<<

AP PHOTO/MARK LENNIHAN

Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Why Big Is Bad and What to Do About It

By Ganesh Sitaraman July 2014

WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Why Big Is Bad and What to Do About It

By Ganesh Sitaraman July 2014 Contents 1 Introduction and summary

2 Unbundling too big to fail

9 Reforming too big to fail

18 Conclusion

20 Endnotes Introduction and summary

Since the 2008 , the problem of financial institutions being “too big to fail,” or TBTF, has been front and center in the public debate over the reform and regulation of the financial industry. Commentators across the political spectrum decried of the biggest financial institutions, arguing that bail- outs would establish too big to fail as public policy. When it was time for reform, legislators tried to address this problem, and even incorporated into the full title of the Dodd-Frank Act that one of the bill’s purposes was “to end ‘too big to fail.’”1

Yet more than five years after the financial crash, the biggest are 37 percent larger than they were before,2 and the debate over what to do about the size of finan- cial institutions continues. Policy proposals range from improving resolution mecha- nisms, to more stringent prudential standards such as leverage limits, to charging fees to eliminate the implicit government subsidy the biggest banks receive, to capping the size of the banks, to instituting a new Glass-Steagall Act. Each approach is hotly contested, with commentators frequently arguing that the proposed solution will not actually fix the problem of financial institutions that are too big to fail.3

The problem at the heart of the debate over too big to fail is that the popular moniker has come to mean more than the concern that big firms get a government in the event of failure. It captures a variety of concerns with the financial industry: eco- nomic, competitive, systemic, firm level, political, legal, and regulatory. This report identifies the full range of reasons reformers might be worried about TBTF. It then describes the various policy options that are most frequently discussed with regard to reforming TBTF, and it connects the specific reforms to the concerns they address.

To make progress, reformers and critics alike need to engage in a more precise debate. Critics too often dismiss reforms without fully addressing the concerns reformers seek to address, and when outlining proposals, reformers could be clearer about the problems they seek to solve. Ultimately, people will disagree about what aspects of TBTF are most concerning to them. But the first step toward a more meaningful debate over reform requires greater clarity about the particular concern—or concerns—with big financial institutions and the specific solutions that address those concerns.

1 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Unbundling too big to fail

The underlying concerns with big financial institutions can be grouped into five categories: , bailout, competition, firm-level concerns, and political control. Each incorporates multiple related worries about the pernicious effects of the size of financial institutions.

Systemic-risk concerns

While there are a variety of definitions of systemic risk, the basic concept is simple: systemic risk exists when the failure of a single institution would have significant effects beyond the firm, to the financial system or the economy as a whole.4 These ripple effects are seen as so troubling that action must be taken to prevent them, whether that means bailouts after firm failure or some form of regulation before failure.

Size-based systemic risk

The concern about size-based systemic risk—the most natural reading of too big to fail in the systemic-risk context—is that the failure of a gigantic will have immense effects on the financial system or the economy as a whole, simply because the firm is extremely large. Size in this context is obviously a proxy for importance, albeit an imperfect one.5 Large institutions might be able to fail without harmful systemwide effects. Likewise, smaller institutions that are central to the functioning of the system might fail with disastrous consequences. But objections on these grounds are largely a debater’s point. The argument is that size is a reasonable and relatively workable proxy for importance.

2 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Interconnectedness-based systemic risk

Many argue that TBTF should instead be called “too interconnected to fail,” a description that identifies a different kind of systemic risk.6 The worry here is that an institution has too many links to other institutions in the economy, such that its failure would have negative effects throughout each of these firms and thus to the system as a whole. This form of risk is often called “contagion,” as the “disease” in one institution will spread to others with which it interacts.7 For example, if firm A is engaged in risky behavior and fails, it may not be able to fulfill its contracts with firms B and C, each of which then fail, affecting firms D and E, with whom they work, and so on. This cascade effect ripples through the economy.

Of course, interconnectedness is not limited to financial institutions. The bail- out of General Motors, or GM, in 2008 and 2009 was in part justified by links between GM and its parts manufacturers, distributors, and others in the automo- tive industry.8 Similarly, imagine the systemic effects of a hypothetical Wal-Mart failure: The firm’s connections throughout the consumer-goods industry would have significant effects on major consumer-product companies.

System effects and systemic risk

A variety of systemic-risk issues also arise when multiple actors operate within a single system whether or not they are interconnected. Three main concerns arise. The first is informational.9 If firm A fails, people may scrutinize firm A’s risky prac- tices, only to realize that firm B has been engaged in the same practices. If people believe those risky practices led to failure in firm A, they may no longer want to work with firm B because it engages in the same risky practices. The second con- cern is often called “common shock,” defined as a situation in which a single exter- nal event affects multiple firms at once, leading to the failure of the institutions simultaneously.10 The third concern is the conventional notion of a panic—that the failure of a TBTF firm will lead to widespread public panic that undermines multiple firms, regardless of the soundness of those other firms.11

One phenomenon that might undergird each of these systemic risks is the “too- many-to-fail” concern, or so-called herd mentality within the industry.12 Economists have shown that when there are isolated failures, regulators will allow other institutions to acquire the failing banks, but when there are many simultaneous

3 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ bank failures, regulators find it optimal to bail out some or all of the failing banks. As a result, smaller banks “herd” toward the policies of large banks to benefit from the bailout policy in the event of failure. This alignment means that multiple bank failures—and, as a result, bailouts—are more likely to occur at once.

Bailout concerns

Another common area of concern is taxpayer bailouts of failing firms. The worry is that the government will bail out firms that are seen as TBTF instead of letting them fail as the principle of creative destruction requires. Whether explicit or implicit, a policy of bailouts skews incentives for firms and harms taxpayers and markets as a result. Bailout recipients can differ—management, shareholders, or creditors—but regardless, bailout concerns focus on two specific issues: and cost.

