The Patent System During the French Industrial Revolution: Institutional Change and Economic Effects Gabriel Galvez-Behar

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Patent System During the French Industrial Revolution: Institutional Change and Economic Effects Gabriel Galvez-Behar The Patent System during the French Industrial Revolution: Institutional Change and Economic Effects Gabriel Galvez-Behar To cite this version: Gabriel Galvez-Behar. The Patent System during the French Industrial Revolution: Institutional Change and Economic Effects. Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte / Economic History Yearbook, De Gruyter, 2019, Patent Law and Innovation in Europe during the Industrial Revolution, 60 (1), pp.31-56. 10.1515/jbwg-2019-0003. halshs-00544730v2 HAL Id: halshs-00544730 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00544730v2 Submitted on 13 Jun 2019 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Copyright The Patent System during the French Industrial Revolution: institutional change and economic efects Gabriel Galvez-Behar Université de Lille – Institut de recherches historiques du Septentrion Preprint Version For quotation, please re!er to Gabriel Galvez-Behar "#he Patent S$ste% during the French Industrial 'evolution ( Institutional Change and *conomic *fects, Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte special issue "Patent La- and Innovation in *urope during the Industrial 'evolution, edited b$ ./ 0onges and F/ Sel&ert vol/ 12 n° 4 5246 p. 31-56. [https(99doi.or&942/48489:b-g-2019-0003] Introduction #he role of institutions in economic development is a sharpl$ debated issue and the one pla$ed b$ intellectual propert$ is particularl$ discussed. #he ti%e is long gone -hen ;a< =eber could clai% -ithout real discussion that "-ithout the sti%ulus of [the? patent la- the inventions crucial !or the development of capitalis% in the @eld of te<tile industr$ in the 18th centur$ -ould nout have been possible,4/ Bot onl$ have patents been the subject of recurring controversies throughout their histor$ but the$ have also been a source of perple<it$ !or historians and econo%ists aliCe/ Fritz ;achlup already stated in 468A that "i! -e did not have a patent s$ste% it -ould be irresponsible on the basis of our present kno-ledge of its economic consequences to reco%%end instituting one/ But since -e have had a patent s$ste% !or a long ti%e it -ould be irresponsible on the basis of our present kno-ledge to recom%end abolishing it,5/ In a sense this kind of debate continues toda$ in the light of ne- 1 M. Weber, General Economic History, Glencoe, Ill. :1950 2 F. Machlup, An Economic Review of the Patent System, Washington 1958 495A -ork on patent-free innovation in the -aCe of -hat 'obert .llen put !or-ard in his 46A7 se%inal paper7/ #he discussion -as revived about Great Britain, -hich =eber had -rongl$ %ade the cradle of the @rst %odern patent la-D/ In short even acade%icall$ the role of patent s$ste%s in econo%ic histor$ re%ains a highly controversial subject/ In !act it is quite possible that such a question %a$ not have an una%biguous ans-er/ 0espite their !a%il$ rese%blance patent la-s have strong national speci@cities that international regulator$ institutions do not erase8/ In addition, these s$ste%s experience a number of often e<ogenous "shocks, that can have an i%pact on their o-n i%ple%entation1/ Finall$ one of the parado<es of patent s$ste%s is that !or a long ti%e the$ have constituted a co%%on base of rules !or completel$ diferent industries even i! certain speci@cities %a$ have been developed in some countries and !or certain activities/ .ll this requires a !airl$ precise look at the diferent regi%es covered b$ a patent s$ste% be!ore %aCing comparisons and dra-ing lessons from the% too quickl$/ France -as one of the @rst %a:or industrialized countries to adopt a legislation on patents in 1791. It pla$ed a leading role in the e%er&ence of the @rst international regulations such as the International Union !or the Protection of Industrial Propert$ (Union de ParisG in 4AA7/ Ho-ever his role is relativel$ little discussed. In her book The Democratization of Invention F5228G B. Iorina Jhan de!ended a sharp point of vie- about the French and British patent s$ste%sE/ By comparing Great-Britain, France and the United States she suggested that .%erican econo%ic per!or%ance -as based on a democratization of invention -hich -as 3 R. C. Allen, Collective invention, in: Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 4/1, 1983, pp. 1-24 ; A. Nuvolari, Collective invention during the British Industrial Revolution: the case of the Cornish pumping engine, in: Cambridge Journal of Economics 28/3, 2004, pp. 347-363 ; L. Hilaire-Pérez/C. MacLeod/A. Nuvolari, Innovation Without Patents, in: Revue économique 64/1, 2013, p. 5-8. 