Money and Financial Capital

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Money and Financial Capital Special Section: Eurocrisis, Neoliberalism and the Common Theory, Culture & Society 2015, Vol. 32(7–8) 39–50 ! The Author(s) 2015 Money and Financial Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav Capital DOI: 10.1177/0263276415598213 tcs.sagepub.com Christian Marazzi University of Applied Sciences of Italian Switzerland Abstract The current post-workerist analyses of the crisis of financial capitalism are rooted in the declaration of inconvertibility of the Dollar in 1971 and the consequent collapse of the Bretton Woods monetary system. The experience of ‘Primo Maggio’, the magazine on militant history directed by Sergio Bologna, was determinant in devel- oping a consistent explanation of the relationship between ‘money as capital’ and working class struggles. The transition from Fordism to Post-fordism, which begun in those years, coincides on the one hand with the crisis of the labour value theory and, on the other, with the emergence of the financialization of capital. The advent of the debt economy, which led to the present crisis, reflects the destruction of the wage relationship and the de-substantialization of money. Beyond any objective measure of value, what is necessary is something that points to the subjectivity of struggles and to the forms of life that give them substance. Keywords debt economy, financialization, inconvertibility of money, money as capital, workerism In order to address the topic at hand, I will start from a historical recon- struction of the analysis, the reflection and the elaboration carried out by workerism and ‘post-workerism’ (I do not know if it is correct to call it this but, in any case, it is what we all share) on money and financializa- tion. There is a paper by Stefano Lucarelli titled ‘Sentieri Interrotti’ [Broken Paths] (published in an edited book on the experience of ‘Primo Maggio’ [May Day], the magazine on militant history edited by Sergio Bologna) which allows anyone interested in the origins of work- erism to understand how, in the 1970s, it took its first steps in that direction. It was titled ‘Broken Paths’ because, in effect, the experience of ‘Primo Maggio’ and, in particular, of the so-called group on money, terminated at the end of that decade, to then re-emerge in the 1990s under new guises and along different paths (some of which were only individual), spurred by the stimuli of the 1997 crisis in South-East Asia Corresponding author: Christian Marazzi. Email: [email protected] Extra material: http://theoryculturesociety.org/ 40 Theory, Culture & Society 32(7–8) and later in Russia, by the internet bubble, and, from 2007 onward, by the great structural crisis of financial capitalism. Let us go back to the 1970s and to the questions addressed and developed by the ‘Primo Maggio’ group, of which I was a member too. Reading Lucarelli’s account, it is clear how important was the declar- ation of 15 August 1971 on the inconvertibility of the dollar. That well- known declaration was the end of the Bretton Woods period, designed by White and Keynes in 1944, which was called, in fact, the Bretton Woods monetary system. The Americans were the winners in those heady days, by virtue of the fact that in the 1930s and during the war they had hoarded two-thirds of the world stock of monetary gold and, thanks to both this metallic power and the power of their military, they had pro- posed a system based on the equivalence between dollar and gold (the well-known 35 dollars per ounce of gold). Hence, a parity was fixed between the dollar and other currencies, which thus came to be ‘indirectly’ related to this gold-standard: it was a mixed system – the ‘gold-dollar exchange standard’. During the 1960s, it became clear that this relation to gold was extremely loose: the Americans, in fact, had considerably increased the quantity of dollars in circulation around the world, to enable the investments of multinational companies and in order to pay for their imports. In those years, the French president Charles de Gaulle insistently protested against this invasion of dollars – a massive influx in the form of payments for goods and services imported from Europe and the rest of the world – demanding to verify how much gold was actually behind this money. It was a method of payment that increas- ingly appeared to everyone as a mere sign, rather than a value, a general equivalent. De Gaulle referred to the work of economist Jacques Rueff, who had even proposed to increase fourfold the price of gold in order to somehow re-establish the proportion between circulating money and the gold base. This preamble is necessary to grasp what happened in the 1970s. Especially as a consequence of the workers’ struggles for wages after 1968, the French considerably