Moral hazard

First is the idea that bailouts lead to a moral hazard.13 TBTF firms know that they can benefit from government bailouts in the event of staggering losses. As a result, it is rational for them to take on riskier behavior because they will be able to capture the profits while socializing the losses among taxpayers. The result is a system that fosters more and more risky behavior because the government’s bailout policy has undermined the disciplining effects of the downside risks that accompany market participation, such as losses, failure, or acquisition.

Bailout costs

Bailouts also mean that taxpayers are on the hook for losses from the risky bets of private actors. If bailouts become a recurring practice, it is not obvious that this will result in financial returns for the U.S. Treasury. But even if the costs of bailouts are paid back to the Treasury over time, the practice is troubling for both moral and practical reasons. Morally, taxpayers should not have to rescue those financial institutions taking on risky activities that have questionable social value—includ- ing giving bonuses or golden parachutes to top executives whose actions caused their institution’s failure. Practically, in a world of constrained resources, there might be opportunity costs to spending money on bailouts for the largest financial

4 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ institutions during a financial crisis, rather than on economic stimulus policies or pro-growth policies such as investment in infrastructure or research and develop- ment. If Congress feels budgetary constraints, then prioritizing bailouts might mean that other important spending gets short shrift.

Competition concerns

TBTF also includes a variety of concerns about competition within the financial industry in which the biggest firms gain undue advantage over smaller firms. Large firms get an implicit subsidy because the market recognizes their TBTF status, and big firms are also better able to bear regulatory burdens.

Implicit subsidies

Just as TBTF firms know they can benefit from bailouts, other market actors can also identify which firms are likely to be bailed out, and they will therefore treat those firms as effectively having government insurance.14 The result is a skewing of the market: TBTF firms have a competitive advantage over other firms because they have a no-cost government insurance policy guaranteeing against losses, particularly for the risky activities that might get a high return.

The consequence is that market discipline will not be as effective against the TBTF firms.15 The value of this implicit insurance policy can be calculated by looking at the borrowing rates of different firms, though estimates of the size of the implicit subsidy vary widely.16 Some have even suggested that the largest Wall Street banks would not be profitable without the subsidy.17

Distribution of regulatory burdens

TBTF firms also benefit from the government’s regulatory response to their size. Regulatory burdens are more difficult for small financial institutions such as com- munity banks and credit unions to bear than for the largest firms because small firms do not have the same level of financial and personnel resources to devote to regulatory compliance. The Independent Community Bankers of America in particular has argued that regulations designed for the largest banks have affected their members adversely.18 This design of responsive regulation makes the playing field in the financial industry uneven and biased toward larger institutions.

5 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Firm-level concerns

Many who are concerned about TBTF are worried about the effects that large size has within firms, particularly with respect to internal discipline on firm behavior. In other words, TBTF firms might turn out to be “too big to manage.”19 Specifically, the concern is that in large firms with multiple divisions and complex structures and practices, management will have a harder time controlling and overseeing the firm’s operations. Commentators have suggested this phenom- enon might have been at work in a variety of recent scandals: JPMorgan’s Whale case, HSBC and ’s extensive money laundering and sanctions violations, fraudulent mortgage practices, and manipulation.20

While the failure of internal controls might be a function of sheer size and complexity, it might also be a function of the TBTF implicit guarantee.21 On this theory, TBTF firms deliberately engage less stringent internal controls because they know they have an implicit government guarantee in the event that risky activities go awry.

Political-control concerns

In addition to market discipline and internal controls, firms are subject to external control via government regulation. However, the growth of financial institutions might weaken the effectiveness of political controls on firms and skew the ability of government to respond to economic crises.

Regulatory concerns

As a matter of regular oversight, TBTF firms might be “too big to regulate” because their sheer size and complexity makes it difficult for government regu- lators to do their jobs.22 This is problematic both for the public and for firms. Internally, supervisors who cannot understand or monitor firm activities through normal supervisory practices will be unable to prevent poor behavior before something bad actually happens.23 At the same time, regulators designing the rules and guidance for these complex and dynamic activities will have trouble drawing up regulations that align with practices on the ground. The result might be that regulations themselves become extremely complicated and convoluted, requiring firms to go to great lengths in their compliance efforts.24 In other words, TBTF might make supervision harder, lead to a disconnect between regulation and real- ity, and increase regulatory complexity.

6 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Legal accountability

After a crash or after an illegal action, TBTF might also undermine the ability of the U.S. Department of Justice to punish bad actors and firms. This phenomenon is known as “too big to prosecute,” “too big for trial,” or “too big to jail,” and has been condemned across the political spectrum.25

When asked about the fact that neither HSBC nor any of its employees were prosecuted for years of sanctions violations and money laundering,26 Attorney General noted that “the size of some of these institutions becomes so large that it does become difficult for us to prosecute them when we are hit with indications that if we do prosecute—if we do bring a criminal charge—it will have a negative impact on the national economy, perhaps even the world economy.”27

In other words, after-the-fact legal controls and ramifications on bad behavior might be ineffective against TBTF firms because the U.S. Department of Justice is worried about the effects on the economy of enforcing the law.

Political influence and capture

The size of financial institutions might also give them outsized influence over the political and regulatory process more broadly—commonly called political, regula- tory, or cognitive capture. Under political capture, firms have outsized influence over congressional activity by virtue of being able to contribute to legislators’ campaigns and spend greater resources on lobbying.28 Wall Street, for example, spent more than $1 million a day on lobbying during the lead up to the Dodd-Frank Act.29

Regulatory capture is similar, but operates via the firms influencing regulators, either through the revolving door between regulators and firms or through lobbying efforts at the agency level. Cognitive, or epistemic, capture is more subtle: TBTF firms can shape the views of individuals within the political and regulatory process by shared educational and cultural experiences in which regulators themselves come to believe that the TBTF firms’ perspective on an issue is optimal even though an unbiased assessment would come to a different conclusion.30 Even academics and intellectuals can be captured cognitively—

7 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ and indeed, they are sometimes targets for capture. Size, when coupled with complexity, increases capture concerns. In a fragmented financial industry, firms within different segments of the industry may have different policy prefer- ences, enabling regulators to divide the industry and evade capture.31 When the industry is not fragmented because TBTF firms dominate in multiple segments, regulators have a harder time playing firms against each other, and capture becomes more likely.

