Exploring Agreeability in Tree Societies Sarah Fletcher Harvey Mudd College

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Exploring Agreeability in Tree Societies Sarah Fletcher Harvey Mudd College Claremont Colleges Scholarship @ Claremont HMC Senior Theses HMC Student Scholarship 2009 Exploring Agreeability in Tree Societies Sarah Fletcher Harvey Mudd College Recommended Citation Fletcher, Sarah, "Exploring Agreeability in Tree Societies" (2009). HMC Senior Theses. 218. https://scholarship.claremont.edu/hmc_theses/218 This Open Access Senior Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the HMC Student Scholarship at Scholarship @ Claremont. It has been accepted for inclusion in HMC Senior Theses by an authorized administrator of Scholarship @ Claremont. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Exploring Agreeability in Tree Societies Sarah Fletcher Francis Su, Advisor Kimberly Tucker, Reader May, 2009 Department of Mathematics Copyright c 2009 Sarah Fletcher. The author grants Harvey Mudd College the nonexclusive right to make this work available for noncommercial, educational purposes, provided that this copyright statement appears on the reproduced materials and notice is given that the copy- ing is by permission of the author. To disseminate otherwise or to republish re- quires written permission from the author. Abstract Let S be a collection of convex sets in Rd with the property that any sub- collection of d − 1 sets has a nonempty intersection. Helly’s Theorem states that \s2S S is nonempty. In a forthcoming paper, Berg et al. (Forthcoming) interpret the one-dimensional version of Helly’s Theorem in the context of voting in a society. They look at the effect that different intersection prop- erties have on the proportion of a society that must agree on some point or issue. In general, we define a society as some underlying space X and a collection S of convex sets on the space. A society is (k, m)-agreeable if every m-element subset of S has a k-element subset with a nonempty inter- section. The agreement number of a society is the size of the largest subset of S with a nonempty intersection. In my work I focus on the case where X is a tree and the convex sets in S are subtrees. I have developed a reduction method that makes these tree societies more tractable. In particular, I have used this method to show that 1 the agreement number of (2, m)-agreeable tree societies is at least 3 jSj and that the agreement number of (k, k + 1)-agreeable tree societies is at least jSj − 1. Contents Abstract iii Acknowledgments xi 1 Background 1 1.1 Helly’s Theorem . 1 1.2 Agreeable Societies . 2 1.3 Graphs and the Helly Property . 5 1.4 Agreeability on Graphs . 5 1.5 Terminology and Notation . 6 1.6 Our Main Goal . 7 2 A Reduction Method 9 2.1 Equivalent Tree Societies . 9 2.2 Irreducible Tree Societies . 9 2.3 A Reduction Process . 11 3 (k, m)-Theorems for Tree Societies 15 3.1 Definitions . 15 3.2 (n, n + 1)-Agreeable Tree Societies . 16 3.3 (2, m)-Agreeable Tree Societies . 18 3.4 More Small Cases . 21 4 Future Work and Discussion 29 4.1 Comparing Linear Societies and Tree Societies . 29 4.2 Other Possible Directions . 30 Bibliography 31 List of Figures 1.1 Four pairwise intersecting intervals. 1 1.2 Three convex sets that intersect pairwise but have a non- empty intersection. 2 1.3 Interpreting the real line as a political spectrum. 3 1.4 A discrete linear society. 4 2.1 Two equivalent societies. 10 2.2 Kinds of leaves. 10 2.3 Illustration of reduction algorithm. 13 3.1 (2, 3)-agreeable tree society with minimal agreement number. 17 3.2 (2, 4)-agreeable tree society with minimal agreement number. 21 3.3 (3, 5)-agreeable tree society with minimal agreement number. 22 3.4 A (3, 6)-agreeable reduced tree society with four leaves and agreement number jSj − 4. 24 3.5 A (3, 6)-agreeable reduced tree society with three leaves and l jSj−1 m a(S) = 2 ........................... 26 List of Tables 3.1 Summary of Small Cases. 