4 C. MacLeod, Inventing the Industrial Revolution : the English patent system, 1660-1800, Cambridge 2002 ; C. MacLeod, Patents for invention: setting the stage for the British industrial revolution?, in: Empiria. Revista de Metodología de las Ciencias Sociales 18, 2009, pp. 37-58 ; S. Bottomley, The British Patent System during the Industrial Revolution 1700–1852: From Privilege to Property, Cambridge 2014 ; S. Bottomley, Did the British Patent System Retard the Industrial Revolution?, in: The Criterion Journal on Innovation 1, 2016, pp. 65-83. 5 J. Lerner, 150 years of patent protection, in: The American Economic Review 92/2, 2002, pp. 221-225. 6 C. Diebolt et K. Pellier, 400 ans de protection par les brevets, 400 years of patent protection: a comparative cliometric contribution, in: Revue économique 63/3, 2012, p. 611-621 7 B. Z. Khan, The Democratization of Invention: Patents and Copyrights in American Economic Development, 1790-1920, Cambridge 2005. 595A allo-ed b$ its o-n patent s$ste%/ Contrar$ to the .%erican one the "philosoph$ and enforce%ent of intellectual propert$ in Britain and in France the structure of patent and copyright s$ste%s and the resulting patterns of invention, -ere all consistent -ith the oli&archic nature of *uropean societ$,A/ For her the revolutionar$ rupture had onl$ a rhetoric %eaning. French %ercantilist policies re%ained during the 46th centur$( %istrust to-ard !oreign inventions strong involve%ent "in the discretionar$ promotion of invention” and pre!erence !or secret re%ained the essential !eatures of French patterns of invention and conduced to promote rent-seeking activities, which were unfavorable to competitiveness/ Such an assess%ent see%s all the %ore severe as the French patent la-s has long been perceived as a s$ste% based on natural right/ #he purpose of this article is to revisit this contradiction in light of ne- sources and -orks6/ #hanks to the historical database provided b$ the French Patent KLce (Institut national de la propriété industrielleG and to ne- dissertations it is possible to give a %ore comprehensive anal$sis of the French patent s$ste% in the @rst hal! of the 19th centur$/ In a @rst part -e describe the le&al fra%e-ork and sho- its contradictor$ aspects( a natural right inspiration, s$%bolized by the so-called refusal of an$ preli%inar$ e<a%ination, on the one hand M a restrictive access due to the cost of the patent, on the other hand. #hen, in a second part -e describe the i%ple%entation of the s$ste% b$ insisting on its diferent use b$ industries/ Finall$ -e highlights the efect of the 4ADD Patent .ct and suggest that the !ailure of the s$ste% -as the result of a lacC of institutional infrastructure/ Inventing the French Patent System .dmittedl$ %an$ of the proble%s relating to the inventorsN rights appeared long be!ore the French 'evolution. #he ro$al declaration on privile&es !or inventors in 4E15 expressed a ne- 8 B. Zorina Khan, The Democratization, p. 6. 9 G. Galvez-Behar, La République des inventeurs. Propriété et organisation de l’innovation en France (1791-1922), Rennes 2008 ; J. Baudry, Une histoire de la propriété intellectuelle: les brevets d’invention en France, 1791-1844 (PhD EHESS Paris, 2014) ; C. Koblentz, La Société d’encouragement pour l’industrie nationale et les inventeurs 1824-1844 (PhD EHESS Paris, 2016). I thank the INPI and especially Steeve Gallizia and Valérie Marchal for having helped me in this research, which has been conducted as part of a collaboration between the INPI and the IRHIS. 795A conception of privile&es -hich depended on the strong debates about the economic regulation42/ In the 1780s even though the e<clusive privile&e -as the subject of considerable criticis% %an$ a&reed that transitional %onopolies could be &ranted to inventors/ Inspired b$ the British e<a%ple the French ro$al administration !acilitated the issuance of privile&es in inventions -hile easing procedures of prior expertise/ In return, it required the deposit of their inventions b$ patentees in order to promote the develop%ent of the industrial kno-ledge/ 'ecognition of the natural right of inventor the issuance of te%porar$ privile&es as a re-ard !or inventors and the disclosure of inventions -ere the three !eatures of a %odel -hich had appeared at the end of the Ancien Régime/ The Revolution of inventors (1791) 0espite some continuities the disruptive i%pact of the 'evolution cannot be underesti%ated. #he @rst revolutionar$ patent la-s resulted from a strong lobbying of inventorsN societies/ Such or&anizations had come to light at the end of
Recommended publications
  • Patent Law: a Handbook for Congress