8 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Reforming too big to fail

Commentators have suggested a wide range of options to address TBTF and the problem of big financial institutions. Reformers debate bankruptcy and resolution mechanisms, size caps, a new Glass-Steagall Act, the , internal con- trols, and prudential regulations, among other options. Studies have been written on all of these reforms, with commentators debating each in extreme detail.

Despite the high-quality debate at the technical level, the political and policy debate often suffers from commentators not connecting the problem to be solved with the solutions that might actually address the problem. For example, commentators often claim that a new Glass-Steagall Act would not put an end to big institutions and the original act’s repeal in 1999 was in fact not the cause of the financial crash in 2008.32 Whatever the merits of those assertions, sup- porters of a new Glass-Steagall Act do not solely, or even mostly, rely on those arguments. They instead argue that the principle behind the law was separating financial functions to limit the interconnectedness of financial practices and potential conflicts of .33

To make progress in the debate over reform, we need to understand the main cat- egories of solutions and then connect those solutions to the concerns they address.

Approaches to reform

Some of the biggest differences in policy reforms are on the fundamental approach to reform: Should it be ex ante or ex post? Should it be structural or technocratic? Each of these is explored in detail below.

9 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Ex ante versus ex post34

Ex-ante reforms are policies that are activated before an undesirable event takes place. They are preventive in nature, hoping to stop bad conduct or the subsequent effects before they happen. Ex-post reforms are policies that are activated only after an undesirable event occurs. Their purpose can be to punish bad actors, to mitigate ill effects, or to create incentives that will deter bad or risky conduct—in fact, in this latter sense, ex-post actions can have ex-ante effects. For example, bank supervision over money laundering is an ex-ante policy, while prosecution for money launderers is an ex-post policy. Similarly, the theory behind capital require- ments is that they are an ex-ante way to prevent bank failures because funding a proportion of a certain asset by equity instead of debt should make losses less problematic. But the theory behind resolution is that banks still might fail, and there must be a process in place for addressing such failures.

The great benefit of ex-ante reforms is that they directly attempt to prevent the ill effects of TBTF in the first place. This is particularly important because in some areas, ex-ante reforms might be the only way to address the underlying concerns. For example, there is a strong argument that the bailout, moral hazard, and implicit subsidy concerns with TBTF are primarily sociological and psychologi- cal, not legal or regulatory. That is, they are based on people’s belief that big firms will be bailed out if they fail.35 If that is true, then removing the government’s legal authority to bail out big banks or instituting bankruptcy proceedings might be helpful. But even if that were to happen, people might still believe that in a serious crisis, regardless of the existing laws, Congress or the executive branch would authorize a bailout. An implicit bailout policy would therefore still exist. The central drawback of ex-ante reform is that it might not solve the problem. Even with prophylactic rules, illegal activity or risky activity might still take place. Firms might still fail. In that case, ex-post rules will be necessary.

Structural versus technocratic reforms

Structural reforms seek to make fundamental changes to the structure of the finan- cial industry. For example, proposals to cap the size of financial institutions and Glass-Steagall-style separation of functions are structural reforms. Technocratic reforms keep the basic structure of the financial system intact but seek to mitigate harmful effects by changing rules or policies in incremental or moderate ways. They also assume that expert regulators and bureaucrats can use policy to create incentives for firms to act legally or that expert regulators and bureaucrats can themselves manage and monitor activity to prevent bad consequences.

10 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Technocratic reforms benefit from being incremental, and in theory, they should be less politically controversial. However, they suffer from their reliance on an optimistic view of regulators and policymakers—and from complexity. For tech- nocratic reforms to work, expert regulators must be able to manage the dynamic changes in markets on an ongoing basis. As a corollary, such reforms are more likely to be technical and specific to a certain context. Structural reforms benefit from not putting so much faith in regulators and as a result are likely to be simpler.

Reform policies

Proposals for addressing TBTF are ubiquitous. The goal here is not to explore each proposal in detail—something that scholars, commentators, industry participants, and regulators have done—or to identify every specific proposal or variation on a proposal. Rather, the goal is to identify the main categories of reforms, discuss some of their shared characteristics, and identify the concerns that they address.

Resolution

A variety of reforms can be grouped together as resolution: bankruptcy; orderly liquidation authority, or OLA; living wills; and Federal , or FDIC, resolution.36 While there are many differences between these policies, they share important similarities. These processes seek to provide an orderly resolution to the institution’s life and operations, thus contributing to market confidence.37 They also aspire to create incentives to change behavior: A well-developed process for resolution should—in theory—make bailouts less credible as a policy solution because resolution is more easily available.38 As a result, big financial institutions should change their operations to avoid activities that might result in failure.

As a category, resolution is an ex-post technocratic reform designed to address bailouts, moral hazard problems, and implicit subsidies. To be sure, all resolu- tion policies have ex-ante effects by changing ex-post practices. Some might also categorize living wills as an ex-ante policy because the work of writing the will takes place before the firm is in trouble.39 In any event, by making failure more plausible, resolution hopes to make bailouts, moral hazard, and implicit subsidies less likely. Resolution does not directly address firm-level concerns or political- control concerns, but it might indirectly address both by giving firms an interest

11 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ in changing their practices and by making government actors less fearful of the too big to jail phenomenon. In addition, resolution might help alleviate certain systemic risks. On the one hand, resolution mitigates systemic risk because mar- ket actors know there is a reliable process in the event of a firm’s failure, which in turn should reduce the risk of contagion. However, some have argued that in the event of multiple simultaneous failures, it is unlikely the government will put all failing firms through a resolution process because of the instability that would create in the financial system.40

Size caps

Some have proposed capping the size of the largest financial institutions—an ex-ante, structural reform designed to end TBTF altogether.41 Putting aside the implementation questions—how to measure size and where to set the cap—this approach seeks to address a variety of concerns with size. Most directly, it aims to end TBTF’s moral hazard, bailout, and implicit subsidy problems through an ex-ante structural approach. If no firms are big enough to jeopardize the economy upon failure, then there would be no need for bailouts and no moral hazard or implicit subsidy.

