World Federation Against the Welfare State: Hayek and Röpke Think Global Before 1945

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

World Federation Against the Welfare State: Hayek and Röpke Think Global Before 1945 Conference Paper Hitotsubashi University Tokyo, Japan March 21, 2015 Draft – Do Not Cite or Circulate World Federation against the Welfare State: Hayek and Röpke Think Global before 1945 Quinn Slobodian Wellesley College It has fallen to myself and a couple of others at this conference to speak not about the proponents of the welfare state but its critics. In the following, I will talk in particular about two of the fathers of the neoliberal intellectual movement, Wilhelm Röpke and Friedrich Hayek. I will do so by way of an insight from geography, asking questions about the welfare state and scale. Because I think it is only when we think about the space between the nation and the world that the neoliberal critique can be grasped. The welfare state, two historians observe, is often “understood as quintessentially a national phenomenon or as a set of uniquely national projects.” 1 Insofar as transnational aspects are recognized in the period before 1945, it is in the traffic of models: the movement of social-scientific knowledge from place to place, and occasionally the activity of a fledgling international organization like the International Labor Organization (ILO) formed in 1919. The national focus is not coincidental. In fact, it follows from the tools of economic policy and knowledge themselves. As is now widely acknowledged, the idea of “the economy” itself as an object to be observed, modeled and engineered only arose with the tools of national income accounting. 2 Röpke himself pointed out in 1937 that macroeconomics encouraged the national frame of policy, including what he called “self- contained national income theory.” 3 The nation-state was the assumed if not the explicit 1 Chris Pierson and Matthieu Leimgruber, "Intellectual Roots," in The Oxford Handbook of the Welfare State , ed. Francis G. Castles (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010), 40. 2 Timothy Mitchell, "Fixing the Economy," Cultural Studies 12, no. 1 (1998): 82-101. See also Daniel Speich Chassé, Die Erfindung Des Bruttosozialprodukts: Globale Ungleichheit in Der Wissensgeschichte Der Ökonomie (Göttingen: Vandenhock & Ruprecht, 2013). 3 Wilhelm Röpke, Economics of the Free Society (Chicago: Regnery, 1963), 125. container for Keynesian economic policy and the distribution of the welfare state’s social services and benefits.4 The breakthrough of scale, we are told, comes with Bretton Woods in 1944. The institutions of the World Bank and the IMF allowed, for the first time, the potential for the international generalization of expansionary state spending policy in the interests of full employment accompanied by social services and robust forms of organized labor. The system of fixed but adjustable exchange rates combined with aid transfers would make “embedded liberalism” (Ruggie) a reality; the welfare state, in short, could go global. 5 This somewhat Whiggish iteration—from the national to the planetary—has enabled a series of redemptive and normative narratives in the realms of both scholarship and politics. One thinks here of the stirring title of Elizabeth Borgwardt’s 2005 book A New Deal for the World: America’s Vision for Human Rights and the rather nostalgic impression it leaves--written, as it was, in the Bush years--of an America that once relied more on aid and training than Bradley fighting vehicles to assert itself overseas.6 The most common version of this narrative comes in the topos of the “global New Deal.” To name a few examples from the last two years, British prime minister Gordon Brown, the UN Conference on Trade and Development, Oxfam, and the head of the AFL-CIO 4 It is important to note from the outset that the protagonists at rendering the world into numbers were not the neoliberals but more those of the left, including Jan Tinbergen, Gerhard Colm, Jacob Marschak, and Oskar Lange. See Philip Mirowski, Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2002). Marcel Boumans, How Economists Model the World into Numbers (New York: Routledge, 2005), chapter 2. 5 John Gerard Ruggie, "International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order," International Organization 36, no. 2 (1982): 379-415. 6 Elizabeth Borgwardt, A New Deal for the World: America's Vision for Human Rights (Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap, 2005). Kiran Patel is currently preparing a manuscript with this title. For uses in the scholarship see Peter Baldwin, The Politics of Social Solidarity: Class Bases of the European Welfare State, 1875-1975 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 108. Michael E. Latham, The Right Kind of Revolution: Modernization, Development, and U.S. Foreign Policy from the Cold War to the Present (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2010), 6-7. Nils Gilman, Mandarins of the Future: Modernization Theory in Cold War America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2003), 276. Claus-Dieter Krohn, Intellectuals in Exile: Refugee Scholars and the New School for Social Research (Amherst: University of Massachusetts Press, 1993), 144. 