27 Acknowledgments I would like to thank Professor Francis Su for his patient guidance and en- couragement both as my advisor for this thesis project and throughout my four years at Mudd and my second reader Professor Kimberly Tucker for all of her helpful comments. I would also like to thank the math depart- ment as a whole for providing a wonderful and supportive environment to learn and grow in for the last four years. Chapter 1 Background 1.1 Helly’s Theorem The simplest version of the classical Helly’s theorem states: Helly’s Theorem in 1-dimension. Given n convex sets, that is intervals, in R, if every pair has a nonempty intersection then all n intersect at a common point. Consider the example in Figure 1.1. Each of the colored lines represents an interval of R, slightly displaced so they may be distinguished. Each pair of intervals has a nonempty intersection and we can see that there is a point contained in all of the intervals. On the plane, the property that every pair of sets in a collection of con- vex sets has a nonempty intersection is no longer sufficient to guarantee that there will be a point contained in all of the sets. In Figure 1.2, we see three convex sets that intersect pairwise but still have an empty intersec- Figure 1.1: Four pairwise intersecting intervals. 2 Background Figure 1.2: Three convex sets that intersect pairwise but have a nonempty intersection. tion. However, if we change the hypothesis to require that every three sets in a collection of n convex sets has a nonempty intersection, we guaran- tee that there is a point in the intersection of the n sets. In general, the d-dimensional version of the classical Helly’s theorem states: Theorem 1.1 (Helly). Given n convex sets in Rd where n > d, if every d + 1 of them has a nonempty intersection, then they all intersect at a common point. In moving to higher dimensions, it is necessary to change the intersec- tion properties of the sets in the hypothesis to guarantee the same conclu- sion. It is also interesting to consider what results can be obtained when we alter the intersection properties in the hypothesis. This has been well ex- plored by Berg et al. (Forthcoming) both in the linear case and in Rd. In the linear case, Berg et al. (Forthcoming) also provide an interesting application to approval voting systems, which we describe below. 1.2 Agreeable Societies If we consider R as the political spectrum and an interval (convex set) as the region of the political spectrum of which a particular voter approves , we can use a collection of intervals to model the political preferences of a society. For example, in Figure 1.3 we have taken our earlier linear example and labeled the line as a political spectrum. We can interpret the line and collection of four intervals as a society with four voters and see that there is a region of the political spectrum approved by all of the voters. Agreeable Societies 3 Liberal Conservative Figure 1.3: Interpreting the real line as a political spectrum. If X is a linear space and S is a collection of convex sets of X, we call the ordered pair (X, S) a linear society, view X as a political spectrum, and associate a voter v to each element Av 2 S called the voter’s approval set. If a candidate’s position falls within Av we say that the voter v would approve that candidate. Let the agreement number a(S) of a society (X, S) be the size of the largest subset of S that has a nonempty mutual intersection. In a society satisfying the hypotheses of the classical Helly’s Theorem, such as the society in Figure 1.3, we have a(S) = jSj. Translating Helly’s theorem in R using this context, we see that in a linear society (R, S) in which the convex sets corresponding to every pair of voters have a nonempty intersection, we have a(S) = jSj, that is, there is some point on the political spectrum of which all voters in the society approve. However, if we are having an election, it is not terribly useful to have a point on the spectrum approved by all voters if there is no candidate at that point for whom to vote. To incorporate the idea of candidates, we can either assume that there is a candidate at every point on the line or we can place a node for every candidate on the line thus moving from R into a discrete line, that is, a possibly infinite (if there are infinitely many candidates) linear tree. If we move to this discrete scenario, then we require the subsets corresponding to the voters to be subtrees of the underlying linear tree. In Figure 1.4 we add five candidates to the linear society we were looking at earlier and convert the intervals associated with each of the four voters into subtrees. Furthermore, we know that any given group of people is highly un- likely to all agree on anything, so it is interesting to ask what happens if, for example, we know that some pair amongst every three people in a so- ciety agree even though any given pair might not. The following theorem gives a bound on the agreement number of a linear society in which every 4 Background Figure 1.4: A discrete linear society. collection of m voters has some subset of k voters that all approve of some candidate.