Size caps address the size-based systemic-risk problem, and they also mitigate some of the concerns about too big to manage, regulatory failures, and legal accountability. In smaller firms, managers should have an easier time implement- ing internal controls and oversight, and regulators should have an easier time supervising activities. Prosecutors will also be less likely to fear prosecuting smaller-sized firms because the risk to the system would be reduced.

The downside to size caps is that they do not address concerns stemming from inter- connectedness and complexity. Smaller firms might still be interconnected, such that the failure of one influences the financial system as a whole. Similarly, complex- ity within firms might make it difficult for managers and regulators to supervise firm activities. At the same time, scholars have argued that size caps might mitigate the systemic risk of information effects. With more firms, the follow-the-leader effect should diminish, creating diversity within financial firm practices.42

12 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Glass-Steagall

A number of proposals can be grouped together under the rubric of Glass- Steagall: returning to Glass-Steagall, a new Glass-Steagall,43 ring fencing,44 and the Volcker Rule.45 Despite frequent commentary, there is a great deal of confusion about these proposals. The central principle underlying all of them is that different kinds of activity should take place in different financial institutions.

The Glass-Steagall regime—which included the and the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956—forced the separation of three types of financial services: depository institutions, investment banking, and insurance underwrit- ing. Calls for a new Glass-Steagall are not focused solely on returning to the old regime’s delineations, but are inspired by the underlying idea of separating dif- ferent financial activities from one another.46 Both ring fencing and the Volcker Rule are weaker versions of this renewed concept of separation. The Volcker Rule separates fewer activities, limiting banks and their affiliates from proprietary trading. Ring fencing addresses many activities but does not fully separate them, relying instead on walls within each institution between the different activities. These proposals are all ex ante and structural, though the Volcker Rule is argu- ably ex ante and technocratic.

Functional separation deals with the interconnectedness and complexity of the financial industry. By separating activities into different institutions, separation should make individual institutions far less complicated, enabling managers to implement better internal controls and regulators to supervise activities. It also creates fragmentation within the financial sector, which may reduce political or regulatory capture. While some forms of systemic risk such as contagion are likely to exist even with separation—because, for example, firms in different sectors may have contracts with each other—separation does mitigate other forms of systemic risk. Panics and informational issues, for example, are more likely to be confined to a specific sector. Of course, functional differentiation cannot guarantee sound practices: was not a on the scale of when it failed in 2008. Still, the interconnectedness risks at Citigroup, for exam- ple, remain so significant that two of its former leaders have called for breaking up the institution with Glass-Steagall-like separation.47 In addition, separation makes it less likely that a particular firm will fail due to risky activities rooted in internal complexity and cross-subsidization within the firm.

13 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Separation indirectly addresses other concerns as well. Separation of big, complex financial institutions would result in breaking them up along functional lines, creating smaller institutions. Of course, separation does not address size com- pletely—one can imagine spinning off its depository business and it remaining extremely large. In addition, separation indirectly addresses bail- outs, moral hazard, and subsidies. Separation might lead to a change in the culture of risk-taking in different sectors.48 It also enables different treatment for different sectors: Some institutions, such as depositories, could be given a public insurance program as the FDIC currently does, and others, such as hedge funds, could be denied any explicit or implicit bailout or insurance. With separation, both culture and policy may make bailouts, moral hazard, and implicit subsidies less likely.

Prudential regulation

Another category of TBTF remedies can be referred to as prudential regulation. Prudential regulation is the archetype of ex-ante technocratic policy. It assumes that regulators can institute policies that will manage risk within firms, known as microprudential regulation, or within the , referred to as macroprudential regulation.

It is helpful to further divide microprudential regulation into two categories: super- vision and regulation. Supervision involves government supervisors monitoring activities from within financial institutions, while regulation involves government establishing rules, standards, and guidance on permissible firm activities. The most prominent microprudential policies are capital requirements, including leverage ratios and contingent capital requirements, and liquidity requirements, both of which require technical judgment in setting the proper levels to adequately manage risk.49 Some commentators have advocated for greater reliance on equity because it effectively means self-insurance for financial institutions, changes their behavior toward risk, and is not socially costly.50 Macroprudential regulation often uses the same tools but it is focused more on addressing systemwide risk than institution-specific risk. The creation of the Financial Stability Oversight Council, or FSOC, is the result of a belief that regulators can do better than they have in the past with respect to macroprudential monitoring and regulation.

The central justification for prudential regulations is that they improve the safety and soundness of financial institutions, preventing them from failing in the first place. A second benefit is that they reduce moral hazard—and in the process should reduce the cost of bailouts if they are necessary.51 Prudential regulation

14 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ should make firms less likely to take on large amounts of risky behavior, which should also improve executives’ control over firm activities. In a sense, this reduced risk from firm bets going bad alleviates some of the burdens on regulatory supervision because the limited consequences mean supervisors have less to be worried about. Prudential regulation might also address certain forms of sys- temic risk, including the effects of panics because, for example, institutions would maintain more capital or have greater liquidity. Finally, many argue that prudential regulation such as leverage requirements should lead to smaller financial institu- tions, as banks will be encouraged to sell their most risky assets.52

The drawbacks to prudential regulation are less frequently discussed. Foremost, prudential regulation is extremely costly, complex, and intensive. It requires a great deal of effort by expert bureaucrats to design regulatory policies and to keep up with them as the market changes. For those skeptical of the ability of civil servants to oversee the financial sector, prudential regulation may therefore be problematic. In addition, prudential regulation risks regulatory capture. In order to design complex regulations that grapple with the dynamic and varied activities taking place in the financial markets, regulators are more likely to need experience working in the regu- lated industry. This increases the likelihood of cognitive capture among regulators.