2 have all called for a “global new deal.” 7 Other than the not-irrelevant fact that it is apparently politically possible to call for a “global New Deal” but not a “global welfare state,” it is notable how the progressive discourse unconsciously echoes the evolutionary scale shifts at the heart of what Tamotsu Nishizawa and others have called the “ethico- historical” approach to economics: the movement from the nation to the world is figured in temporal terms as a positive evolution: a development or a progression.8 By contrast, when the neoliberal critique of the welfare state comes on strong in the 1970s, it is represented as moving in the opposite direction: dissolving the nation-state down to its composite individuals—or maybe, in the conservative version, down to its local communities. It is not for nothing that Margaret Thatcher’s 1987 declaration that “there is no such thing” as society is so talismanic for critics of neoliberalism. She appears in this statement to have given up the game, let the mask slip. Because neoliberals are against scaling up, this argument goes, they must be against progress. But how would it change the storyline if we realized that neoliberals started with the world? That the conceptual territory of the global is first staked out not by the forces of the left or social democracy but by its opponents? Neoliberals Started with the World The neoliberals inherited their worldview first from the classical liberals, adopting a perspective that embraces all of the world’s wealth and resources. This is explicit in their own writings. Ludwig von Mises wrote in 1916 that “from a purely economic standpoint, the largest possible expansion of the economic region, that is the free trade region, is to 7 Brown seeks 'new deal' with Obama, BBC News , 1 Mar 2009; “Oxfam seeks 'new deal' on inequality from world leaders,” BBC News , 18 Jan 2013; Bruce Vail, “Rejecting TPP, AFL-CIO’s Trumka calls for ‘Global New Deal,’” In These Times , March 25, 2014; UNCTAD, Trade and Development Report (Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 2014), 61. As a side note, for those of us who fear our work is never read, it’s heartening to see that UNCTAD pegs much of their restored faith in the moment of the mid-1940s on Eric Helleiner’s recent book on Forgotten Foundations of Bretton Woods . 8 Tamotsu Nishizawa, "The Ethico-Historical Approach Abroad: The Case of Fukuda," in No Wealth but Life: Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in Britain, 1880-1945 , ed. Roger Backhouse and Tamotsu Nishizawa (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2010). 3 be strived for; and the largest region is the entire inhabited surface of the earth.” 9 Röpke wrote in 1937 that "the highly modern economic system encompasses not alone a single city, however great, not alone a country however vast, but…the whole terrestrial globe.” 10 The First World War had left a new global consciousness in its wake, expressed most starkly by a raft of new compound “world” words in English, often imported from German: “world affairs,” “world politics,” “world government,” “world literature,” “world history” and, most notably, “world economy.” Röpke began his 1943 book with the self-evident statement that “we are constantly aware of the earth as a whole.”11 He was part of a cohort that not only labeled the Great Depression (as it’s still known in German) the “world economic crisis” but called the entire period from 1914 to the 1940s the period of the “world crisis.” 12 Neoliberals may have started with the individual—as in the Austrian theory of subjective value—but they also started with the world. Global talk was not idle rhetoric. It had normative ramifications. In economic terms, the goal of economic activity was the most rational use of the world’s resources. Röpke wrote in 1938 that: There will be always an optimum scheme of the world distribution of productive resources based on the most rational localization of the different branches of production—a scheme which an omniscient dictator of a socialist world community would have in mind were he to re-arrange world production on the most rational lines. 13 9 Ludwig Mises, "Vom Ziel Der Handelspolitik," Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 42, no. 2 (1916)., 580. 10 Röpke, Economics of the Free Society , 3. 11 The Social Crisis of Our Time (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1950), 2. 12 "International Economics in a Changing World," in The World Crisis , ed. Geneva Graduate Institute of International Studies (London: Longmans, Green and Co., 1938). 13 Röpke. Investigation into Postwar Agrarian and Industrial Protectionism. Outline of the First Special Research Program (Natural changes in the scheme of the international division of labor). Nov 1937. RF, 104, 944.
