project Part of the Corporate Finance Commons Recommended Citation Lahiani, Mohamed, "The capital structure puzzle: On the existence of an optimal capital structure" (2003). Theses Digitization Project. 2350. https://scholarworks.lib.csusb.edu/etd-project/2350 This Project is brought to you for free and open access by the John M. Pfau Library at CSUSB ScholarWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Theses Digitization Project by an authorized administrator of CSUSB ScholarWorks. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE PUZZLE: ON THE EXISTENCE OF AN OPTIMAL CAPITAL STRUCTURE A Proj ect Presented to the Faculty of California State University, San Bernardino In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Business Administration by Mohamed Lahiani September 2003 THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE PUZZLE: ON THE EXISTENCE OF AN OPTIMAL CAPITAL STRUCTURE A Project Presented to the Faculty of California State University, San Bernardino by Mohamed Lahiani September 2003 Approved by: 7/A Date Dr. Taewon Yang Dr. Otto Chang, Department CJ Accounting & Finance 1 © 2003 Mohamed Lahiani ABSTRACT A perennial debate in corporate finance concerns the question of optimal capital structure: given the level of total capital necessary to support a company's activities, is there a way of dividing up that capital into debt and equity that maximizes current firm value? And, if so, what are the critical factors in setting the leverage ratio for a given company? Corporate finance researchers have long been puzzled by low corporate debt ratios given debt's corporate tax advantage.
    [Show full text]
  • Circle One Answer That Is the Best. (2.5 Points Each) 1
    AFM 372 Fall 2006 Key Midterm Examination I. Multiple choice questions: Circle one answer that is the best. (2.5 points each) 1. A bond issued by Owers Divestiture Corporation on July 1, 2005 has the following features: face value $1,000, annual interest rate of 8%, maturity date July 1, 2010, semi-annual interest payments on July 1 and January 1 each year. How much is the accrued interest if an investor buys the bond on Sept. 1, 2006? A) $13.33 B) $26.67 C) $40.00 D) $80.00 E) $120.00 1. Answer: A. Accrued interest on Sept 1 = (.08/12) (2) (1000) = $13.33 Use the information below to answer questions 2 and 3: The shareholders of the Unicorn Company need to elect five new directors. There are one million shares outstanding. 2. At least how many shares should you own to be certain that you can elect two directors if the company has straight voting? A) 500,001 B) 500,000 C) 1 million D) 333,334 E) 166,667 3. At least how many shares should you own to be certain that you can elect one director if the company has cumulative voting? A) 500,001 B) 500,000 C) 1 million D) 333,334 E) 166,667 4. Consider two corporations, G and H, that have exactly the same risk. They both have a current stock price of $60. Corporation G pays no dividend and will have a price of $66 one year from now. Corporation H pays dividends and will have a price of $63 one year from now after payment of a dividend.
    [Show full text]