reduced their rigidity: in order to cope with these struggles, it was more convenient for them to loosen the inflex- ibility of exchange rates (the exchange rate between the French franc and the dollar was fixed, as was established by the Bretton Woods agree- ments). Giovanni Arrighi notes this in his last book, where he affirms that the French – while arguing for the stability of the monetary referent – partially gave up on this claim after the struggles for wages in 1968–9, as they realized that flexible and non-fixed exchange rates were more convenient in such a system. In this way, by devaluing the French franc or any other national currency, it was possible to recover what had been lost in terms of labour costs. In the circumstances created during the course of the 1960s, the United States declared the inconvertibility of dollar to gold. This was described Marazzi 41 as a ‘top-down revolution’. After the 15th of August, Toni Negri, with his usual swiftness, wrote an article in Potere Operaio [Workers’ Power] (a monthly magazine that was also distributed in the factories), replete with references to the Grundrisse, in which he interpreted this epochal event from the point of view of the famous ‘Fragment on Machines’, where Marx foresaw the end of the law of labour-value as a consequence of the development of productive forces and the science incorporated in machinery. At that point, labour only represents the least part of value and, therefore, there is no need for a general equivalent, be it gold or any other type of fiduciary money that functions as a general equivalent. The article tried to link the end of convertibility to the non-measurability of value. It was no longer possible to think of the general equivalent in classical Marxist terms, that is, to think of money as the sovereign good, to which all other goods referred and into which they could be translated. Negri’s interpretation thus pointed to a break in the relation between the measurability of value and its monetary representation, i.e. the general equivalent. The following year, Sergio Bologna wrote an article – entitled ‘Moneta e Crisi’ [Money and Crisis] – which was to prove foundational to the establishment of both ‘Primo Maggio’, in 1973, and the work of the group on money. In this work, militant historian Bologna read Marx’s articles for the New York Daily Tribune, on the crisis which broke out in France in the mid-18th century, as a consequence of the great socializa- tion of credit carried out by the Pereire brothers’ Cre´dit Mobilier, and which allowed Napoleon III to exit the crisis produced by the class strug- gles of 1848. In these writings, Marx had already utilized the category of ‘top-down revolution’, which Engels would take up again some 20 years later when talking about Bismarck. It was the revolution of a capital in confrontation with a working class capable of fighting and destabilizing the system. The response to this crisis, which was linked to a specific type of class composition and subjectivity, was a grandiose operation, which was at one and the same time capitalist and state-led. It was capitalist in that the Pereire brothers’ Cre´dit Mobilier began to buy shares across the whole of France, thus multiplying the funds for other purchases. In other words, this was a sort of precursor of the subprime credit system, with the support of the state and of Napoleon III, who together provided the funds. This great operation of socialization, a sort of ‘communism of capital’ through banking credit, consisted of the creation of money by the state and the central bank, through which the working class was co-opted and returned to work. Obviously, Marx analysed this operation from the point of view of its internal contradictions too. This is what he would develop later in the third book of Capital: the capacity of capital to expand and promote growth through the forced socialization of credit. However, the growth of capital contains within itself its own 42 Theory, Culture & Society 32(7–8) contradictions, i.e. crises and over-production; the fact that, at some point, it must face the impossibility of extracting surplus value beyond a certain level, due to the rigidity imposed by the labour necessary to the operation. Therefore, behind the crisis and over-production there is the rigidity of necessary labour: this is a point that will define the workerist theories of the crisis, and which, by the way, had already been empha- sized by various Marxists like, for example, Lenin and Grossman, the latter of whom was possibly the one theorist who best brought this dynamic into focus. At stake is the impossibility of carrying on accumu- lating due to the lack of capitalist interest: since the rate of profit does not increase, what can they do? This question comes up in all Marxist inter- pretations of the 20th century.