Recommended publications
  • Welfare State Regimes: a Literature Review
    Welfare State Regimes: a Literature Review Arshad Isakjee IRIS WORKING PAPER SERIES, NO. 18/2017 www.birmingham.ac.uk/iris IRiS Working Paper Series The Institute for Research into Superdiversity (IRiS) Working Paper Series is intended to aid the rapid distribution of work in progress, research findings and special lectures by researchers and associates of the Institute. Papers aim to stimulate discussion among scholars, policymakers and practitioners and will address a range of topics including issues surrounding population dynamics, security, cohesion and integration, identity, global networks, rights and citizenship, diasporic and transnational activities, service delivery, wellbeing, social exclusion and the opportunities which superdiverse societies offer to support economic recovery. The IRiS WP Series is edited by Dr Nando Sigona at the Institute for Research into Superdiversity, University of Birmingham. We welcome proposals for Working Papers from researchers, policymakers and practitioners; for queries and proposals, please contact: [email protected]. All papers are peer-reviewed before publication. The opinions expressed in the papers are solely those of the author/s who retain the copyright. They should not be attributed to the project funders or the Institute for Research into Superdiversity, the School of Social Policy or the University of Birmingham. Papers are distributed free of charge in PDF format via the IRiS website. Hard copies will be occasionally available at IRiS public events. This Working Paper is also part of UPWEB Working Paper Series (No.5/2017) For more info on UPWEB: http://www.birmingham.ac.uk/generic/upweb/index.aspx 2 | IRIS WORKING PAPER SERIES NO.18/2017 Abstract This literature review seeks to position the UPWEB research project in relation to discourses on welfare regimes.
    [Show full text]
  • What's Right with Welfare? the Other Face of AFDC
    The Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare Volume 16 Issue 2 June - Special Issue on Social Justice, Article 2 Values, and Social Work Practice June 1989 What's Right with Welfare? The Other Face of AFDC Ronald B. Dear University of Washington Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.wmich.edu/jssw Part of the Social Welfare Commons, and the Social Work Commons Recommended Citation Dear, Ronald B. (1989) "What's Right with Welfare? The Other Face of AFDC," The Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare: Vol. 16 : Iss. 2 , Article 2. Available at: https://scholarworks.wmich.edu/jssw/vol16/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you by the Western Michigan University School of Social Work. For more information, please contact [email protected]. What's Right with Welfare? The Other Face of AFDC' RONALD B. DEAR University of Washington School of Social Work Eleven million people, mostly mothers and children, depend on Aid to Families with Dependent Children, America's largest child welfare pro- gram. Much is wrong with AFDC welfare, and serious efforts are being made, again, to reform it. So far, no major attempts at reform have been successful. If reform is to succeed, we must understand what needs to be corrected and what does not. What's right with welfare? This study, not an apology or excuse for AFDC, answers that rarely asked question. Part I surveys back- ground. Part II cites myths and criticisms of AFDC and portrays pov- erty as it afflicts children and female-headed households. The focus of the analysis is on the depiction of 12 positive features of AFDC.
    [Show full text]
  • Welfare, Work, and American Indians November 2001
    Acknowledgements This report was made possible through funding from the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services and the W. K. Kellogg Foundation through the National Congress of American Indians. We extend special thanks to Sarah Hicks (National Congress of American Indians) for her guidance and support throughout the development of this report, to Delaine Alley and Ashley Cruse for invaluable research assistance, to the program administrators of the 34 HHS-approved tribal TANF programs for responding to the “Tribal TANF Administration Survey,” to Norm DeWeaver of the Indian and Native American Training Coalition for his contributions to and review of the document, and to the numerous tribal professionals, TANF program staff members, and other individuals who shared their expertise and experience with us and our colleagues at conferences and in dozens of conversations and interviews. Contacts For Further Information Dr. Eddie F. Brown, Director Kathryn M. Buder Center for American Indian Studies George Warren Brown School of Social Work, Washington University Campus Box 1196, One Brookings Drive St. Louis, MO 63130-4899 Tel: 314-935-4510 Email: [email protected] Dr. Stephen Cornell, Director Udall Center for Studies in Public Policy, The University of Arizona 803 East First Street Tucson, AZ 85719 Tel: 520-884-4393 Email: [email protected] Welfare, Work, and American Indians November 2001 Executive Summary The Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996 (PRWORA) ushered in a new era of welfare programs in America. PRWORA and related legislation specifically addressed the needs of American Indian tribes. In this report we review the key features of the welfare reform legislation as it applies to American Indians and Indian Country, assess—to the best of our ability with currently available information—its impact on Indian nations and its chances of achieving its goals, and identify key issues that demand attention if welfare reform is to succeed on Indian lands.