Fees and taxes

Some have called for imposing fees or taxes on the biggest financial institutions. Fees and taxes are an ex-ante technocratic approach to reforming bigness. Some propos- als take aim at implicit subsidies, moral hazard, and bailouts. They compare the banks’ implicit subsidy to a free government insurance plan, and they seek to have the banks internalize the cost for that insurance.53 Fees or taxes could also act as a way to pay for a possible bailout fund in the event that bailouts are necessary. Taking a more comprehensive approach, fees or taxes could be used to require large finan- cial institutions to internalize the full costs of their activities, potentially including lost gross domestic product, or GDP, and effects of unemployment, among other social costs.54 Others argue that a tax on the size of financial institutions will help cut the biggest banks down to size, addressing size-based systemic risk.55

Fees and taxes suffer from a number of technical challenges, in particular how to determine the amount of the fee or tax. But they also extend to a broader issue: Do we want to put a price on the underlying activity? A set fee or tax would enable financial institutions that are willing to pay to continue engaging in the

15 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ underlying risky behavior. As a society, we may simply prefer that the risky activ- ity, even if compensated by a fee, does not take place at all—and this may be particularly true if the fee or tax does not account for all the indirect costs, such as employment losses, of firm failure to the economy.

Internal controls

Some think that instituting better internal controls within financial institutions could help address the riskiness of firm behavior and that firm management can be incentivized to adopt more stringent controls. The most prominent internal con- trol mechanisms are regulating pay of the CEO, executives, or bankers, requiring executive certifications, and regulating risk-management committees.

Scholars have argued that compensation is often tied to short-term results and is fre- quently structured so that bankers get compensation that is linked to gains but insu- lated from losses—meaning they are paid highly if all goes well, but are also paid well if things go wrong.56 If compensation structures are regulated, the regulations could create incentives for executives to ensure the bank is engaged in less risky behavior. Executive certifications use psychological and legal tools instead of economic incen- tives, requiring executives to certify that activities are legal and that controls are in place. Advocates argue that these certifications make it more likely the executive will feel responsible for the certified activity because he or she is affixing his or her name to documents attesting to the legality of the activity. As a result, the executive should feel obligated to impose more stringent internal controls.57 Certifications are a feature of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and Volcker Rule regulation, and they have been suggested in other contexts as well.58 Finally, pursuant to the Dodd-Frank Act, the has recently issued rules relating to risk-management committees within financial institutions.59 These rules are designed to structure internal manage- ment systems in a manner that will prevent excessive risk-taking.

Incentives to create more stringent internal controls are ex-ante technocratic policies that directly address the firm-level concerns with size. Greater internal controls should give management a better handle on the activities taking place in their firms, and regulators should have an easier time supervising firm activities as a result. Internal controls might also mitigate concerns about legal accountability, as certifications and pay incentives should push executives to implement policies that improve legal compliance. In addition, internal controls indirectly affect the riskiness of firm activities, which may combat the informational version of systemic

16 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ risk. Recall that under this version of systemic risk, the failure of firm A unveils information about practices within firm A, which when discovered to exist in firms B and C, might lead to those other firms failure. Internal controls, in theory, should make it more likely that firms B and C have different—that is, less risky—practices.

The problems with internal controls are readily visible. First, these mechanisms do not directly confront the risky practices themselves. Rather, they rely on incentives and decision-making processes such as risk committees. The result is that these methods might not be terribly effective. Managers hostile to internal-control mechanisms might not take controls seriously. For example, in a complex financial institution, executives might just sign off on certifica- tions, knowing they will be penalized legally or via public opinion, regardless of the level of internal controls they develop in the company. In addition, these approaches do not address most of the central concerns with TBTF: systemic risk, bailouts, implicit subsidies, and political capture.

17 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Conclusion

The concerns with big financial institutions are varied, ranging from bailouts and implicit subsidies to systemic risk to political, regulatory, and legal capture. The best solution or solutions to adopt will depend largely on which concerns are most at issue. Of course, different people will come to different conclusions on how troubling each of the concerns with TBTF are, and policymakers will there- fore prefer different solutions. But the first step is identifying why TBTF is bad for our financial system and the economy as a whole—and then outlining how to address those specific concerns.

TABLE 1 Linking problems and solutions in the TBTF debate Cap Glass- Fees Internal Prudential Resolution the size Steagall and taxes controls regulation Moral hazard ● ● ● ● ● Bailout costs ● ● ● ● ● Implicit subsidy ● ● ● ● Regulatory playing field ● ● Size-systemic risk ● ● ● ● Interconnected-systemic ● ● risk System effects- systemic ● ● ● ● risk Firm-level concerns ● ● ● ● ● Regulatory challenges ● ● ● ● Legal accountability ● ● ● ● Political and regulatory ● ● capture

Ex ante ● ● ● ● ● Ex post ● Structural ● ● Technocratic ● ● ● ●

● = Directly addresses issue ● = Indirectly or partly addresses issue

18 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ About the author

Ganesh Sitaraman is a Senior Fellow at the Center for American Progress and an assistant professor of law at Vanderbilt Law School. From 2011 to 2013, he served as policy director for the for Senate campaign and senior counsel to Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D-MA). Prior to Warren’s successful Senate bid, Sitaraman served as an advisor to Warren when she was chair of the Congressional Oversight Panel for the Troubled Asset Relief Program, or TARP.

