Intuitions About Penalties and Compensation in the Context of Tort Law

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Intuitions About Penalties and Compensation in the Context of Tort Law Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7:17-33 (1993) © 1993 Kluwer Academic Publishers Intuitions about Penalties and Compensation in the Context of Tort Law JONATHAN BARON Department of Psychology, University of Pennsylvania, 3SI5 Walnut Street, Philadelphia, PA 19104-6196 I LAN A RITOV* Department of Industrial Enffncering and Management, Ben-Gurion University, P.O. Box 653, Beer Sheeva 84105, Isrnel Abstract Students, retired judges, economists, and others made judgments of appropriate penalties and compen,sation for hypothetical injuries. In some scenarios, compensation was paid by the government and penalties were paid to the government, so the two could differ. Penalties were generally uninfluenced by their deterrent effect on future behavior. Penalties were greater when they were paid directly to the victim than when they were paid to the government. Compensation was affected by whether injuries were caused by people or by nature, or by acts vs, omissions. These effects are not justified according to consequentialist views of penalties and compensation. We suggest that people are overgeneralizing reasonable rules and that such overgeneralization may be in- volved in perverse effects of tort law. Key words: tort law, penalties, compensations, intuitive judgments When one person (or group) harms another, people often think that the injurer should compensate the victim. Tort law can compel compensation. Such a transaction not only compensates the victim but also punishes the injurer. When the injurer compensates the victim, as when a child is induced to give back something she has taken or when a victim sues an injurer in court, punishment and compensation are linked together. Sometimes these functions are separated. Criminals are punished whether or not their victims are compensated. Insurance (private and social) provides compensation for misfortunes regardless of whether they are caused by people or nature, and regardless of whether the insurer collects from the injurer. In the studies described here, we sought to understand how people think about pun- ishment and compensation in the context of hypothetical cases in which people are killed or injured by birth-control pills or vaccines. These are typical situations in which lawsuits against companies occur. Some of our cases separated punishment and compensation, so that we could learn how people think about each function alone. *We thank David Houston, Robert Field, Rajeev Gowda, John C, Hershey, Jacqueline Meszaros, George Priest, and the anonymous reviewers for helpful suggestions, and Penny Pollister and Joanne Schwartz for research assistance. This work was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation (SES-8809299), 18 JONATHAN BARON/ILANA RITOV It has been argued that the tort system sometimes leads systematically to undesirable results (e.g., Huber, 1988,1991). Rather than encouraging safety improvements or caus- ing harmful products to be withdrawn, tort penalties have caused highly beneficial prod- ucts—such as vaccines and birth-control products—to be withdrawn and have led to a reduction in research and development expenditures for similar products. For example, pertussis vaccine might cause brain damage or death in small numbers of children, although whooping cough, the disease it prevents, is far more dangerous. Production of this vaccine in the U,S, declined drastically as a result of lawsuits (David, 1986; Hinman, 1986; Huber, 1988; Inglehart, 1987), and the price increased, although the passage of a (partial) no-fault compensation law in 1986 may have reversed this trend (Hofmann, 1988). Likewise, research on new birth-control methods seems to have decreased for the same reason (Djerassi, 1989; Huber, 1988; Mastroianni, Donaldson and Kane, 1990), Viscusi and Moore (in press) present general evidence that liability costs tend to increase research and development expenditures up to a point and then cause a decline when the costs are sufficiently high. Although it is likely that some products should he withdrawn from the market, or not developed, because their harm exceeds their benefit, the examples cited by Viscusi and Moore, as well as those just cited, suggest that many successful lawsuits do not involve such harmful products. The motive of courts in these cases could have been to compensate victims, but U,S, society makes no comparable effort to compensate victims of natural disease for their misfortune. In this article, we suggest that undesirable results of the liability system could result in part from the intuitions of those involved in the system—judges, lawyers, plain- tiffs, defendants, and juries—about what penalties ought to be assessed and what com- pensation ought to be paid. In particular, two basic intuitive principles may be involved: the desire for retribution against an injurer, whatever the consequences; and the depen- dence of compensation judgments on judgments of human responsibility, so that com- pensation is considered more necessary when the injury is caused by a human act. These effects could be exacerbated by the usual linkage of compensation and penalties. Use of these intuitive principles, which are not based on expected consequences, could help to produce the kinds of undesirable outcomes that have led to complaints. Conceivably, the attempt to consider consequences directly might be self-defeating, and intuitive rules of this sort might yield better results in the long run. However, people who accept rules without understanding their consequentialist justifications can be in- duced to use rules that have no such justification. 