    [Show full text]
  • Studying Social Work: Neoliberalism, Institutional Ethnography and a Program of Undergraduate Social Work Education
    STUDYING SOCIAL WORK: NEOLIBERALISM, INSTITUTIONAL ETHNOGRAPHY AND A PROGRAM OF UNDERGRADUATE SOCIAL WORK EDUCATION Kathleen Piovesan Bachelor of Arts, University of Victoria, 2002 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS In the Department of Sociology and Anthropology O Kathleen Piovesan 2007 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY All rights reserved. This work may not be reproduced in whole or in part, by photocopy or other means, without permission of the author Name: Kathleen Piovesan Degree: Master of Arts Title of Thesis: Studying Social Work: Neoliberalism, Institutional Ethnography and A Program of Undergraduate Social Work Education Examining Committee: Chair: Dr. Wendy Chan Associate Professor of Sociology Dr. Dara Culhane Senior Supervisor Associate Professor of Anthropology Dr. Jane Pulkingham Supervisor Associate Professor of Sociology Dr. Dany Lacombe External Examiner Associate Professor of Sociology Declaration of The author, whose copyright is declared on the title page of this work, has granted to Simon Fraser University the right to lend this thesis, project or extended essay to users of the Simon Fraser University Library, and to make partial or single copies only for such users or in response to a request from the library of any other university, or other educational institution, on its own behalf or for one of its users. The author has further granted permission to Simon Fraser University to keep or make a digital copy for use in its circulating collection (currently available to the public at the 'Institutional Repositoryw link of the SFU Library website <www.lib.sfu.ca> at: <http://ir.lib.sfu.ca/handle/1892/112>) and, without changing the content, to translate the thesis/project or extended essays, if technically possible, to any medium or format for the purpose of preservation of the digital work.
    [Show full text]
  • The Struggle for Social Welfare: Towards an Emerging Welfare Sociology
    SOCIETY REGISTER 2019 / 3(2): 7-19 ISSN 2544–5502 DOI: 10.14746/sr.2019.3.2.01 THE STRUGGLE FOR SOCIAL WELFARE: TOWARDS AN EMERGING WELFARE SOCIOLOGY MARIUSZ BARANOWSKI1 1 Adam Mickiewicz University in Poznań, Szamarzewskiego 89 C, 60-568 Poznań, Poland. ORCID: 0000- 0001-6755-9368, Email: [email protected] ABSTRACT: The main aim of the article is to outline welfare sociology as a potential sub-discipline of sociology and to discuss the issues of broadly defined social welfare. While in contemporary social sciences the literature concerning welfare often focuses on themes such as happiness (psychology), prosperity (economics), or quality of life (sociology), these themes may be considered too narrow and do not reflect the com- plexity of the issue. However, if one considers the definition of social welfare through the prism of material and non-material needs, as well as the needs expressed individ- ually and collectively, it is possible to attempt a comprehensive study of this phenom- enon. The author uses the definition of social welfare to look at research on (a) welfare state regimes, (b) welfare attitudes and (c) issues of work in contemporary capitalism, all to enable the application of research results within the analysis of the title concept. KEYWORDS: social welfare, welfare scarcity, welfare sociology, well-being, ill-being INTRODUCTION The history of all hitherto existing society is the history of social welfare struggles (cf. Marx and Engels [1848] 1948:9). Class struggle, for example, is an important but only a subset of the space/agglomerate of multifaceted battles for social welfare.
    [Show full text]
  • The Welfare State
    The Welfare State: Where Do We Go From Here? by Michael Walzer, Frances Fox Piven, Jean Bethke Elshtain, Joseph Schwartz, Margaret Weir will have to await further developments. They, out of their unique historic expe­ rience, have something to teach us, as EDITORIAL we have something to teach them. It seems that the socialization ofourecon­ omy and society has turned out to be a Democracy First, Economic Relations Later far more complex and drawn-out proc­ ess than many of us had hoped. But to brothers and sisters in Eastern Europe paraphrase Churchill's remark about A 11 across Eastern Europe, from about whether it is really capitalism democracy: democratic socialism is the the Baltic to the Bosphorus, the buzz they want. That's something they are worst possible goal, except when you words are now "democracy," "plural­ goingtohaveto find out for themselves. consider the alternatives. ism," "market economy." Other words They understand the evils from which -- Gordon Haskell enter the political discourse, but their they flee far better than the ones which use seems to depend more on how many await them. Life has taught them to DEMOCRATIC LEFT disbelieve anything they are told by their months have passed sinoo the great thaw Founding Editor ending the Stalinist ice age has reached rulers and to believe almost anything Michael Harrington (1928-1989) the particular country in question. As told them by those rulers' opponents Managing Editor time passes, "communism wilh a hu­ and enemies. They know that there is Sherri Levine man face" tends to give way to "social­ unemployment, poverty, crime, and Editorial Committtt ism," and that in turn to "social democ­ homelessness in the West, and that the Joanne Barkan racy" or just plain "democracy." rich and powerful dominate the media Neil McLaughlin The semantic changes express a real and the politics dependent on them.