Recommended publications
  • Determinants of Financial Capital Use Review of Theories and Implications for Rural Businesses
    No. 19, February 2012 Jarmila Curtiss Determinants of Financial Capital Use Review of theories and implications for rural businesses ABSTRACT This paper presents a review of financial economics literature and offers a comprehensive discussion and systematisation of determinants of financial capital use. In congruence with modern financial literature, it is acknowledged here that real and financial capital decisions are interdependent. While the fundamental role of the (unconstrained) demand for real capital in the demand for finance is acknowledged, the deliverable focuses on three complementary categories of the determinants of financial capital use: i) capital market imperfections; ii) factors mitigating these imperfections or their impacts; and iii) firm- and sector-related factors, which alter the severity of financial constraints and their effects. To address the question of the optimal choice of financial instruments, theories of firm capital structure are reviewed. The deliverable concludes with theory-derived implications for agricultural and non-agricultural rural business’ finance. FACTOR MARKETS Working Papers present work being conducted within the FACTOR MARKETS research project, which analyses and compares the functioning of factor markets for agriculture in the member states, candidate countries and the EU as a whole, with a view to stimulating reactions from other experts in the field. See the back cover for more information on the project. Unless otherwise indicated, the views expressed are attributable only to the authors
    [Show full text]
  • Fictitious Capital and the Elusive Quest in Understanding Its Implications: Illusions and Paradoxes*
    CADMUS, Volume 2, No.3, October 2014, 55-65 Fictitious Capital and the Elusive Quest in Understanding its Implications: Illusions and Paradoxes* Joanílio Rodolpho Teixeira Fellow, World Academy of Art & Science; Emeritus Professor, University of Brasilia, Brazil Paula Felix Ferreira Post-graduate Student, Autonomous University of Madrid, Spain Abstract This paper deals with the interaction between fictitious capital and the neoliberal model of growth and distribution, inspired by the classical economic tradition. Our renewed interest in this literature has a close connection with the recent international crisis in the capitalist economy. However, this discussion takes as its point of departure the fact that standard eco- nomic theory teaches that financial capital, in this world of increasing globalization, leads to new investment opportunities which improve levels of growth, employment, income distribu- tion, and equilibrium. Accordingly, it is said that such financial resources expand the welfare of people and countries worldwide. Here we examine some illusions and paradoxes of such a paradigm. We show some theoretical and empirical consequences of this vision, which are quite different and have harmful constraints. 1. Introduction There is an extensive controversy concerning traditional models of economic equi- librium and new development paradigms based on an interdisciplinary, broader study of economics. When faced with the harmful effects of misguided directives in an economic and global sense, theorists have the obligation not only to explain their causes, but also to offer a practical solution or alternate thinking. After all, consistent levels of poverty, unemploy- ment and low growth are results which were not expected in orthodox economic models of equilibrium and should be dealt with instead of being thrown aside as a politically restricted issue.
    [Show full text]
  • Financialization and the World Economy
    1. Introduction: Financialization and the World Economy Gerald A. Epstein ______________________________________________________________ INTRODUCTION In the last thirty years, the economies of the world have undergone profound transformations. Some of the dimensions of this altered reality are clear: the role of government has diminished while that of markets has increased; economic transactions between countries have substantially risen; domestic and international financial transactions have grown by leaps and bounds (e.g. Baker, Epstein and Pollin, 1998: chapter 1). In short, this changing landscape has been characterized by the rise of neoliberalism, globalization, and financialization. While many books have been written about neoliberalism and globalization, research on the phenomenon of financialization, the subject of this book, is relatively new. In fact, there is not even common agreement about the definition of the term, and even less about its significance. Greta Krippner gives an excellent discussion of the history of the term and the pros and cons of various definitions (Krippner 2004). As she summarizes the discussion, some writers use the term ‘financialization’ to mean the ascendancy of ‘shareholder value’ as a mode of corporate governance; some use it to refer to the growing dominance of capital market financial systems over bank-based financial systems; some follow Hilferding’s lead and use the term ‘financialization’ to refer to the increasing political and economic power of a particular class grouping: the rentier class; for some financialization represents the explosion of financial trading with a myriad of new financial instruments; finally, for Krippner herself, the term refers to a ‘pattern of accumulation in which profit making occurs increasingly through financial channels rather than through trade and commodity production’ (Krippner 2004: 14).
    [Show full text]
  • What Do Entrepreneurs Pay for Venture Capital Affiliation?
    THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LIX, NO. 4 AUGUST 2004 • • What Do Entrepreneurs Pay for Venture Capital Affiliation? DAVID H. HSU∗ ABSTRACT This study empirically evaluates the certification and value-added roles of reputable venture capitalists (VCs). Using a novel sample of entrepreneurial start-ups with multiple financing offers, I analyze financing offers made by competing VCs at the first professional round of start-up funding, holding characteristics of the start-up fixed. Offers made by VCs with a high reputation are three times more likely to be accepted, and high-reputation VCs acquire start-up equity at a 10–14% discount. The evidence suggests that VCs’ “extra-financial” value may be more distinctive than their functionally equivalent financial capital. These extra-financial services can have financial consequences. A CENTRAL ISSUE for early-stage high-tech entrepreneurs is obtaining external resources when the assets of their start-up are intangible and knowledge-based. Particularly for entrepreneurs without an established reputation, convincing external resource providers such as venture capitalists (VCs) to provide finan- cial capital may be challenging. The literature contains two main lines of re- search for overcoming this problem. One research stream has concentrated on designing institutional structures to permit financing early-stage ventures. This contractual- and monitoring-based approach is aimed at solving poten- tial agency problems between investors and entrepreneurs (e.g., Admati and Pfleiderer (1994), Lerner (1995), Hellmann (1998), and Kaplan and Stromberg¨ (2001, 2002, 2003)). A second research stream has suggested that when the quality of a start-up cannot be directly observed, external actors rely on the quality of the start-up’s affiliates as a signal of the start-up’s own quality ∗The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.
    [Show full text]
  • Hard Cash, Easy Credit, Fictitious Capital
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Finance and Society Article Finance and Society 2015, 1(1): 20-37 © The Author(s) Hard cash, easy credit, fictitious 10.2218/finsoc.v1i1.1369 capital: Critical reflections on money as a fetishised social relation Bob Jessop Lancaster University, UK Abstract This article explores some aspects of money as a social relation. Starting from Polanyi, it explores the nature of money as a non-commodity, real commodity, quasi-commodity, and fictitious commodity. The development of credit-debt relations is important in the last respect, especially in market economies where money in the form of coins and banknotes plays a minor role. This argument is developed through some key concepts from Marx concerning money as a fetishised and contradictory social relation, especially his crucial distinction, absent from Polanyi, between money as money and money as capital, each with its own form of fetishism. Attention then turns to Minsky’s work on Ponzi finance and what one might describe as cycles of the expansion of easy credit and the scramble for hard cash. This analysis is re-contextualised in terms of financialisation and finance-dominated accumulation, which promote securitisation and the autonomisation of credit money, interest-bearing capital. The article ends with brief reflections on the role of easy credit and hard cash in the surprising survival of neo-liberal economic and political regimes since the North Atlantic Financial Crisis became evident. Keywords Marxism, money, credit, fictitious capital, commodity, debt Introduction Although the title of this first issue of Finance and Society is ‘hard cash’, ‘hard cash’ (in the sense of circulating coins and banknotes) has long been insignificant in the overall operation of modern capitalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Venture Capital Investment Strategies Under Financing Constraints: Evidence from the 2008 Financial Crisis
    Venture Capital Investment Strategies under Financing Constraints: Evidence from the 2008 Financial Crisis Annamaria Conti* Nishant Dass† Stuart J.H. Graham‡ ABSTRACT This paper employs the 2008 financial crisis as an empirical setting to show that, while predictably venture capitalists (VCs) reduce investment, they lean towards startups operating in the VCs’ core sectors. These effects are driven by more-experienced VCs, and are strongest for early-stage startups. These findings are robust to controlling for VC-times-startup fixed effects, and time-variant VC and startup characteristics. Complementing these results, we find superior ex post performance among crisis-funded startups operating in more-experienced VCs’ core sectors. Keywords: Financial Crises, Investment Decisions, Venture Capital, Value of Firms, Startups Acknowledgements: the authors wish to thank Marco Ceccagnoli, Andras Danis, Cheol Eun, Jonathan Giuliano, Alex Oettl, Eunhee Sohn, Peter Thompson, and participants at two Georgia Tech (Scheller) faculty seminars and the 2016 INFORMS conference for helpful comments on previous drafts. All errors are our own. Conti and Graham acknowledge research funding from the Center for International Business Research and Education at Georgia Tech. * Corresponding author. [email protected]. Scheller College of Business, Georgia Institute of Technology, 800 W. Peachtree St. NW, Atlanta, GA 30308 USA. † Scheller College of Business, Georgia Institute of Technology. [email protected]. ‡ Scheller College of Business, Georgia Institute of Technology. [email protected]. Venture Capital Investment Strategies under Financing Constraints: Evidence from the 2008 Financial Crisis ABSTRACT This paper employs the 2008 financial crisis as an empirical setting to show that, while predictably venture capitalists (VCs) reduce investment, they lean towards startups operating in the VCs’ core sectors.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring Capital -- OECD Manual