Recommended publications
  • Hyperconvexity and Metric Embedding
    Hyperconvexity and Metric Embedding David Eppstein Univ. of California, Irvine Computer Science Department Metric embedding problems Input: complicated metric space Output: simple metric space Quadratic # degrees of freedom As close as possible to e.g. distance matrix the input metric space shortest paths in weighted graph n-dimensional L-infinity space Linear # degrees of freedom Hyperconvexity and metric embedding D. Eppstein, 2009 Hyperconvex metric spaces Defined by Helly property on metric balls Include trees, L∞ metrics, other interesting spaces Tight span Embed any metric space into a hyperconvex space “Convex hull” for metric spaces Algorithms Diameter in hyperconvex spaces Planar tight spans and Manhattan embedding Minimum dilation stars Hyperconvexity and metric embedding D. Eppstein, 2009 Outline Hyperconvexity Tight spans Planar tight span construction Minimum dilation stars CC-BY-NC photo by Makz on Flickr, http://www.flickr.com/photos/makz/119762730/ Hyperconvexity and metric embedding D. Eppstein, 2009 Outline Hyperconvexity Tight spans Planar tight span construction Minimum dilation stars CC-BY-NC photo by Makz on Flickr, http://www.flickr.com/photos/makz/119762730/ Hyperconvexity and metric embedding D. Eppstein, 2009 Helly’s theorem [Helly 1923] Given a family of convex objects in d-dimensional Euclidean space: If each (d+1)-tuple has a common intersection, so does the whole family Hyperconvexity and metric embedding D. Eppstein, 2009 k-Helly family Any family of sets such that, for any subfamily, if all k-tuples in the subfamily intersect, then the whole subfamily has a common intersection (Like convex sets in (k–1)-dimensional Euclidean space) Helly family Special case of a 2-Helly family (the simplest nontrivial case of a k-Helly family, like intervals of the real line) Hyperconvexity and metric embedding D.
    [Show full text]
  • Arxiv:1610.03307V1 [Math.MG] 11 Oct 2016 Hoyo Ovxsbes Ial,Ti Ed Oahlytp Theore Helly-Type a to Leads This Connec Finally, Subsets
    BALL INTERSECTION PROPERTIES IN METRIC SPACES BENJAMIN MIESCH AND MAEL¨ PAVON´ Abstract. We show that in complete metric spaces, 4-hyperconvexity is equivalent to finite hyperconvexity. Moreover, every complete, almost n- hyperconvex metric space is n-hyperconvex. This generalizes among others results of Lindenstrauss and answers questions of Aronszajn-Panitchpakdi. Furthermore, we prove local-to-global results for externally and weakly ex- ternally hyperconvex subsets of hyperconvex metric spaces and find sufficient conditions in order for those classes of subsets to be convex with respect to a geodesic bicombing. 1. Introduction Hyperconvexity and related properties lie at the interface of several fields like fixed point theory [15], mapping extensions [1, 7], functional analysis [10, 14], geo- metric group theory [9] or convex geometry [8]. Motivated by these applications, we study weak notions of hyperconvexity and afterwards connect them with the theory of convex subsets. Finally, this leads to a Helly-type theorem for weakly externally hyperconvex subsets. In the first part of this work we generalize results related to extensions of uni- formly continuous functions and compact linear operators. In [10], Lindenstrauss characterizes all Banach spaces B with the property that any compact linear oper- ator with target B possesses an ”almost” norm preserving extension in pure metric terms, namely as the Banach spaces which are n-hyperconvex for every n. A coun- terpart for uniformly continuous maps between metric spaces was later proven by Esp´ınola and L´opez, see [7]. This motivates a closer look on results concerning n-hyperconvexity in general metric spaces. Note that the following definition is slightly different from the one given in [1].