1. Consequentialist accounts of penalties and compensation Consequentialism justifies penalties by their deterrent function, i.e., by the fact that they provide an incentive to do something other than what was penalized. Thus, a penalty with no beneficial deterrent effect is simply an unjustified wrong against the injurer, and "two wrongs don't make a right," Even if other factors are involved in determining penalties, we might expect deterrence considerations to affect their magnitude. INTUITIONS ABOUT PENALTIES AND COMPENSATION IN THE CONTEXT OF TORT LAW 19 Several scholars from the "law and economics" tradition (e.g., Brown, 1973; Landes and Posner, 1987; Shavell, 1987) have argued that deterrence provides the main justifi- cation of the common law of torts. Landes and Posner (1987) argue that common law has evolved to serve this function, despite the fact that many of its precepts seem nonintuitive to laypeople and the fact that the judges who made the law did not themselves under- stand the full economic rationale. Compensation can be given a consequentialist justification as a form of insurance, as when damaged property is replaced by an injurer or an insurance company (Calabresi, 1970). The loss increases the utility of money for the victim: if your car is stolen, you can use money more efiiciently to achieve your goals than you could before, e.g., you can buy a new car (Calfee and Rubin, in press; Friedman, 1982; Schwartz, 1988). It is irrelevant to this justification whether an injury is brought about by a negligent act, an innocent act, an omission, or a natural misfortune. (Compensation can also be justified as an incentive for victims to sue or complain.) Critics of the U.S. legal system maintain that those who sue successfully are well compensated, while others who sufi'er the same injury at the hands of nature (or the hands of a "shallow pocket") are left to fend for themselves, although the insurance justification is the same in both cases. 2. Psychological mechanisms We hypothesize that people make judgments of penalties and compensation on the basis of general intuitive rules, which often do produce the best consequences, but that people do not understand the consequentialist justifications of these rules (Baron, 1991, in press). As a result, people apply the rules to cases in which the justifications are absent. Previous studies (e.g.. Baron and Hershey, 1988; Ritov and Baron, 1990; Spranca, Minsk, and Baron, 1991) support these general claims. Two instances of the general hypothesis are examined: 1) people will not refer to the deterrence justification of punishment judgments on other principles, such as retribution; and 2) compensation judgments will be afi'ected by factors that afi'ect penalties but do not affect the insurance function of compensation; these factors include the negligence of the injurer and whether the injury was caused by an act, by an omission, or by nature. Retribution and deterrence are typically correlated. Through observation, people could come to think of punishment solely as retribution, without understanding that retribution is beneficial at least partly because of its correlation with deterrence. Their intuitive rule for the justification of punishment is, then, that it should depend on the magnitude of the harm and the intention behind it (Fincham and Jaspers, 1980), not on its deterrent efi'ect. When the correlation between deterrence and retribution is broken, they will stick with retribution. Other research suggests that many people do not take deterrence into account. Baron, Gowda, and Kunreuther (1993) have examined intuitions about deterrence in the con- text of hazardous waste, where compensation is not at issue. The subjects included 20 JONATHAN BARON/ILANA RITOV experts in hazardous waste legislation, retired judges, economists, members of environ- mental organizations, legislators, and officers of corporations. The questionnaire
Recommended publications
  • Day Fines in American Courts
    If you have issues viewing or accessing this file contact us at NCJRS.gov. U.S. Department of Justice Office of Justice Programs NalionallnSlilute ofJustice Day Fines in American Courts: The Staten Island and Milwaukee Experiments sa p c About the National Institute of Justice The National Institute of Justice is the research and development agency of the U.S. Department of Justice, est'~blished to prevent and redu-::e crime and to improve the criminal justice system. Specific mandates established by Congress in the Omnibus Crime Control and Safe Streets Act of 1968, as amended, and the Anti-Drug Abuse Act of 1988 direct the National Institute of Justice to: III Sponsor special projects and research·and development prugrums that will improve and strengthen lhe criminal justice system and reduce or prevent crime. III Conduct national demonstration projects that employ innovatiYe or promising approaches for improving criminal justice. III Del'e/op new technologies to fight crime and improve criminal justice. III Evaluate the effectiveness oj criminal justice programs ana identify programs that promise' to be successful if continued or repeated. .. Recommend actions that can be taken by Federal, State, and local governments as well as private organizations to improve criminal justice. III Carry out research on criminal behavior. II Develop new methods oj crime prevention and reduction of crime and delinquency. The National Institute of Justice has a long history of accomplishments, including the following: .. Basic research on career criminals that led to development of special police and prosecutor units to deal with repeat offenders. III Research that confirmed the link between drugs and crime.