19 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Endnotes

1 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protec- 13 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” pp. 489–490; Thomas tion Act, Public Law 203, 111th Cong. (July 21, 2010), M. Hoenig, “Financial Reform: Post Crisis?”, Speech at 1376–2223. Women in Housing and Finance, Washington D.C., Feb- ruary 23, 2011, available at http://www.kansascityfed. 2 Stephen Gandel, “By every measure, the big banks org/publicat/speeches/hoenig-DC-Women-Housing- are bigger,” Fortune, September 13, 2013, available at Finance-2-23-11.pdf. http://finance.fortune.cnn.com/2013/09/13/too-big-to- fail-banks/. 14 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 490; Hoenig, “Finan- cial Reform,” p. 5. 3 Louise C. Bennetts, “‘Too Big to Fail’ Is a Distraction,” American Banker, March 6, 2013, available at http:// 15 Richard Fisher, “Ending ‘Too Big to Fail’: A Proposal for www.americanbanker.com/bankthink/too-big-to-fail- Reform Before It’s Too Late,” Speech to the Committee is-a-distraction-1057258-1.html. for the Republic, Washington, D.C., January 16, 2013, available at http://www.dallasfed.org/news/speeches/ 4 Steven L. Schwarcz, “Systemic Risk,” Georgetown Law fisher/2013/fs130116.cfm; Sheila C. Bair, “We Must Re- Journal 97 (1) (2008) . For a review of the definitions solve to End Too Big to Fail,” Speech to the 47th Annual of systemic risk, see Adam J. Levitin, “In Defense of Conference on Bank Structure and Competition of the Bailouts,” Georgetown Law Journal 99 (2011): 435–514. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, May 5, 2011, avail- able at https://www.fdic.gov/news/news/speeches/ 5 James Kwak, “Treasury and the Blogs,” The Baseline archives/2011/spmay0511.html. Scenario, November 6, 2009, available at http://baseli- nescenario.com/2009/11/06/treasury-and-the-blogs/; 16 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, “TBTF Subsidy Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 452; Jerome H. Pow- for Large Banks—Literature Review” (2014), available at ell, “Ending ‘Too Big to Fail,’” Speech to the International http://www.fdic.gov/news/news/speeches/literature- Bankers 2013 Washington Conference, Washington, review.pdf; International Monetary Fund, “Global D.C., March 4, 2013, available at http://www.federalre- Financial Stability Report: Moving from Liquidity- to serve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20130304a.htm. Growth-Driven Markets” (2014), available at http:// www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/2014/01/pdf/text. 6 Alice M. Rivlin, “Systemic Risk and the Role of the Fed- pdf. eral Reserve” (Washington: Pew Task Force on Economic Reform, 2009), available at http://www.brookings. 17 Matthew C. Klein, “How Our Big Banks Really Make their edu/~/media/Research/Files/Reports/2009/7/ Money,” BloombergView, March 31, 2014, available at 29%20systemic%20risk%20rivlin/0729_systemic_risk_ http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/2014-03-31/ rivlin.PDF; Sheri Markose, “Too Interconnected to Fail,” how-our-big-banks-really-make-their-money. Presentation to IMF Workshop on Operationalizing Systemic Risk Monitoring, May 26–28, 2010, available at 18 Independent Community Bankers of America, “End http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2010/ Too-Big-to-Fail” (2013), available at http:// mcm/pdf/SMarkose.pdf. www.icba.org/files/ICBASites/PDFs/EndTBTFStudy.pdf.

7 Jeffrey N. Gordon and Christopher Muller, “Confronting 19 Ben W. Heineman, Jr., “Too Big to Manage: JP Morgan Financial Crisis: Dodd-Frank’s Dangers and the Case for and the Mega Banks,” Harvard Business Review, Octo- a Systemic Emergency Insurance Fund,” Yale Journal on ber 3, 2013, available at http://blogs.hbr.org/2013/10/ Regulation 28 (1) (2011); Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” too-big-to-manage-jp-morgan-and-the-mega-banks/; p. 455. Richard W. Fisher and Harvey Rosenblum, “How Huge Banks Threaten the Economy,” The Wall Street Journal, 8 President , “Remarks by the President on April 4, 2012, available at http://online.wsj.com/news/ the American Automotive Industry,” March 30, 2009, articles/SB100014240527023038165045773121108213 available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press- 40648; Central Banker, “The Big Banks: Too Complex to office/remarks-president-american-automotive-indus- Manage?,” Winter 2012, available at http://www.stlouis- try-33009. fed.org/publications/cb/articles/?id=2328; Julian Birkin- shaw and Suzanne Heywood, “Too Big to Manage?”, The 9 Gordon and Muller, “Confronting Financial Crisis,” p. Wall Street Journal, October 26, 2009, available at http:// 160; Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 458; Jonathan R. online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB100014240529702035 Macey and James P. Holdcroft, “Failure Is an Option: An 85004574392673999432000. Ersatz-Antitrust Approach to ,” The Yale Law Journal 120 (6) (2011): 1278–1589. 20 Heineman, “Too Big to Manage.”

10 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 460. 21 Fisher, “Ending ‘Too Big to Fail.’”

11 Daniel Tarullo, “Confronting Too Big to Fail,” Speech 22 , “Let’s Keep Banks from Growing Too at the Exchequer Club, Washington, D.C., October 21, Big to Regulate,” The Washington Post, April 30, 2010, 2009, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/ available at http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/ newsevents/speech/tarullo20091021a.htm. content/article/2010/04/29/AR2010042902358.html.

12 Viral V. Acharya and Tanju Yorulmazer, “Too many to 23 Fisher and Rosenblum, “How Huge Banks Threaten fail—An analysis of time-inconsistency in bank closure the Economy”; Thomas M. Hoenig and Charles S. policies,” Journal of Financial Intermediation 16 (2007): Morris, “Restructuring the Banking System to Improve 1–31, available at http://iiw.uni-bonn.de/semin- Safety and Soundness” Testimony before the Senate are/2011/regulierung/unterlagen/Thema%201.6%20 Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, Acharya,%20Yorulmazer%20%282007%29.pdf. May 9, 2012, available at http://www.fdic.gov/about/ learn/board/hoenig/Restructuring-the-Banking- System,Hoenig,Morris,Nov.2013.pdf.