    [Show full text]
  • Codomain from Wikipedia, the Free Encyclopedia Contents
    Codomain From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Contents 1 Algebra of sets 1 1.1 Fundamentals ............................................. 1 1.2 The fundamental laws of set algebra .................................. 1 1.3 The principle of duality ........................................ 2 1.4 Some additional laws for unions and intersections .......................... 2 1.5 Some additional laws for complements ................................ 3 1.6 The algebra of inclusion ........................................ 3 1.7 The algebra of relative complements ................................. 4 1.8 See also ................................................ 5 1.9 References ............................................... 5 1.10 External links ............................................. 5 2 Axiom of choice 6 2.1 Statement ............................................... 6 2.1.1 Nomenclature ZF, AC, and ZFC ............................... 7 2.1.2 Variants ............................................ 7 2.1.3 Restriction to finite sets .................................... 7 2.2 Usage ................................................. 8 2.3 Examples ............................................... 8 2.4 Criticism and acceptance ....................................... 8 2.5 In constructive mathematics ..................................... 9 2.6 Independence ............................................. 10 2.7 Stronger axioms ............................................ 10 2.8 Equivalents .............................................. 10 2.8.1 Category
    [Show full text]
  • Convexity in Combinatorial Structures
    WSAA 14 Pierre Duchet Convexity in combinatorial structures In: Zdeněk Frolík and Vladimír Souček and Marián J. Fabián (eds.): Proceedings of the 14th Winter School on Abstract Analysis. Circolo Matematico di Palermo, Palermo, 1987. Rendiconti del Circolo Matematico di Palermo, Serie II, Supplemento No. 14. pp. [261]--293. Persistent URL: http://dml.cz/dmlcz/701901 Terms of use: © Circolo Matematico di Palermo, 1987 Institute of Mathematics of the Academy of Sciences of the Czech Republic provides access to digitized documents strictly for personal use. Each copy of any part of this document must contain these Terms of use. This paper has been digitized, optimized for electronic delivery and stamped with digital signature within the project DML-CZ: The Czech Digital Mathematics Library http://project.dml.cz CONVEXITY IN COMBINATORIAL STRUCTURES (*) Pierre Duchet CNRS3 Paris SUMMARY. The recent (since 1968) combinatorial developments of abs­ tract convexity are surveyed. The combinatorial properties' of convex r sets (Hetty propertys Eckhoff s partition problem ...) are consider­ ed in the general setting of finitary closure systems ("Convexity Spaces" or "Alignements "). In ordered sets3 in tree-like structures and in combinatorial structures inspired by Geometry (e.g. "oriented matroids") there are natural definitions of convex sets : an axiomatic common background is the theory, of "convex geometries" (or anti-• exchange convexitiesff) of Edelman and Jamison or dually the theory of "shelling structures" (or "APS-greedoids")of Korte and Lovasz. Convexity in graphs recently appeared of independent interest (contraction into complete graphs^ universal properties of geodesic convexity .. ) I - INTRODUCTION Properly speaking, convexity is not a mathematical theory, but rather a notional domain where five basic concepts operate : between- ness (-* medians, convex dependance) , algebraicness (-+convex hull operator, dimension), separation ( •>hemispaces, copoints), connected- ness and optimization (-*• extremal points, face-lattices, duality).
    [Show full text]
  • Sobre a Propriedade Helly De Alguns Grafos De Interseção
    ON THE HELLY PROPERTY OF SOME INTERSECTION GRAPHS Tanilson Dias dos Santos Tese de Doutorado apresentada ao Programa de Pós-graduação em Engenharia de Sistemas e Computação, COPPE, da Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, como parte dos requisitos necessários à obtenção do título de Doutor em Engenharia de Sistemas e Computação. Orientadores: Jayme Luiz Szwarcfiter Uéverton dos Santos Souza Rio de Janeiro Setembro de 2020 ON THE HELLY PROPERTY OF SOME INTERSECTION GRAPHS Tanilson Dias dos Santos TESE SUBMETIDA AO CORPO DOCENTE DO INSTITUTO ALBERTO LUIZ COIMBRA DE PÓS-GRADUAÇÃO E PESQUISA DE ENGENHARIA DA UNIVERSIDADE FEDERAL DO RIO DE JANEIRO COMO PARTE DOS REQUISITOS NECESSÁRIOS PARA A OBTENÇÃO DO GRAU DE DOUTOR EM CIÊNCIAS EM ENGENHARIA DE SISTEMAS E COMPUTAÇÃO. Orientadores: Jayme Luiz Szwarcfiter Uéverton dos Santos Souza Aprovada por: Prof. Jayme Luiz Szwarcfiter, Ph.D. Prof. Uéverton dos Santos Souza, D.Sc. Prof. Claudson Ferreira Bornstein, Ph.D. Profa. Liliana Alcón, D.Sc. Profa. María Pía Mazzoleni, D.Sc. Profa. Márcia Rosana Cerioli, D.Sc. RIO DE JANEIRO, RJ – BRASIL SETEMBRO DE 2020 Santos, Tanilson Dias dos On the Helly Property of Some Intersection Graphs/Tanilson Dias dos Santos. – Rio de Janeiro: UFRJ/COPPE, 2020. IX, 94 p. 29; 7cm. Orientadores: Jayme Luiz Szwarcfiter Uéverton dos Santos Souza Tese (doutorado) – UFRJ/COPPE/Programa de Engenharia de Sistemas e Computação, 2020. Referências Bibliográficas: p. 88 – 94. 1. Edge Path. 2. Grid Path. 3. Intersections. 4. search. I. Szwarcfiter, Jayme Luiz et al. II. Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, COPPE, Programa de Engenharia de Sistemas e Computação. III.
    [Show full text]
  • Gluing Constructions and Local-To-Global Results for Hyperconvex Metric Spaces
    Research Collection Doctoral Thesis Gluing Constructions and Local-to-Global Results for Hyperconvex Metric Spaces Author(s): Miesch, Benjamin Publication Date: 2017 Permanent Link: https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-a-010867059 Rights / License: In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection. For more information please consult the Terms of use. ETH Library Diss. ETH No. 23997 Gluing Constructions and Local-to-Global Results for Hyperconvex Metric Spaces A thesis submitted to attain the degree of DOCTOR OF SCIENCES of ETH ZURICH¨ (Dr. sc. ETH Z¨urich) presented by Benjamin Raphael Miesch MSc ETH Mathematik, ETH Z¨urich born May 14, 1987 citizen of Titterten BL accepted on the recommendation of Prof. Dr. Urs Lang, examiner Prof. Dr. Rafael Esp´ınola,co-examiner 2017 Soli Deo Gloria. Zusammenfassung Hyperkonvexit¨at beschreibt eine Schnitteigenschaft von B¨allen in metrischen R¨aumen und wurde 1956 von N. Aronszajn and P. Panitchpakdi fur¨ das Studi- um von Erweiterungen gleichm¨assig stetiger Abbildungen eingefuhrt.¨ In dieser Arbeit studieren wir nun verschiedene Eigenschaften von hyperkon- vexen metrischen R¨aumen. Zuerst untersuchen wir Verklebungen von solchen R¨aumen entlang isometrischer Teilmengen. Fur¨ schwach extern hyperkonvexe Klebmengen k¨onnen wir eine notwendige und hinreichende Bedingung angeben, so dass der resultierende Raum wieder hyperkonvex ist. Als Konsequenz erhal- ten wir, dass das Verkleben von metrischen R¨aumen entlang extern hyperkon- vexer oder stark konvexer Teilmengen die Hyperkonvexit¨at erhaltet. Wir geben auch eine Klassifizierung fur¨ Verklebungen von hyperkonvexen Vektorr¨aumen entlang eines linearen Unterraumes. In einem zweiten Teil analysieren wir, wann ein lokal hyperkonvexer me- trischer Raum hyperkonvex ist.
    [Show full text]