    [Show full text]
  • Protecting Those Who Blow the Whistle on Government Wrongdoing
    Statement of Glenn A. Fine Principal Deputy Inspector General, Performing the Duties of the Inspector General, Department of Defense for a Hearing on Protecting Those Who Blow the Whistle on Government Wrongdoing Before the Subcommittee on Government Operations Committee on Oversight and Reform U.S. House of Representatives January 28, 2020 Chairman Connolly, Ranking Member Meadows, and members of the subcommittee, thank you for inviting me to appear before you today for this hearing on the contributions of federal whistleblowers and the need to protect them from reprisal. I. INTRODUCTION My testimony will focus on the important work of the Department of Defense Office of Inspector General (DoD OIG) relating to whistleblowers. I am the DoD Principal Deputy Inspector General, Performing the Duties of the Inspector General, and have been serving as the head of the DoD OIG for over 4 years. Prior to this position, in addition to working as an attorney in private practice, I was the Inspector General of the Department of Justice for 11 years, from 2000 to 2011. In my testimony today, I will discuss the significant contributions of whistleblowers, why the protection of whistleblowers is so important, how the DoD OIG evaluates and investigates whistleblower disclosures and complaints of reprisal, and several best practices we have implemented at the DoD OIG to improve our timeliness and efficiency in whistleblower investigations. Specifically, my testimony discusses: • the mission and responsibilities of the DoD OIG, • the importance of whistleblowers and the need to protect them from reprisal, • examples of cases resulting from whistleblower disclosures, • the DoD OIG’s investigative processes, • best practices that the DoD OIG has implemented to improve the timeliness and efficiency of reprisal investigations, 1 • the need for DoD management to take timely corrective action on substantiated whistleblower reprisal investigations, and • the need for adequate resources to handle these important responsibilities.
    [Show full text]
  • Penal Code Offenses by Punishment Range Office of the Attorney General 2
    PENAL CODE BYOFFENSES PUNISHMENT RANGE Including Updates From the 85th Legislative Session REV 3/18 Table of Contents PUNISHMENT BY OFFENSE CLASSIFICATION ........................................................................... 2 PENALTIES FOR REPEAT AND HABITUAL OFFENDERS .......................................................... 4 EXCEPTIONAL SENTENCES ................................................................................................... 7 CLASSIFICATION OF TITLE 4 ................................................................................................. 8 INCHOATE OFFENSES ........................................................................................................... 8 CLASSIFICATION OF TITLE 5 ............................................................................................... 11 OFFENSES AGAINST THE PERSON ....................................................................................... 11 CLASSIFICATION OF TITLE 6 ............................................................................................... 18 OFFENSES AGAINST THE FAMILY ......................................................................................... 18 CLASSIFICATION OF TITLE 7 ............................................................................................... 20 OFFENSES AGAINST PROPERTY .......................................................................................... 20 CLASSIFICATION OF TITLE 8 ..............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Misdemeanors