20 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ 24 Karen Petrou, “A New Framework for Systemic Financial 33 21st Century Glass-Steagall Act of 2013, S. 1282, 113 Regulation” (Washington: Federal Financial Analytics Cong. 1 sess. (Government Printing Office, 2013), avail- Inc., 2011), available at http://www.fedfin.com/images/ able at http://www.warren.senate.gov/files/documen stories/client_reports/complexityriskpaper.pdf; Hoenig ts/21stCenturyGlassSteagall.pdf; Thomas M. Hoenig, and Morris, “Restructuring the Banking System to “Back to the Business of Banking,” Speech to the 29th Improve Safety and Soundness,” p. 19. Annual Monetary and Trade Conference of the Global Interdependence Center and Drexel University LeBow 25 Mark A. Calabria and Lisa Gilbert, “Are Banks Too Big to College of Business, May 24, 2011, available at http:// Jail?”, Cato Institute, January 6, 2014, available at http:// www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/speeches/Hoenig- www.cato.org/publications/commentary/are-banks- MonetaryandTradeConference-05-24-11.pdf. See also too-big-jail. Julie A.D. Manasfi, “Systemic Risk and Dodd-Frank’s Volcker Rule,” William & Mary Business Law Review 4 (1) 26 For a discussion of this issue, see Matt Taibbi, “Gangster (2013): 181–212. Bankers: Too Big to Jail,” Rolling Stone, February 14, 2013, available at http://www.rollingstone.com/poli- 34 For a helpful discussion of ex ante and ex post reforms tics/news/gangster-bankers-too-big-to-jail-20130214; in the financial context, see Steven L. Schwarcz, , “Too Big to Jail,” December 15, 2012, “Keynote Address: Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Approaches available at http://www.economist.com/news/finance- to Financial Regulation,” Chapman Law Review 15 (1) and-economics/21568403-two-big-british-banks- (2011): 257–269. reach-controversial-settlements-too-big-jail. 35 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts”; Powell, “Ending ‘Too Big 27 Eric Holder, Testimony before the Senate Judiciary to Fail.’”; Satya Thallam, “Reconsidering Too Big to Fail” Committee, March 6, 2013, available at http://www. (Washington: American Action Forum, 2014), available americanbanker.com/issues/178_45/transcript-attor- at http://americanactionforum.org/uploads/files/re- ney-general-eric-holder-on-too-big-to-jail-1057295-1. search/AAF_too_big_to_fail.pdf. html. Holder later backtracked: Jason M. Breslow, “Eric Holder Backtracks Remarks on ‘Too Big To Jail,’” Front- 36 For an overview, see Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” pp. line, May 16, 2013, available at http://www.pbs.org/ 478, 483–89; Gordon and Muller, “Confronting Financial wgbh/pages/frontline/business-economy-financial- Crisis,” pp. 185–93. crisis/untouchables/eric-holder-backtracks-remarks- on-too-big-to-jail/. Similarly, Assistant Attorney General 37 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 478. Lanny Breuer commented in a 2012 speech that he takes into account the effect a prosecution might have 38 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 467. on shareholders, markets, or the economy as a whole. See Lanny A. Breuer, Speech to the New York City Bar 39 For a helpful overview of the difference between Association, September 13, 2012, available at http:// Dodd-Frank Title I (living will) and Title II (resolution) www.justice.gov/criminal/pr/speeches/2012/crm- authorities, see Thomas Hoenig, “Can We End Financial speech-1209131.html. Bailouts?” Speech to the Boston Economic Club, May 7, 2014, available at http://www.fdic.gov/news/news/ 28 Simon Johnson and James Kwak, 13 Bankers: The Wall speeches/spmay0714.html. Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown (New York: Pantheon Books, 2010). 40 Gordon and Muller, “Confronting Financial Crisis,” pp. 153–54. 29 Kevin Connor, “Big Bank Takeover: How Too-Big-to- Fail’s Army of Lobbyists Has Captured Washington” 41 Brown-Kauffman Amendment of 2010, S2765, SA 3733, (Washington: Institute for America’s Future, 2011), avail- 111 Cong., (Government Printing Office, 2010), avail- able at http://public-accountability.org/wp-content/ able at https://beta.congress.gov/crec/2010/04/28/ uploads/2011/09/big-bank-takeover-final.pdf. CREC-2010-04-28-pt1-PgS2765.pdf; Macey and Hold- croft, “Failure Is an Option.” 30 Simon Johnson, “Too Politically Connected to Fail in Any Crisis,” The Baseline Scenario, October 8, 2009, 42 Macey and Holdcroft, “Failure Is an Option,” pp. available at http://baselinescenario.com/2009/10/08/ 1383–1384. too-politically-connected-to-fail-in-any-crisis/; Gordon and Muller, “Confronting Financial Crisis,” p. 178. For 43 21st Century Glass-Steagall Act of 2013. a discussion of cultural capture, see David Freeman Engstrom, “Corralling Capture,” Harvard Journal of Law 44 Independent Commission on Banking, “Interim and Public Policy 36 (1) (2012): 31–39. Report: Consulation on Reform Options” (2011), available at http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov. 31 Adam J. Levitin, “The Politics of Financial Regulation uk/20121204124254/http://www.hm-treasury.gov. and the Regulation of Financial Politics,” Harvard Law uk/d/icb_interim_report_full_document.pdf; High- Review 127 (7) (2014): 1992–2067. level Expert Group on Reforming the Structure of the EU Banking Sector, “Final report (the )” 32 Bennetts, “‘Too Big to Fail’ Is a Distraction”; Nin-Hai (2012), available at http://ec.europa.eu/internal_mar- Tseng, “A new Glass Steagall Won’t Prevent Another ket/bank/docs/high-level_expert_group/report_en.pdf. Financial Crisis,” Fortune, July 15, 2013, available at http://finance.fortune.cnn.com/2013/07/15/glass-stea- 45 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection gall-elizabeth-warren/; Steven Pearlstein, “Shattering Act, Public Law 203, 111th Cong., (July 21, 2010) § 619 the Glass-Steagall Myth,” The Washington Post, July 28, (codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1851). 2012, available at http://www.washingtonpost.com/ lets-shatter-the-myth-on-glass-steagall/2012/07/27/ 46 Hoenig, “Back to the Business of Banking”; Thomas M. gJQASaOAGX_story.html. Hoenig, “Do SIFIs have a Future?”, Speech to conference “Dodd-Frank One Year On,” Pew Financial Reform Proj- ect and New York University Stern School of Business, June 27, 2011.