    Patent Law: A Handbook for Congress September 16, 2020 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R46525 SUMMARY R46525 Patent Law: A Handbook for Congress September 16, 2020 A patent gives its owner the exclusive right to make, use, import, sell, or offer for sale the invention covered by the patent. The patent system has long been viewed as important to Kevin T. Richards encouraging American innovation by providing an incentive for inventors to create. Without a Legislative Attorney patent system, the reasoning goes, there would be little incentive for invention because anyone could freely copy the inventor’s innovation. Congressional action in recent years has underscored the importance of the patent system, including a major revision to the patent laws in 2011 in the form of the Leahy-Smith America Invents Act. Congress has also demonstrated an interest in patents and pharmaceutical pricing; the types of inventions that may be patented (also referred to as “patentable subject matter”); and the potential impact of patents on a vaccine for COVID-19. As patent law continues to be an area of congressional interest, this report provides background and descriptions of several key patent law doctrines. The report first describes the various parts of a patent, including the specification (which describes the invention) and the claims (which set out the legal boundaries of the patent owner’s exclusive rights). Next, the report provides detail on the basic doctrines governing patentability, enforcement, and patent validity. For patentability, the report details the various requirements that must be met before a patent is allowed to issue.
    [Show full text]
  • When Creativity Strikes: News Shocks and Business Cycle Fluctuations
    When Creativity Strikes: News Shocks and Business Cycle Fluctuations Silvia Miranda-Agrippino∗ Sinem Hacıo˘gluHoke† Bank of England Bank of England Centre for Macroeconomics (LSE) Data Analytics for Finance and Macro (KCL) Kristina Bluwstein‡ Bank of England August 22, 2018 Abstract We use monthly US utility patent applications to construct an external instrument for identification of technology news shocks in a rich-information VAR. Technology diffuses slowly, and affects total factor productivity in an S-shaped pattern. Responsible for about a tenth of economic fluctuations at business cycle frequencies, the shock elicits a slow, but large and positive response of quantities, and a sluggish contraction in prices, followed by an endogenous easing in the monetary stance. The ensuing economic expansion substantially anticipates any material increase in TFP. Technology news are strongly priced-in in the stock market on impact, but measures of consumers' expectations take sensibly longer to adjust, consistent with a New-Keynesian framework with nominal rigidities, and featuring informationally constrained agents. Keywords: Technology News Shocks; Business Cycle; Identification with External Instruments; Patents Applications. JEL Classification: E23, E32, O33, E22, O34 ∗Monetary Analysis, Bank of England, Threadneedle Street, London EC2R 8AH, UK. E-mail: [email protected] Web: www.silviamirandaagrippino.com †Financial Stability, Strategy and Risk. E-mail: [email protected] Web: www.sinemhaciogluhoke.com ‡Financial Stability, Strategy and Risk. E-mail: [email protected] Web: www.kristinabluwstein.com/ We are grateful to Franck Portier, Michael McMahon, Emanuel M¨onch, and seminar partici- pants at the Bank of England for useful comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • 6-12-03 Letter.Ppc
    FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER Number 2004-17, July 9, 2004 New Keynesian Models and Their Fit to the Data Central banks use macroeconomic models to help Hybrid New Keynesian models frame the issues that they face, to mold their ideas, Hybrid New Keynesian models have the canonical and to guide them in their decisionmaking.While model at their core, but they introduce a number a wide range of models are available, economists of important modifications.Typically these modi- are increasingly examining monetary policy issues fications seek to generate persistence in output and the design of optimal monetary policies in and inflation in order to slow down the rapid the context of “New Keynesian” macroeconomic adjustments that occur in the canonical model. models. New Keynesian models are notable for using microeconomic principles to describe the Consider, for a moment, the canonical model (see, behavior of households and firms, while allowing for example, Rotemberg and Woodford 1997). price and/or wage rigidities and inefficient market Households are assumed to smooth consumption outcomes. One particular model, often called the by saving or by borrowing against expected future canonical New Keynesian model, has received income; specifically, they save more when interest special attention, not only because it is easy to rates are high and consume more when interest work with, but also because it succinctly summa- rates are low. Firms are assumed to have some rizes the principal mechanisms through which market power, allowing those selling similar prod- policy interventions affect the economy. ucts to charge different prices. Although firms choose the price that they charge for their product, The canonical model does have some drawbacks, costs associated with changing prices—re-labeling however.
    [Show full text]
  • Intellectual Property's Leviathan
    KAPCZYNSKI_BOOKPROOF (DO NOT DELETE) 12/3/2014 2:10 PM INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY’S LEVIATHAN AMY KAPCZYNSKI* Neoliberalism is a complex, multifaceted concept. As such, it offers many possible points of entry into my primary field of study, that of intellectual property (IP) law. We might begin by investigating tensions between IP law and a purely economic conception of neoliberalism, for example.1 Or we might consider whether or how IP law might be “insulated from democratic governance” while also being rapidly assembled.2 In these few pages, I want to focus instead on a different line of inquiry, one that reveals the powerful grip that one particular neoliberal conception has on our contemporary imaginary: the neoliberal conception of the state. Today, both those who defend robust private IP law and their most prominent critics, I will show, typically describe Copyright © 2014 by Amy Kapczynski. This article is also available at http://lcp.law.duke.edu/. * Associate Professor of Law, Yale Law School. Many thanks to Talha Syed, David Grewal, and Jed Purdy for helpful conversation and comments. This paper is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-Non-Commercial 4.0 International license and should be reproduced as “first published in 77 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS 131 (Fall 2014).” 1. Neoliberalism is commonly understood in economic terms. See, e.g., David Singh Grewal & Jedediah Purdy, Introduction: Law and Neoliberalism, 77 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., no. 4, 2014 at 1. David Harvey has argued, however, that neoliberalism as “a political project to re-establish the conditions for capital accumulation and to restore the power of economic elites” tends to prevail over the “economic utopian” conception of neoliberalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Overcoming Intellectual Property Monopolies in the COVID-19 Pandemic
    MSF Briefing Document July 2020 Overcoming intellectual property monopolies in the COVID-19 pandemic Médecins Sans Frontières (MSF) is responding to the global COVID-19 pandemic, providing treatment and care for people with COVID-19, protecting people living in vulnerable conditions, and ensuring uninterrupted essential health services for people suffering from other diseases.1 Having universal access to existing and future tools for treatment, diagnosis and prevention is critical. MSF has repeatedly witnessed how exclusive rights and monopolies granted to pharmaceutical corporations, resulting in high prices and blocking generic competition, have had a negative impact on our medical actions in different countries.2 For example, in the past, high prices for patented medicines have undermined the capacity of countries to provide access to treatment for HIV/AIDS, tuberculosis (TB), hepatitis C and cancer to all patients who need them. However, the impact of intellectual property (IP) monopolies is not limited to drugs. The availability of more affordable pneumococcal conjugate vaccine and human papillomavirus vaccine in low- and middle-income countries has been delayed due to unmerited patents on key technologies blocking follow-on producers.3 Intellectual property monopolies in the COVID-19 pandemic While several of the drugs being trialled as COVID-19 treatments are now off patent, patented drugs and experimental drugs are also being trialled, and some of which are under patent protection in many developing countries.4 With control over the market as a result of patents or other exclusive rights, pharmaceutical companies could determine how global production and supply chain are organised, who ultimately has access, who can produce medicines and where they can be supplied.
    [Show full text]
  • Common and Uncommon Knowledge: Reducing Conflict Between Standards and Patents
    [Revised August 2007; earlier version appeared in Sherrie Bolin, ed., The Standards Edge: Golden Mean] Common and Uncommon Knowledge: Reducing Conflict between Standards and Patents Brian Kahin Computer & Communications Industry Association/University of Michigan ABSTRACT: As standards have become critical for advancing technology and new markets, patents have become easier to get, more potent, and readily available for software and business methods. The low standards and opacity of the patent system has made inadvertent infringement commonplace, dramatically increasing opportunities for patent trolls to threaten IT standards. Since these standards have much the same investment rationale as most forms of intellectual property, standards that meet threshold requirements should be accorded protection from patent predators. Patent holders should assert their rights promptly or waive the opportunity to sue those who merely practice the standard. In March of 2007, Alcatel-Lucent won a patent infringement against Microsoft and was awarded $1.52 billion in damages, a record verdict for an infringement judgment. The award was not about cutting edge proprietary technology but for using a familiar industry standard for audio encoding, MP3, developed in the early 1990s. Microsoft thought it had duly licensed MP3 from the Fraunhofer Institute for $16 million in 1994,1 only to learn 13 years later that it owed someone else nearly 100 times much for another patent underlying the standard. The verdict has become a poster child for more disciplined calculation of damages awarded in litigation, a controversial issue in patent reform. However, it also shows how vulnerable industry standards are to attacks from patent holders that do not participate in developing or setting the standard, a structural problem has not been addressed in the debate over patent reform.
    [Show full text]
  • Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship
    University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 2019 The "Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship Erika Lietzan University of Missouri School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.missouri.edu/facpubs Part of the Food and Drug Law Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, and the Science and Technology Law Commons Recommended Citation Erika Lietzan, The "Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship, 53 Akron Law Review 805 (2019). Available at: https://scholarship.law.missouri.edu/facpubs/984 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. DATE DOWNLOADED: Wed Jan 20 13:42:00 2021 SOURCE: Content Downloaded from HeinOnline Citations: Bluebook 21st ed. Erika Lietzan, The "Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship, 53 AKRON L. REV. 805 (2019). ALWD 6th ed. Lietzan, E. ., The "evergreening" metaphor in intellectual property scholarship, 53(4) Akron L. Rev. 805 (2019). APA 7th ed. Lietzan, E. (2019). The "evergreening" metaphor in intellectual property scholarship. Akron Law Review, 53(4), 805-872. Chicago 7th ed. Erika Lietzan, "The "Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship," Akron Law Review 53, no. 4 (2019): 805-872 McGill Guide 9th ed. Erika Lietzan, "The "Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship" (2019) 53:4 Akron L Rev 805. AGLC 4th ed. Erika Lietzan, 'The "Evergreening" Metaphor in Intellectual Property Scholarship' (2019) 53(4) Akron Law Review 805.
    [Show full text]
  • Punitive Patent Liability: a Comparative Examination*
    Punitive Patent Liability: A Comparative Examination* Dan L. Burkt INTRODUCTION ................................................................................ 327 I. INFRINGEMENT OF STANDARD ESSENTIAL PATENTS ............. 330 II. COMPARATIVE INJUNCTIVE CONSIDERATIONS ...................... 334 III. PROPERTY & LIABILITY REGIMES ......................................... 340 IV. LEVERAGING LIABILITY RULES ............................................. 347 V. RESTITUTIONARY PARALLELS ............................................... 352 VI. PARALLEL ANALYSES ............................................................ 358 C ON CLU SION ................................................................................... 365 INTRODUCTION Monetary damage awards and permanent injunctions have long been viewed as complementary remedies: damages as compensation for past realized harm, and injunctions as a restriction against future unrealized harm. But at times these complements may be seen as possible substitutes. In the context of patent infringement, each of these remedies has been identified at different times as mechanisms necessary to prompt ex ante bargaining for patent licenses. 1 The use of monetary damages as a penalty to deter infringing behavior is conceptually straightforward. But some commentary also argues that the potential for injunctive relief is essential to provide deterrence against opportunistic or strategic patent * Copyright 2016-17 by Dan L. Burk. t Chancellor's Professor of Law, University of California, Irvine. I thank
    [Show full text]
  • Inventions and Patents
    MODULE 03 Inventions and Patents MODULE 03. Inventions and Patents OUTLINE LEARNING POINT 1: Basics of invention and patent 1. One way of adding value to a product 2. Reasons for patenting an invention LEARNING POINT 2: Patent application 1. Evaluating the patentability of an invention 2. Deciding whether to patent an invention 3. Preparing a patent application (1) Detailed description of the invention (2) Claims (3) Who prepares (4) After filing a patent application LEARNING POINT 3: Patent infringement 1. Definition of patent infringement 2. If you come across your competitor’s patent LEARNING POINT 4: Patent management system 1. Basic elements of a patent management system 2. Patent portfolio INTRODUCTION The term "intellectual property (IP)" is defined as the property resulting from creations of the human mind, the intellect. In this regard, it is fair that the person making efforts for an intellectual creation has some benefit as a result of this endeavor. Probably, the most important among intellectual properties is “patent.” A patent is an exclusive right granted by a government for an invention, which is a product or a process that provides, in general, a new way of doing something, or offers a new technical solution to a problem. The details on the way of acquiring patents will be provided for protecting precious intellectual properties. LEARNING OBJECTIVES 1. You understand how to decide whether your new technology or invention should be protected by one or more patents and, if so, how to do so. 2. You know how the grant of a patent over an invention or technology helps you to prevent or have an upper hand in legal disputes that may arise later on.
    [Show full text]
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • Intellectual Property, Privatization and Democracy: a Response to Professor Rose Mark P
    Notre Dame Law School NDLScholarship Journal Articles Publications 2006 Intellectual Property, Privatization and Democracy: A Response to Professor Rose Mark P. McKenna Notre Dame Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.nd.edu/law_faculty_scholarship Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons Recommended Citation Mark P. McKenna, Intellectual Property, Privatization and Democracy: A Response to Professor Rose, 50 St. Louis U. L.J. 829 (2005-2006). Available at: https://scholarship.law.nd.edu/law_faculty_scholarship/266 This Response or Comment is brought to you for free and open access by the Publications at NDLScholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of NDLScholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, PRIVATIZATION AND DEMOCRACY: A RESPONSE TO PROFESSOR ROSE MARK P. McKENNA* The broad thesis of Professor Rose's article Privatization: The Road to Democracy? is an important reminder that no institution deserves all the credit for democratization, and that the success of any particular institution in promoting democracy depends to a greater or lesser extent on the existence and functioning of other political institutions.' While protection of private property has proven quite important to successful democratic reform, we should not be lulled into thinking private property can carry the whole weight of reform. That lesson has particular significance in the context of intellectual property, given proponents' general tendency to overstate the significance of intellectual 2 property rights (IPRs) in encouraging innovation. But even if they play a small role in promoting democracy, this Paper argues that IPRs can and do play a role that should not be overlooked.
    [Show full text]
  • Rent-Seeking and Innovation
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 347 October 2004 Rent-Seeking and Innovation Michele Boldrin∗ Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis andUniversityofMinnesota David K. Levine∗ University of California, Los Angeles ABSTRACT Innovations and their adoption are the keys to growth and development. Innovations are less socially useful, but more profitable for the innovator, when they are adopted slowly and the innovator remains a monopolist. For this reason, rent-seeking, both public and private, plays an important role in determining the social usefulness of innovations. This paper examines the political economy of intellectual property, analyzing the trade-off between private and public rent-seeking. While it is true in principle that public rent-seeking may be a substitute for private rent-seeking, it is not true that this results always either in less private rent-seeking or in a welfare improvement. When the public sector itself is selfish and behaves rationally, we may experience the worst of public and private rent-seeking together. ∗Both authors thank the National Science Foundation and Boldrin thanks the University of Minnesota Grants in Aid Program, and the BEC2002-04294-C02-01 project for financial support. We are grateful to Hugo Hopenhayn and Galina Vereshchagina and other Carnegie-Rochester seminar participants for helpful com- ments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. 1. Introduction In the pursuit of profits, economic agents, be they large firms or single individuals, seek to gain an advantage over direct competitors by introducing new goods, services, and technologies.
    [Show full text]