    « STATISTICS ON E LIN BL E A IL A V A E www.SourceOECD.org N G I D L I N SP E ONIBLE Measuring Capital OECD Manual MEASUREMENT OF CAPITAL STOCKS, CONSUMPTION OF FIXED CAPITAL AND CAPITAL SERVICES © OECD, 2001. © Software: 1987-1996, Acrobat is a trademark of ADOBE. All rights reserved. OECD grants you the right to use one copy of this Program for your personal use only. Unauthorised reproduction, lending, hiring, transmission or distribution of any data or software is prohibited. You must treat the Program and associated materials and any elements thereof like any other copyrighted material. All requests should be made to: Head of Publications Service, OECD Publications Service, 2, rue André-Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France. « STATISTICS Measuring Capital OECD Manual MEASUREMENT OF CAPITAL STOCKS, CONSUMPTION OF FIXED CAPITAL AND CAPITAL SERVICES 2001 ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT Pursuant to Article 1 of the Convention signed in Paris on 14th December 1960, and which came into force on 30th September 1961, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) shall promote policies designed: – to achieve the highest sustainable economic growth and employment and a rising standard of living in Member countries, while maintaining financial stability, and thus to contribute to the development of the world economy; – to contribute to sound economic expansion in Member as well as non-member countries in the process of economic development; and – to contribute to the expansion of world trade on a multilateral, non-discriminatory basis in accordance with international obligations. The original Member countries of the OECD are Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Financing the Capital Development of the Economy: a Keynes-Schumpeter-Minsky Synthesis
    Working Paper No. 837 Financing the Capital Development of the Economy: A Keynes-Schumpeter-Minsky Synthesis by Mariana Mazzucato* University of Sussex L. Randall Wray† Levy Economics Institute of Bard College May 2015 * [email protected][email protected] This paper was prepared for the project “Financing Innovation: An Application of a Keynes-Schumpeter- Minsky Synthesis,” funded in part by the Institute for New Economic Thinking, INET grant no. IN012-00036, administered through the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College; Mariana Mazzucato (Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex) and L. Randall Wray (Levy Institute) are the project’s co-principal investigators. The authors thank INET, SPRU, and the Levy Institute for support of this research. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2015 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract This paper discusses the role that finance plays in promoting the capital development of the economy, with particular emphasis on the current situation of the United States and the United Kingdom.
    [Show full text]
  • Civics and Economics CE.12 Study Guide
    HISTORY AND SOCIAL SCIENCE STANDARDS OF LEARNING CURRICULUM FRAMEWORK 2008 (NEW) Reformatted version created by SOLpass www.solpass.org Civics and Economics CE.12 Study Guide STANDARD CE.12A -- BUSINESS ORGANIZATION Types of business organizations and the role of entrepreneurship How do resources, goods and services, and money flow among There are three basic ways that businesses organize to earn individuals, businesses, and governments in a market economy? profits. Economic flow (circular flow) Entrepreneurs play an important role in all three types of • Individual and business saving and investment business organizations. provide financial capital that can be borrowed for What are the basic types of profit-seeking business structures? business expansion and increased consumption. Basic types of business ownership • Individuals (households) own the resources used in • Proprietorship: A form of business organization production, sell the resources, and use the income to with one owner who takes all the risks and all the purchase products. profits. • Businesses (producers) buy resources; make products that are sold to individuals, other • Partnership: A form of business organization with businesses, and the government; and use the profits two or more owners who share the risks and the to buy more resources. profits. • Governments use tax revenue from individuals and • Corporation: A form of business organization that is businesses to provide public goods and services. authorized by law to act as a legal entity regardless of the number of
    [Show full text]
  • Econ – Chapter 13 – Outline #1 I. Savings and Financial System = An
    Econ – Chapter 13 – Outline #1 I. Savings and Financial System = An economic system must be able to produce capital if it is to satisfy the wants and needs of its people. To produce capital, people must be willing to save, which releases resources for use elsewhere. + Savings to and Economist = A. Saving and Capital Formation = when people save, they make funds available to others. When businesses borrow these savings, new goods and services are created, new plants and equipment are produced, and new jobs become available. Saving makes economic growth possible. 1. Example – Entrepreneurs who borrow = a. When people save, they are abstaining form consumption, which frees resources for others to borrow and use. These resources also make investments possible. B. Financial Assets and the Financial System – for people to use the savings of others, the economic must have a financial system, or a way to transfer savers’ dollars to investor. 1. How do people save? a. Financial Assets = 1). If the borrower defaults, the lender can use the financial asset as proof in court that the funds were borrowed and that repayment is expected. 2). When funds are lent from one individual or business to another, a financial asset is generated. 2. The Financial System a. The Main Components of the Financial System = b. Any sector of the economy can provide savings, but the most important sectors are the household and businesses. State and local governments provide some savings, but they are net borrowers of funds. c. Financial intermediaries = d. Borrowers = e. Almost everyone participates in the financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Capital, Human Capital, and the Transition to Self-Employment: Evidence from In~Rgenerational Links
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERES FINANCIAL CAPITAL, HUMAN CAPITAL, AND THE TRANSITION TO SELF-EMPLOYMENT: EVIDENCE FROM IN~RGENERATIONAL LINKS Thomas Dunn Douglas Holtz-Eakin Working Paper 5622 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 June 1996 This research was in part funded by the Bureau of Labor Statistics under contract number B9J43507. We thank Donald Bruce and Chris Furgiuele for outstanding research assistance, and Esther Gray, Ann Wicks, and Jodi Woodson for their help in preparing the manuscript. We also thank seminar participants at the Bureau of Labor Statistics, NLS Summer Workshop, Cornell University, Princeton University, Syracuse University, and the University of Rochester for helpful comments. This paper is part of NBER’s research programs in Labor Studies and Public Economics. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. O 1996 by Thomas Dunn and Douglas Holtz-Eakin. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including @ notice, is given to the source. NBER Working Paper 5622 June 1996 FINANCIAL CAPITAL, HUMAN CAPITAL, AND THE TRANSITION TO SELF-EMPLOYMENT: EV~ENCE FROM INTERGENERATIONAL LINKS ABSTRACT The environment for business creation is central to economic policy, as entrepreneurs are believed to be forces of innovation, employment and economic dynamism. We use data from the National Longitudinal Surveys (NLS) to investigate the relative importance of financial and human capital exploiting the variation provided by intergenerational links. Specifically, we estimate the impacts of parental wealth and human capital on the probability that an individual will make the transition from a wage and salary job to self-employment.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Goods,” from the BOOK: the Science of Economics by Fred E
    CHAPTER 4, “Capital Goods,” FROM THE BOOK: The Science of Economics By Fred E. Foldvary 1. Definition In Chapter 1, capital goods are defined as real wealth (which has been produced) which is used to produced more wealth instead of for direct consumption. Real wealth consists of physical goods and services rather than financial capital, claims to real wealth such as money and bonds. The word "capital" is confusingly applied to both capital goods and financial capital, the latter being coupons or tickets (such as money) that one can exchange for real wealth. In this chapter, we will focus only on capital goods and use "capital" to refer only to capital goods. Whether an item is a capital good depends on how it is used. A car used for personal use is not a capital good, whereas the same car used to haul goods for income becomes a capital good. The economist Nassau Senior is credited with forming "the abstinence theory of capital accumulation" (McConnel, 1980, p. 67). The theory states that land and labor are the primary factors in production; they are used to produce the third factor, capital goods. In order to provide tools, as illustrated by the model in Chapter 3, it is necessary to abstain from the production of immediate consumer goods in order to make the tools instead. Capital goods are produced to be used at a later stage in the production of more wealth. Unlike most forms of land, the quantity of capital goods can be increased or decreased in two ways: 1) more can be produced; 2) personal wealth can be converted into capital goods, and vice versa.
    [Show full text]