    MISDEMEANORS STUDY ON RECORD RETENTION, AVAILABILITY AND ACCESS OF RECORDS REGARDING FINE- ONLY MISDEMEANORS As directed by SB 47, 85th Legislature (Due 1/1/19) Contents Executive Summary ...................................................................................................................................... 1 Background ................................................................................................................................................... 2 Methodology ................................................................................................................................................ 2 Class C Misdemeanor Records For “Children Under Age 18” ................................................................... 4 Data Limitations ........................................................................................................................................ 4 Survey Results .............................................................................................................................................. 4 Access and Availability .............................................................................................................................. 4 Adult Records ............................................................................................................................................ 4 Records Access and Availability Policy .................................................................................................. 6 Records “Related to a Child
    [Show full text]
  • Alternatives to Custodial Supervision: the Day Fine
    Document Title: Alternatives to Custodial Supervision: The Day Fine Author(s): Edwin W. Zedlewski Document No.: NCJ 230401 Date Received: May 2010 This report has not been published by the U.S. Department of Justice. To provide better customer service, NCJRS has made this National Institute of Justice (NIJ) produced report available electronically in addition to traditional paper copies. Opinions or points of view expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the official position or policies of the U.S. Department of Justice. 1 Alternatives to Custodial Supervision: The Day Fine Edwin W. Zedlewski April 2010 NCJ 230401 Discussion Paper Alternatives to Custodial Supervision: The Day Fine Edwin W. Zedlewski April 2010 NCJ 230401 The opinions and conclusions expressed in this document are solely those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the U.S. Department of Justice. Alternatives to Custodial Supervision: The Day Fine Introduction Corrections populations in the U.S. have risen at alarming rates. From 1990 to 2007, probation populations rose 61 percent, with 4.3 million persons on probation as of December 31, 2007 (Bonczar and Glaze, 1999, 2008). Parole populations have risen 55 percent to a level of 824,000 persons (Bonczar and Glaze, 1999, 2008). Incarceration sentences have expanded by even greater amounts — jail populations rose 93 percent (to 780,000), and prison populations rose 311 percent (to 2.3 million inmates) over the same interval (Beck and Gilliard, 1996; Sabol and West, 2008) More than 7.2 million persons are under correctional supervision today (Bonczar and Glaze, 2008).
    [Show full text]
  • Damages Surprisingly Victims?
    10 Damages Personal Injury [10.10] What remedy does (and should) the legal system provide to tort victims? Although they may occasionally obtain injunctions intended to prevent ongoing harm, almost all successful tort claimants obtain money damages.’ A surprisingly large number of difficult and contested issues arise, however, in determining just how much money should be awarded. This chapter explores those issues. Part of the problem is factual uncertainty, especially, but not only, with respect to losses that will occur in the future, that is, after the trial or settlement of the case. But, in addition, there are fundamental legal questions at issue that centrally arise from disputes about the underlying reasons for awarding tort damages in the first place; whether tort law is ultimately compensatory, a deterrent or concerned with corrective justice is discussed in Chapter 1. The focus of this chapter will be on damages for bodily injury (and death). The material is organised in this way. First, the question of whether damages should be paid in a lump sum or periodically is addressed. Secondly, consideration is given to the strength of the proof plaintiffs must offer in order successfully to claim their damages. 2 So, The focus then shifts to the specific types of recoveries that are allowed. thirdly, considerable attention is given to what are typically termed pecuniary losses — (a) expenses incurred (or to be incurred) because of the harm the tortfeasor has imposed on the victim and (b) the victim’s lost income or lost earning power. Fourthly, compensatory awards for non-pecuniary losses (for example, pain and suffering) are explored.
    [Show full text]
  • Day Fines: Reviving the Idea and Reversing the (Costly) Punitive Trend
    DAY FINES: REVIVING THE IDEA AND REVERSING THE (COSTLY) PUNITIVE TREND Elena Kantorowicz-Reznichenko* “Pecuniary punishments should always be regulated by the fortune of the offender. The relative amount of the fine should be fixed, not its absolute amount. ...”1 INTRODUCTION For more than four decades, the United States has operated under “tough on crime” policies. This approach has led to the well-known prison crisis. Over the years, the number and costs of prisons in the United States has increased, the overcrowding problem has expanded, and court orders mandating the release of prisoners have become a common practice.2 In the last four decades, imprisonment became the “ordinary sanction.”3 Consequently, in 2015, the United States witnessed an astonishing rate of 666 prisoners per 100,000 of the national population.4 This expedited growth in incarceration led to the absurd situation where Americans constitute five percent of the global population, yet detain twenty-five percent of the world’s prisoners.5 This is a costly policy for the American taxpayer. For example, in 2015, California spent over 8.5 billion dollars on prisons alone,6 or approximately twenty-three million dollars per day.7 * Rotterdam Institute of Law and Economics (RILE), Erasmus School of Law, Erasmus University Rotterdam. I would like to thank Michael Faure, Christoph Engel, Louis Visscher, Paul Mevis, Anne-Lise Sibony, and Claire Mansfield for their valuable comments. In addition, I am grateful to the participants of the 1st Topics Workshop in Criminology at Erasmus University Rotterdam, Law and Market Behaviour International Research Network Conference in Dublin, and faculty seminars at Bologna University and at Erasmus University Rotterdam for their useful suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyright Infringement
    COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENT Mark Miller Jackson Walker L.L.P. 112 E. Pecan, Suite 2400 San Antonio, Texas 78205 (210) 978-7700 [email protected] This paper was first published in the State Bar of Texas Corporate Counsel Section Corporate Counsel Review, Vol. 30, No. 1 (2011) The author appreciates the State Bar’s permission to update and re-publish it. THE AUTHOR Mark Miller is a shareholder with Jackson Walker L.L.P., a Texas law firm with offices in San Antonio, Dallas, Houston, Austin, Ft. Worth, and San Angelo. He is Chair of the firm’s intellectual property section and concentrates on transactions and litigation concerning intellectual property, franchising, and antitrust. Mr. Miller received his B.A. in Chemistry from Austin College in 1974 and his J.D. from St. Mary’s University in 1978. He was an Associate Editor for St. Mary’s Law Journal; admitted to practice before the United States Patent and Trademark Office in 1978; served on the Admissions Committee for the U.S. District Court, Western District of Texas, and been selected as one of the best intellectual property lawyers in San Antonio. He is admitted to practice before the United States Supreme Court, the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals, the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth and Tenth Circuits, the District Courts for the Western, Southern, and Northern Districts of Texas, and the Texas Supreme Court. He is a member of the American Bar Association’s Forum Committee on Franchising, and the ABA Antitrust Section’s Committee on Franchising. Mr. Miller is a frequent speaker and writer, including “Neglected Copyright Litigation Issues,” State Bar of Texas, Intellectual Property Section, Annual Meeting, 2009, “Unintentional Franchising,” 36 St.
    [Show full text]
  • Contributors
    Contributors Edward J. McCaffery is Robert C. Packard Trustee Chair in Law and Po- litical Science at the University of Southern California and visiting pro- fessor of law and economics at the California Institute of Technology. Joel Slemrod is Paul W. McCracken Collegiate Professor of Business Economics and Public Policy, director of the Office of Tax Policy Research in the Stephen M. Ross School of Business, and professor of economics at the University of Michigan. Caroline Adams teaches psychology at the University of Plymouth, En- gland. Jonathan Baron is professor of psychology at the University of Pennsyl- vania. James J. Choi is assistant professor of finance at the Yale School of Man- agement. Terrence Chorvat is associate professor in the George Mason University, School of Law. John Cullis is reader in economics in the Department of Economics and International Development at the University of Bath in England. Henk Elffers is senior researcher at the Netherlands Institute for the Study of Crime and Law Enforcement and professor of psychology and law at Antwerp University in Belgium. Richard A. Epstein is James Parker Hall Distinguished Service Professor of Law at the University of Chicago and Peter and Kirsten Bedford Se- nior Fellow at the Hoover Institution. vii viii Behavioral Public Finance Hanming Fang is associate professor of economics at Yale University and faculty research fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Lee Anne Fennell is associate professor of law at the University of Illi- nois College of Law. Bruno S. Frey is professor of economics at the University of Zurich and research director of CREMA (Center for Research in Economics, Manage- ment and the Arts).