    [Show full text]
  • When Can Experimental Evidence Mislead? a Re-Assessment of Canada’S Self Sufficiency Project
    IZA DP No. 9939 When Can Experimental Evidence Mislead? A Re-Assessment of Canada’s Self Sufficiency Project Chris Riddell W. Craig Riddell May 2016 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor When Can Experimental Evidence Mislead? A Re-Assessment of Canada’s Self Sufficiency Project Chris Riddell ILR School, Cornell University W. Craig Riddell University of British Columbia and IZA Discussion Paper No. 9939 May 2016 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion.
    [Show full text]
  • Institute for Research on Poverty Discussion Paper No. 1184-99
    Institute for Research on Poverty Discussion Paper no. 1184-99 Statecraft: The Politics of Welfare Reform in Wisconsin Lawrence M. Mead Department of Politics New York University E-mail: [email protected] February 1999 A version of this paper was presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, September 3–6, 1998. IRP publications (discussion papers, special reports, and the newsletter Focus) are now available on the Internet. The IRP Web site can be accessed at the following address: http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/irp/ Abstract Wisconsin’s reform of family welfare is the most radical and, arguably, the most successful in the nation. This is not due to anything special about the welfare problem or public opinion in the state but rather to special features of the state’s politics and government. Reform is radical, but at the same time it has been largely bipartisan, with most Democrats joining with Governor Tommy Thompson and other Republicans in seeking to transform the system. Bipartisanship, in turn, reflects the unusual moderation of Republicans in approaching reform and the unusual willingness of Democrats to criticize the old system. Outside groups—such as black leaders, welfare advocates, and academics, who elsewhere block reform—have been moderate or ineffective in their protests, while business has been unusually supportive. Two background conditions have helped shape this political environment—Wisconsin’s cohesive society and its masterful government, the product of its Progressive past. In Wisconsin, in contrast to other urban states, both the will to reform welfare and the capacity to do so are strong.
    [Show full text]
  • A Beginner's Guide to Liberty
    A Beginner’s Guide to Liberty Edited by Dr Richard Wellings The Adam Smith Institute has an open access policy. Copyright remains with the copyright holder, but users may download, save and distribute this work in any format provided: (1) that the Adam Smith Institute is cited; (2) that the web address adamsmith.org is published together with a prominent copy of this notice; (3) the text is used in full without amendment [extracts may be used for criticism or review]; (4) the work is not re–sold; (5) the link for any online use is sent to [email protected]. The views expressed in this report are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect any views held by the publisher or copyright owner. They are published as a contribution to public debate. © Adam Smith Research Trust 2009 Published in the UK by ASI (Research) Ltd. ISBN: 1–902737–65–2 Some rights reserved Printed in England Contents Introduction – Richard Wellings 5 1 The importance of liberty – J. C. Lester 8 2 How markets work – Eamonn Butler 17 3 Free trade – Daniel Griswold 26 4 Taxation and government spending – Daniel J. Mitchell 36 5 Property rights – Karol Boudreaux 47 6 Why government fails – Peter J. Boettke & Douglas B. Rogers 56 7 Sex, drugs and liberty – John Meadowcroft 67 8 Welfare without the state – Kristian Niemietz 76 9 Banking, inflation and recessions – Anthony J. Evans 87 10 The role of government – Stephen Davies 95 About the authors 102 Introduction by Richard Wellings Liberty needs defending. In Western countries, including the US and UK, governments are taking more and more control over people’s lives.
    [Show full text]
  • Community Without Politics
    Civitas Choice in Welfare No. 27 Community Without Politics A Market Approach to Welfare Reform David G. Green Civitas London, 1996 First published January 1996 © Civitas 1996 All rights reserved ISBN 0-255 36364-8 Typeset in Palatino 11 point Printed in Great Britain by St Edmundsbury Press Ltd Blenheim Industrial Park, Newmarket Rd Bury St Edmunds, Suffolk Contents Page The Author iv Preface v Summary ix 1 Introduction 1 2 The Ideal of Liberty: A Re-statement 4 3 The Three Inseparables and the Sources of Collectivism 38 4 The Welfare System: What is Going Wrong? 84 5 Making A Reality of Civil Association 113 6 Some Policy Proposals 135 iv The Author Dr David Green is the Director of the Health and Welfare Unit at the Institute of Economic Affairs. He was formerly a Labour councillor in Newcastle upon Tyne from 1976 until 1981, and from 1981 to 1983 was a Research Fellow at the Australian National University in Canberra. His books include Power and Party in an English City, Allen & Unwin, 1980; Mutual Aid or Welfare State, Allen & Unwin, 1984, with L. Cromwell; Working Class Patients and the Medical Establish- ment, Temple Smith/Gower, 1985; and The New Right: The Counter Revolution in Political, Economic and Social Thought, Wheatsheaf, 1987. His work has also been published in journals such as The Journal of Social Policy, Political Quarterly, Philosophy of the Social Sciences and Policy and Politics. The IEA has published his The Welfare State: For Rich or for Poor, 1982; Which Doctor?, 1985; Challenge to the NHS, 1986; Medicines in the Marketplace, 1987; Everyone a Private Patient, 1988; Should Doctors Advertise?, 1989; Equalizing People, 1990; Medicard: A Better Way to Pay for Medicines?, 1993 (with David Lucas); and Reinvent- ing Civil Society, 1993.
    [Show full text]
  • The Welfare State: a General Theory Paul Spicker
    The Welfare State: a general theory Paul Spicker First published 2000 by Sage Publications, ISBN 0-7619-6704-4 and 0-7619-6705-2 © Paul Spicker The author retains the intellectual property. This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs 3.0 Unported License. You are free to copy, distribute and transmit the work, under the following conditions: ! Attribution: you must attribute the work in the manner specified by the author or licensor (but not in any way that suggests that they endorse you or your use of the work). ! Noncommercial: you may not use this work for commercial purposes. ! No Derivative Works: you may not alter, transform, or build upon this work. To view a copy of the licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/ or send a letter to Creative Commons, 444 Castro Street, Suite 900, Mountain View, California, 94041, USA. 2 CONTENTS Method 6 I. PEOPLE AND SOCIETY 18 I.1. The person 15 People in society 15 The nature of the personal 17 Social obligations 20 I.2. Society 25 Collective action 25 Society and social relationships 29 Social structure 32 I.3. Social responsibility 38 Solidarity: altruism and responsibility 38 Mutual aid 41 Cohesion and exclusion 46 Social responsibility and social borders I.4. The moral community 52 Moral rules 52 The social construction of morality 54 Deviance and control 57 Moral approaches to social action 60 The moral community 61 II. WELFARE 65 II.1 The nature of welfare 66 Welfare 66 Poverty and exclusion 69 Responding to need 72 3 II.2 The preconditions for welfare 75 Economic development 75 Basic security 77 The structure of rights 79 II.3 Social protection 84 Social protection 84 The limits of the market 86 The social services 89 The moral basis of welfare provision II.4 Welfare and redistribution 94 Welfare in society 94 Social justice 98 Inequality 99 Redistribution 101 Redistribution between societies 104 III.
    [Show full text]
  • Challenging the Neoliberal Attack on the Welfare State
    Indiana Law Journal Volume 78 Issue 2 Article 4 Summer 2003 Efficiency and Social Citizenship: Challenging the Neoliberal Attack on the Welfare State Martha T. McCluskey State University of New York at Buffalo Follow this and additional works at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ilj Part of the Social Welfare Law Commons Recommended Citation McCluskey, Martha T. (2003) "Efficiency and Social Citizenship: Challenging the Neoliberal Attack on the Welfare State," Indiana Law Journal: Vol. 78 : Iss. 2 , Article 4. Available at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ilj/vol78/iss2/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School Journals at Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Indiana Law Journal by an authorized editor of Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Efficiency and Social Citizenship: Challenging the Neoliberal Attack on the Welfare Statet MARTHA T. MCCLUSKEY* I. A FD C ................................................................................................... 799 A. Reconstructing the Economics of Redistribution................. 802 1. The Rise and Fall of Keynesianism .................................................... 802 2. The Triumph of the Neoliberal Double Bind ..................................... 805 B. Neoliberal Citizenship and Welfare Reform ............................................. 807 1. A FD C as M oral H azard .....................................................................
    [Show full text]