21 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ 47 John Reed, “Ex-Citi CEO John Reed: We Need To 53 For a discussion, see Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” Break Up The Big Banks,” Huffington Post, Sep- p. 473; Arthur E. Wilmarth, Jr., “The Dodd-Frank Act: A tember 9, 2013, available at http://www.huffing- Flawed and Inadequate Response to the Too-Big-To-Fail tonpost.com/2013/09/09/john-reed-break-up- Problem,” Oregon Law Review 89 (3) (2011): 951–1058. banks_n_3893687.html; Michael J. De la Merced, “Weill Calls for Splitting Up Big Banks,” The New York Times, 54 Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Too Big to Live,” Project Syndi- July 25, 2012, available at http://dealbook.nytimes. cate, December 7, 2009, available at http://www. com/2012/07/25/weill-calls-for-splitting-up-big-banks/. project-syndicate.org/commentary/too-big-to-live; Willem Buiter, “Too Big to Fail Is Too Big,” Financial 48 Andrew G. Haldane, “On Being the Right Size,” Speech Times, June 24, 2009, available at http://blogs. to the Institute of Economic Affairs’ 22nd Annual Series, ft.com/maverecon/2009/06/too-big-to-fail-is-too- The 2012 Beesley Lectures, October 25, 2012, available big/#axzz32RJ2nkQu. at http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/ Documents/speeches/2012/speech615.pdf. 55 Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” p. 463.

49 For a discussion of Dodd Frank’s prudential regulation 56 Lucian A. Bebchuk and Holger Spamann, “Regulating requirements, see Levitin, “In Defense of Bailouts,” pp. Bankers’ Pay,” Georgetown Law Journal 98 (2) (2010): 476–477; Schwarcz, “Systemic Risk,” pp. 211-225; John C. 247–287; Sanjai Bhagat and Roberta Romano, “Reform- Coffee Jr., “Systemic Risk After Dodd Frank: Contingent ing, Executive Compensation: Focusing and Commit- Capital and the Need for Regulatory Strategies Beyond ting to the Long-Term,” Yale Journal on Regulation 26 Oversight,” Columbia Law Review 111 (795) (2011): 795– (2) (2009): 359–372; Frederick Tung, “Pay for Banker 847; Hal S. Scott, “The Reduction of Systemic Risk in the Performance: Structuring Executive Compensation United States Financial System,” Harvard Journal of Law for Risk Regulation,” Working Paper 10-93 (Emory & Public Policy 33 (2) (2010): 671–734; For a discussion University School of Law, Public Law and Legal Theory of contingent convertibles, see Charles W. Calomiris Research Paper Series, 2010), available at http://ssrn. and Richard J. Herring, “How to Design a Contingent com/abstarct=1546229. Convertible Debt Requirement That Helps to Solve Our Too Big to Fail Problem,” Journal of Applied Corporate 57 Merritt B. Fox, Required Disclosure and Corporate Gov- Finance 25 (2) (2013): 21–44, available at http://fic.whar- ernance, Law and Contemporary Problems 62 (3) (1999): ton.upenn.edu/fic/Policy%20page/25.Calomiris_forth- 113–127. coming.pdf; Ze’ev Eiger, “Frequently Asked Questions about Contingent Capital” (San Francisco: Morrison & 58 For an analysis of the requirements in Sarbanes-Oxley, Foerster, 2014), available at http://www.mofo.com/files/ see White & Case, LLP, “Short Guide to CEO and CFO Uploads/Images/FAQs-Contingent-Capital.pdf. Certifications and Internal Control Reporting Under the Sarbanes-Oxley Act” (2003), available at http://www. 50 Anat Admati and Martin Hellwig, The Bankers’ New whitecase.com/files/Publication/6cc6997f-c2f1-496b- Clothes: What’s Wrong with Banking and What to Do aab9-9c39c76f8783/Presentation/PublicationAttach- About It (Princeton, NJ: Press, ment/ad2ac9f2-ad26-4a6e-b5ee-a0b771c027ff/memo_ 2013). short_guide_to_ceo_10_9_03.pdf. For discussions on the Volker Rule, see Sullivan & Cromwell, LLP, “Volcker 51 Tarullo, “Confronting Too Big to Fail”; Daniel Tarullo, Rule” (2014), available at http://www.sullcrom.com/ “Regulating Systemically Important Financial Firms,” siteFiles/Publications/SC_Publication_Volcker_Rule.pdf. Speech at the Peter G. Peterson Institute for Interna- tional Economics, Washington, D.C., June 3, 2011, avail- 59 Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection able at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/ Act, Public Law 203, 111 Cong., 2d sess. (July 21, 2010) § speech/tarullo20110603a.htm. 165(h) (codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5365(h)); for an overview see Davis Polk & Wardwell, LLP, “U.S. Bank Holding 52 Mayra Rodriguez Valladares, “Why the Bank Leverage Companies: Overview of Dodd-Frank Enhanced Ratio Is Important,” The New York Times, Febru- Prudential Standards Final Rule” (2014), http://www. ary 28, 2014, available at http://dealbook.nytimes. davispolk.com/sites/default/files/Visual.Summary.US_. com/2014/02/28/why-the-bank-leverage-ratio-is- Bank_.Holding.Companies.Dodd_.Frank_.Enhanced. important/?_php=true&_type=blogs&_r=0. Prudential.Standards.pdf.

22 Center for American Progress | Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ The Center for American Progress is a nonpartisan research and educational institute dedicated to promoting a strong, just and free America that ensures opportunity for all. We believe that Americans are bound together by a common commitment to these values and we aspire to ensure that our national policies reflect these values. We work to find progressive and pragmatic solutions to significant domestic and international problems and develop policy proposals that foster a government that is “of the people, by the people, and for the people.”

1333 H STREET, NW, 10TH FLOOR, WASHINGTON, DC 20005 • TEL: 202-682-1611 • FAX: 202-682-1867 • WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG