Factors of Urbanisation in the Nineteenth Century Developed Countries: a Descriptive and Econometric Analysis

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Factors of Urbanisation in the Nineteenth Century Developed Countries: a Descriptive and Econometric Analysis Urban Studies (1986) 23, 285-305 © 1986 Urban Studies Factors of Urbanisation in the Nineteenth Century Developed Countries: A Descriptive and Econometric Analysis Paul Bairoch and Gary Goertz [First received January 1985; in finalform October 1985] Summary. This paper describes the situation from the beginning of the industrial revolution when levels of urbanisation were dependent on geography and the historical situation and when the general level of urbanisation was low, through the nineteenth century in which agricultural productivity and industrialisation determined the levels of urbanisation. This period represents a dramatic increase in the levels of urbanisation during which the present urban structures were put into place. A comparative econometric study, finds that economic growth pushed urbanisation, with industrialisation being the most important factor for Europe and agricultural productivity being quite important for the European settled countries. Other important factors are found to be, trade, total population, topography, and form of industrialisation. Railroad networks more or less extensive than normal were not found to be influential. 1. Introduction and overview rose from 15 per cent to 34 per cent. Importantly, this level of urbanisation was achieved without the The 19th century, and particularly the period be- massive imports of foodstuffs from other countries. tween 1820-30 and 1914, constitutes a turning point The England of the 1830s was certainly no longer a between a society still essentially rural and a devel- region with a surplus of cereals despite being called oped, urbanised society prefiguring that of the end the 'breadbasket' of Europe by contemporaries in of the the 20th century, a society in which over 90 the middle of the 18th century. However, with its per cent of the population would no longer be imports consituting 4-6 per cent of its food needs, it involved in agriculture, even if some of these might was also not the England of the end of the 19th still live in the countryside. It is no exaggeration to century which, like the Netherlands of the 17th say that, with the exception of the USSR and also century or certain Italian city-states of the 13-14th Japan,' the present urban system was almost in century, fed its urban population largely with im- place at the eve of World War I. ported cereals. Around 1700, London with its Certainly around 1830, England, the cradle of the 550,000 inhabitants was along with Paris, one of the industrial revolution, had already behind it a large largest cities of Europe, but that continent and even part of what one might call the 'urban transition', more so Asia had known cities twice as large. How- since from around 1700 to 1830 the English popula- ever, towards 1830 London or Greater London (the tion living in cities of more than 5,000 inhabitants metropolitan area of London) already had 1.5 million Paul Bairoch is Professor of Economic History at the University of Geneva, Gary Goertz holds appointments in the University of Michigan and the University of Geneva. The authors would like to thank Professors H. Glejser, of the University of Brussels and P. Balestra and F. Calevaro of the University of Geneva for having read and criticised earlier versions of this paper. They are, of course, not responsible for the views expressed here. 'Japan and South Africa are not included in this study because their social and economic structures are too different from the other developed countries. All references, except when otherwise noted, to developed countries are to be understood as excluding Japan and South Africa. 285 286 PAUL BAIROCH AND GARY GOERTZ inhabitants, which made it the largest city of the period Table 2 and maybe the largest in history up to that time. This Evolution of the number of great cities in the developed world was certainly the case by 1851 when a census reported that London had 2.4 million inhabitants. City sizes 1580 1700 1800 1914 1980 (thousands) But because the England of 1830, with a total population of 14 million inhabitants, represented 100-200 3 9 16 138 457 only 5 per cent of the population of the future 200-500 1 I 6 84 334 500-1000 - 2 1 47 115 developed world, the urban structure of this future 1000-5000 - - I 10 93 developed world was but marginally changed. In 5000 and more - - - 2 7 1830, the level of urbanisation of the future devel- Total 4 12 24 281 1006 oped world was close to that of previous centuries Sources.: Adapted from (see Table 1). At this date, the level of urbanisation 2 Bairoch (1985). can be estimated at 12.3 per cent, compared with the growth of already existing cities, but also a about 10-11 per cent in 1700, the level of urbanisa- period 'par excellence' of the emergence of new tion increasing by only about 0.1I per cent per year. cities. The long term evolution of the urban struc- This moderate increase during the 18th century ture measured by city size is summarised in Table 2. continued a trend already established during the The number of large cities (more than 100,000 preceding two centuries. However, by the eve of inhabitants) which doubled between 1700 and 1800 World War I, this level was 36 per cent (43 per cent increased by a factor of 12 between 1800 and 1914. excluding Russia). Hence, between 1830 and 1914, As for very large cities (more than 500,000) these the level of urbanisation increased by 1.3 per cent increased by a factor of 200 during the 19th century. per year, the urban population by 2.3 per cent per If these changes are essentially the result of the year, while from 1914 to 1980 these increased respec- growth of the size of the city, the 19th century is also tively by 0.4 per cent and 1.7 per cent. Thus, the the period in urban history which saw the birth of developed world of around 1830 had only one city of the largest number of new cities. Effectively, of the over a million inhabitants became that of 1914 with approximately 268 cities of more than 100000 twelve such cities, the largest of which being London inhabitants in the developed world around 1910, with more than 7 million inhabitants. some 98 did not exist or were villages at the begin- The period studied here is not only a key period in ning of the 19th century (or in England in the middle of the 18th century). The proportion must be higher Table for smaller cities so that one can estimate that 40 per Long term evolution of urbanisation of the developed countries cent of the cities of more than 50,000 existing in 1910 were new cities or became cities during the 19th Total Urban Level of population population urbanisation century. After World War I very few new cities were (millions) (millions) (%) created, except in the USSR, although in 1930 there began the creation of new planned cities, these, 1300 80-100 7-9 7.0-9.0 1500 85-105 8-9 7.0-9.0 however, being created largely in order to alleviate 1700 135 160 14-17 10.0-11.0 the congestion of large existing urban agglomera- 1800 211 23 10.7 tions. 1830 255 31 12.3 1880 405 95 23.6 It is also important to examine the various factors 1914 600 215 35.7 both economic and non-economic which led to the 1950 749 353 47.1 urbanisation of 19th century Europe as well as those 1980 992 659 66.4 other countries now qualified as developed. It is in Source.: 1800-1914: see Table 3; other data adapted from the period 1830-1914 that Europe undertook urban- Bairoch, P., De Jericho d Mexico: Villes et conomie dans isation at its fastest rate. It is on Europe that this l'Histoire, 1985. Note: The degree of rounding of the figures does not imply a study will concentrate in the econometric analysis in correspondingly low margin of error. the second section, although the European settled 2 From this point on, except when indicated to the contrary, we will consider urban population as defined by cities of 5,000 inhabitants or more. See Appendix Al. URBANISATION IN THE NINETEENTH CENTURY DEVELOPED COUNTRIES 287 countries (i.e. Australia, Canada, New Zealand and by the industrial revolution. The most striking fact is the USA) will also be included. One purpose of this the large spread in the level of urbanisation of the study is to try to move beyond the explanation of various countries. Around 1800, between the least the level of urbanisation in terms of the level of urbanised country (Finland) and the most (the Gross National Product per capita and to consider Netherlands) the spread is from 1 to 12. The urban economic factors in somewhat more detail and, in situation in these various countries around 1800 is addition, to consider social, demographic and struc- still very marked by their several hundred and even tural factors which may contribute to or constrain several thousand years of previous history. In the the urbanisation of a society. It should be recalled previous several hundred years, if one excludes the that in 1800, when the disparities in GNP per capita United Kingdom, the six most urbanised countries were reasonably small, less than a 2 to range, (in decreasing order: the Netherlands, Belgium, already the level of urbanisation of the Netherlands Italy, Spain, Denmark and Portugal) have an urban was four times that of Germany while its GNP per network that is the result of previous periods of capita was only roughly one-third higher, and that commercial power already long past.
Recommended publications
  • The Great Divergence the Princeton Economic History
    THE GREAT DIVERGENCE THE PRINCETON ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE WESTERN WORLD Joel Mokyr, Editor Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815, by Philip T. Hoffman The Vanishing Irish: Households, Migration, and the Rural Economy in Ireland, 1850–1914, by Timothy W. Guinnane Black ’47 and Beyond: The Great Irish Famine in History, Economy, and Memory, by Cormac k Gráda The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, by Kenneth Pomeranz THE GREAT DIVERGENCE CHINA, EUROPE, AND THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD ECONOMY Kenneth Pomeranz PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON AND OXFORD COPYRIGHT 2000 BY PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PUBLISHED BY PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, 41 WILLIAM STREET, PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY 08540 IN THE UNITED KINGDOM: PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, 3 MARKET PLACE, WOODSTOCK, OXFORDSHIRE OX20 1SY ALL RIGHTS RESERVED LIBRARY OF CONGRESS CATALOGING-IN-PUBLICATION DATA POMERANZ, KENNETH THE GREAT DIVERGENCE : CHINA, EUROPE, AND THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD ECONOMY / KENNETH POMERANZ. P. CM. — (THE PRINCETON ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE WESTERN WORLD) INCLUDES BIBLIOGRAPHICAL REFERENCES AND INDEX. ISBN 0-691-00543-5 (CL : ALK. PAPER) 1. EUROPE—ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—18TH CENTURY. 2. EUROPE—ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—19TH CENTURY. 3. CHINA— ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—1644–1912. 4. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT—HISTORY. 5. COMPARATIVE ECONOMICS. I. TITLE. II. SERIES. HC240.P5965 2000 337—DC21 99-27681 THIS BOOK HAS BEEN COMPOSED IN TIMES ROMAN THE PAPER USED IN THIS PUBLICATION MEETS THE MINIMUM REQUIREMENTS OF ANSI/NISO Z39.48-1992 (R1997) (PERMANENCE OF PAPER) WWW.PUP.PRINCETON.EDU PRINTED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 3579108642 Disclaimer: Some images in the original version of this book are not available for inclusion in the eBook.
    [Show full text]
  • Tena Istambul05
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Universidad Carlos III de Madrid e-Archivo The good reputation of late XIX century protectionism: manufacture versus total protection in the European tariff growth debate. Antonio Tena Universidad Carlos III [email protected] “Although import substitution policies have gradually lost their shine over the postwar period, their reputation has remained intact for the late nineteenth century” (Irwin, D. (2001) p. 1.) Paper presented to the 6th Conference of EHES in Istambul (This is a very preliminary work please do not quote) Antonio Tena Junguito Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Despacho 7.55 e-mail: [email protected] C/. Madrid 126.- 28 903 Getafe (Madrid) Tel: (34)91-624 96 20 .- Fax: (34) 91-624 95 74 1 The good reputation of late XIX century protectionism: manufacture versus total protection in the European tariff growth debate. Antonio Tena Universidad Carlos III [email protected] “Although import substitution policies have gradually lost their shine over the postwar period, their reputation has remained intact for the late nineteenth century” (Irwin, D. (2001) p. 1. Abstract: In the tariff growth debate, especially for Europe late XIX century, the important question is: was protection a successful policy to foster industrialization? Total tariff average may not only provide little information for interpreting the tariff mechanism causation to growth but perhaps an erroneous one. This paper try to make more explicit the relation between industrial, agricultural and fiscal tariffs to clear the mechanism of causation between tariffs and growth.
    [Show full text]
  • A Cape of Asia: Essays on European History
    A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 1 a cape of asia A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 2 A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 3 A Cape of Asia essays on european history Henk Wesseling leiden university press A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 4 Cover design and lay-out: Sander Pinkse Boekproductie, Amsterdam isbn 978 90 8728 128 1 e-isbn 978 94 0060 0461 nur 680 / 686 © H. Wesseling / Leiden University Press, 2011 All rights reserved. Without limiting the rights under copyright reserved above, no part of this book may be reproduced, stored in or introduced into a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means (electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise) without the written permission of both the copyright owner and the author of the book. A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 5 Europe is a small cape of Asia paul valéry A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 6 For Arnold Burgen A Cape of Asia.indd | Sander Pinkse Boekproductie | 10-10-11 / 11:44 | Pag. 7 Contents Preface and Introduction 9 europe and the wider world Globalization: A Historical Perspective 17 Rich and Poor: Early and Later 23 The Expansion of Europe and the Development of Science and Technology 28 Imperialism 35 Changing Views on Empire and Imperialism 46 Some Reflections on the History of the Partition
    [Show full text]
  • PAUL BAIROCH Elise S
    New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2008 PAUL BAIROCH Elise S. Brezis Paul Bairoch was born in Antwerp in 1930. He was the son of a Jewish family that emigrated from Poland to Belgium in the 1920s, and that later went into exile in a small village in Gers, France during World War II. After the war, Bairoch moved to Brussels, later spent a short period in Israel, and started studying economic history upon his return to Belgium. While a research fellow at the University of Brussels, Bairoch developed statistical time series on the national statistics of Belgium, worked on his doctorate, and in 1963, presented his thesis, titled “The Starting Process of Economic Growth”. He then went on to teach in a number of universities and even worked at GATT for a time. From 1972 onwards, Bairoch was a member of the faculty at the University of Geneva, where he was director of the Center of International Economic History until his death in 1999 in Geneva. A trait common to all Bairoch’s research in economic history from his thesis onwards was that he based his opinions on data, and when the data did not exist, he found a way to collect or construct it. Bairoch can be seen as a pioneer of cliometrics, and believed that without data and statistical information, economic history is left to eradication. David Landes (1998, p.XIII) even gave Bairoch the nickname “collector and calculator of the numbers of growth and productivity”. Another characteristic typical of Bairoch’s research is that he was not afraid to be non-conformist and present views that ran against the mainstream.
    [Show full text]
  • Tariffs the World Around 1870-1938
    Who Protected and Why? Tariffs the World Around 1870-1938 by Christopher Blattman University of California - Berkeley Michael A. Clemens Center for Global Development Jeffrey G. Williamson Harvard University August 2002 Paper to be presented to the Conference on the Political Economy of Globalization, Trinity College, Dublin (August 29-31, 2002). We have received superb research assistance from Martin Kanz and István Zöllei. In addition, we are grateful to many who have helped in our search for country tariff and other data used in this paper: Luis Bertola, Alan Dye, Bouda Etemad, David Feeny, Aurora Gomez, Paul Gregory, Pedro Lains, Peter Lindert, Ian McLean, Anna Maria Mayda, Sevket Pamuk, Dwight Perkins, Gunnar Persson, Leandro Prados, Paul Rhode, Athanasios Vamvakidis, and Tarik Yousef. We also benefitted from comments from Graciella Marquez Colin, Richard Cooper, Ron Findlay, Jeff Frieden, Steve Haber, Elhanan Helpman, Doug Irwin, Dani Rodrik, Dick Salvucci, Ken Sokoloff, Alan Taylor and seminar participants at a Harvard/IADB conference and the University of Uruguay. Most important, the paper draws extensively on a Latin American tariff paper written by Williamson with John Coatsworth, who the authors are pleased to thank publically. Remaining errors belong to us. Williamson acknowledges with pleasure financial support from the National Science Foundation SES-0001362, and all three authors thank the Center for International Development for allocating office space to the project. The post-conference revision of this paper will contain
    [Show full text]
  • Models of the Developmental State
    Models of the developmental state Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira Abstract This paper seeks to understand the developmental state and its historical role in industrial revolutions and afterwards. First, the developmental state is defined as an alternative to the liberal state. Second, it is argued that industrial revolutions have always taken place within the framework of a developmental state. Third, four models of developmental states are defined according to the point in time at which the industrial revolution took place and the central or peripheral character of the country. Fourth, the paper describes how the state withdraws partially from the economy after the industrial revolution, but the developmental state continues to have a major role in directing industrial policy and in conducting an active macroeconomic policy. Keywords Public administration, economic planning, macroeconomics, liberalism, nationalism, economic policy, economic development JEL classification O10, O11, O19 Author Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira is an Emeritus Professor with the Department of Economics of the Sao Paulo School of Economics, Getulio Vargas Foundation, Brazil. Email: [email protected]. 36 CEPAL Review N° 128 • August 2019 I. Introduction In the 1950s, Brazilian political scientists and economists identified “developmentalism” as a set of political ideas and economic strategies that drove Brazil’s rapid industrialization and underpinned the coalition of social classes identified with national development. Hélio Jaguaribe (1962, p. 208) stated in the early 1960s that “the core thesis of developmentalism is that the promotion of economic development and the consolidation of nationality stand as two correlated aspects of a single emancipatory process”. Through “national developmentalism”, which would become the established term for the country’s development strategy, Brazilian society was successfully overcoming the patrimonial state that characterized its politics until 1930.
    [Show full text]
  • Current Urban Studies Concentration Worksheet
    Urban Studies Concentration Worksheet (updated September 2020) Name: ________________________________________________ Expected Date of Graduation: _______ Advisor:______________________________________ Engaged Scholar Program Y/N_______ Concentration Advisors: Profs. Rebecca Carter (ANTH), Tamar Katz (ENGL), James Morone (POLS), Dietrich Neumann (HIAA), Marion Orr (POLS), Josh Pacewicz (SOC), Kenneth Wong (EDUC), and Samuel Zipp (AMST). It is strongly encouraged that ALL concentration requirements be taken for a grade with the possible exception of the research methods requirement. Please use this worksheet to record your concentration requirements and bring it to your meeting with your advisor. 1. Introduction (1 course required) POLS 0220 City Politics URBN 0210 The City: An Introduction to Urban Studies URBN 0230 Urban Life in Providence: An Introduction (1st Year Seminar) 2. Research Methods (1 course required) APMA 0650 Essential Statistics APMA 1650 Statistical Inference I APMA 1660 Statistical Inference II CLPS 0900 Quantitative Methods in Psychology ECON 1620 Introduction to Econometrics EDUC 1110 Introductory Statistics for Education Research and Policy Analysis PHP 1501 Essentials of Data Analysis POLS 1600 Political Research Methods SOC 1020 Methods of Social Research SOC 1100 Introductory Statistics for Social Research 3. Basic Curriculum (Total of 6 courses required) a) Core Courses (3 courses required, in at least 3 disciplines, such as American Studies, anthropology, economics, education, history, history of art and architecture,
    [Show full text]
  • 9789287039125 World Trade Report 2013 En 72
    II. Trade and development: recent trends and the role of the WTO The World Trade Report 2014 looks at how many developing economies are successfully leveraging trade for rapid growth. It focuses on four recent trade trends – the rise of new global players, the spread of production chains, increasing commodity prices, and growing economic interdependence. These trends are transforming the way developing economies benefit from global economic integration. The rules, flexibilities, technical assistance and institutional infrastructure of the WTO have been helpful for developing economies to take advantage of, adapt to and mitigate risks arising from these four trends. The multilateral trading system itself will also need to continue to adapt, so that it can serve to realize the full development potential inherent in the world economy’s ongoing transformation. Contents A Introduction 40 B The increasing importance of developing countries in the global economy 52 C The rise of global value chains 78 D A new role for commodities in development strategies 128 E Increased synchronization and globalization of macroeconomic shocks 170 F The WTO and developing countries 188 G Conclusions 209 WORLD TRADE REPORT 2014 A. Introduction Globalization is transforming development. This section examines how, in its scope and speed, the recent rise of the developing world is unprecedented – eclipsing the rise of the newly industrializing countries after the Second World War, and dwarfing the earlier rise of Europe and North America in the late 19th century. There are many reasons why the developing world has achieved economic lift-off. One of the most important is its integration into the world economy – and the new access to markets, technology and investment that has resulted.
    [Show full text]
  • Urban History for Planners
    Portland State University PDXScholar Urban Studies and Planning Faculty Publications Nohad A. Toulan School of Urban Studies and and Presentations Planning 1-1-2006 Urban History for Planners Carl Abbott Portland State University Let us know how access to this document benefits ouy . Follow this and additional works at: http://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/usp_fac Part of the Urban Studies and Planning Commons Citation Details Abbott, Carl, "Urban History for Planners" (2006). Urban Studies and Planning Faculty Publications and Presentations. Paper 58. http://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/usp_fac/58 This Post-Print is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Urban Studies and Planning Faculty Publications and Presentations by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Urban History for Planners Carl Abbott School of Urban Studies and Planning Portland State University Portland, OR Prepublication version of: “Urban History for Planners,” Journal of Planning History, 5 (Nov. 2006). 1 Urban History for Planners Planning history and urban history are two different things. There’s plenty of overlap, of course, in scholarly topics and scholarly practitioners, but the two fields have developed distinct institutional structures and identities. There is a Journal of Planning History and a Journal of Urban History, the one edited from a Department of Urban Planning and the other from a Department of History. The Society for City and Regional Planning History took its initial energy and direction from planning professor Larry Gerckens. The Urban History Association took its initial impetus and guidance from history professors Kenneth Jackson and Michael Ebner.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Trade Policy and Economic Development
    1 TRADE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT The truth is that, historically, free trade is the exception and protectionism the rule. – Paul Bairoch, Economics and World History The streets of Quebec City are an unlikely place to find police in riot gear. First settled nearly four centuries ago, its old quarter normally evokes a romantic, old- world charm that attracts thousands of tourists annually. But not from 20 to 22 April 2001. That weekend, its visitors included the thirty-four democratically elected leaders of the Americas as well as an estimated 35,000 demonstrators determined to impress upon the leaders their disapproval of globalization, freer trade, and in- ternational trade negotiations. In order to avoid a repeat of the debacle that had marred the third ministerial meeting of the World Trade Organization in Seattle eighteen months earlier, the police relied on a temporary fence built around the perimeter of the conference site. Their strategy worked. The official meeting was able to pursue its task without incident. The protestors, however, also succeeded. As has become increasingly common- place, television found the motley array of dissidents and their message more visu- ally appealing and easier to report than the complex issues facing the leaders and their advisors. Unlike at Seattle, the leaders succeeded in adopting their communiqué and in giving renewed impetus to the quest for freer trade throughout the Ameri- cas. The protestors, not surprisingly, also claimed victory, and so the media re- ported. The goal of liberalizing international trade and investment and placing them on a more secure, rules-based footing seemed to be increasingly under attack, and the chances of ultimate success waning.
    [Show full text]
  • The Eurasian Divergence Debate: Europe and China in the Era of Mercantilism and the Industrial Revolution, 1368-18391
    The Eurasian Divergence Debate: Europe and China in the Era of Mercantilism and the Industrial Revolution, 1368-18391 Patrick O’Brien Centennial Professor of Economic History London School of Economics Email: p.o’[email protected] Smith, Marx and Weber Along with histories of hegemony and power, histories of material life and economic growth are the most popular of metanarratives currently published in the growing field of global history. Indeed no surprise will be occasioned by the appearance in our times, marked by ‘globalization’, of histories seeking to encompass a ‘world economy’, dealing with chronologies going back millennia and written to expound upon the disparate levels of material progress achieved by groups, societies, communities regional and national economies located on all continents. Such concerns continue to be the litmus test of the mission of global economic history to keep ‘humanity in view’. After all, most people, in most places for most of history have been preoccupied with obtaining food, shelter, clothing and other manufactured artefacts that they required to sustain either a basic, a comfortable and only latterly, an agreeable standard of living. Traditions of historical enquiry into the wealth and poverty of nations began with Herodotus but modern paradigms for investigation need be traced no further back than to the towering intellects of two cosmopolitan, but perhaps equally ‘Eurocentric’ Germans: Karl Marx and Max Weber. Both scholars maintained a serious interest (admittedly as a counterpoise to Europe) in the evolution of the Indian, Chinese, American and Russian economies. Although Weber’s investigations into Oriental religions, philosophies, cities and states look far more serious than anything written by Marx or Engles.
    [Show full text]
  • Tariff-Growth Nexus: an Analysis of One Hundred Years of Australian
    Working Papers in Trade and Development Tariff-Growth Nexus in the Australian Economy, 1870-2002: Is there a Paradox? Prema-chandra Athukorala And Satish Chand July 2007 Working Paper No. 2007/08 Division of Economics Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies ANU College of Asia and the Pacific Tariff-Growth Nexus in the Australian Economy, 1870-2002: Is there a Paradox? Prema-chandra Athukorala Economics Division Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies College of Asia and the Pacific The Australian National University [email protected] Satish Chand Crawford School of Economics and Government The Australian National University [email protected] Corresponding Address : Prema-chandra Athukorala Economics Division Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies College of Asia and the Pacific The Australian National University July 2007 Working paper No. 2007/08 This Working Paper series provides a vehicle for preliminary circulation of research results in the fields of economic development and international trade. The series is intended to stimulate discussion and critical comment. Staff and visitors in any part of the Australian National University are encouraged to contribute. To facilitate prompt distribution, papers are screened, but not formally refereed. Copies may be obtained from WWW Site http://rspas.anu.edu.au/economics/publications.php 1 Tariff-Growth Nexus in the Australian Economy, 1870-2002: Is there a Paradox? Prema-chandra Athukorala Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies Australian National University [email protected] Satish Chand Crawford School of Economics and Government Australian National University [email protected] Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between tariff and growth in the Australian economy over the period from 1871 to 2002.
    [Show full text]