    [Show full text]
  • How to Use Structured Fines (Day Fines) As an Intermediate Sanction
    T O EN F J U.S. Department of Justice TM U R ST A I P C E E D B O J Office of Justice Programs C S F A V M F O I N A C I J S R E BJ G O OJJ DP O F PR Bureau of Justice Assistance JUSTICE Bureau of Justice Assistance How To Use Structured Fines (Day Fines) as an Intermediate Sanction Monograph Bureau of Justice Assistance How To Use Structured Fines (Day Fines) as an Intermediate Sanction November 1996 Monograph NCJ 156242 This document was prepared by The Justice Management Institute and the Vera Institute of Justice, supported by grant number 91–DD–CX–0016(S–2), awarded by the Bureau of Justice Assistance, Office of Justice Programs, U.S. Department of Justice. The opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this document are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the official position or policies of the U.S. Department of Justice. © Vera Institute of Justice 1996. All rights reserved. Bureau of Justice Assistance 633 Indiana Avenue NW., Washington, DC 20531 U.S. Department of Justice Response Center 1–800–421–6770 Bureau of Justice Assistance Clearinghouse 1–800–688–4252 Bureau of Justice Assistance Internet Address http://www.ojp.usdoj.gov/BJA The Bureau of Justice Assistance is a component of the Office of Justice Programs, which also includes the Bureau of Justice Statistics, the National Institute of Justice, the Office of Juvenile Justice and Delinquency Prevention, and the Office for Victims of Crime.
    [Show full text]
  • Rethinking Comparative Law: Variety and Uniformity in Ancient and Modern Tort Law
    University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Journal Articles Faculty Scholarship 1986 Rethinking Comparative Law: Variety and Uniformity in Ancient and Modern Tort Law Saul Levmore Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/journal_articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Saul Levmore, "Rethinking Comparative Law: Variety and Uniformity in Ancient and Modern Tort Law," 61 Tulane Law Review 235 (1986). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. TULANE LAW REVIEW VOLUME 61 DECEMBER 1986 NUMBER 2 RETHINKING COMPARATIVE LAW: VARIETY AND UNIFORMITY IN ANCIENT AND MODERN TORT LAW SAUL LEVMORE* Ancient codes and customary laws have a great deal of sub- ject matter in common with one another and with contemporary legal systems. It could hardly be otherwise. Any system of rules that seeks to regulate behavior or resolve disputes in a commu- nity that is too large to rely solely on informal sanctions, but that is large enough for its rules to have been' recorded in a way that allowed survival to the present day, must deal with murder, theft, accident prevention, insolvent debtors, and other circum- stances in which, for various reasons, purely private agreements and enforcement mechanisms are likely to be inferior to more formal rules and arrangements. Indeed, nearly every legal sys- tem of which we are aware, from ancient Babylon to our own, not only contains rules about murder and theft but also deals with inheritance, marital obligations, and those mundane mat- ters that are the stuff of private law.
    [Show full text]
  • Penal Code Chapter 12. Punishments
    PENAL CODE TITLE 3. PUNISHMENTS CHAPTER 12. PUNISHMENTS SUBCHAPTER A. GENERAL PROVISIONS Sec.A12.01.AAPUNISHMENT IN ACCORDANCE WITH CODE. (a) A person adjudged guilty of an offense under this code shall be punished in accordance with this chapter and the Code of Criminal Procedure. (b)AAPenal laws enacted after the effective date of this code shall be classified for punishment purposes in accordance with this chapter. (c)AAThis chapter does not deprive a court of authority conferred by law to forfeit property, dissolve a corporation, suspend or cancel a license or permit, remove a person from office, cite for contempt, or impose any other civil penalty. The civil penalty may be included in the sentence. Acts 1973, 63rd Leg., p. 883, ch. 399, Sec. 1, eff. Jan. 1, 1974. Amended by Acts 1993, 73rd Leg., ch. 900, Sec. 1.01, eff. Sept. 1, 1994. Sec.A12.02.AACLASSIFICATION OF OFFENSES. Offenses are designated as felonies or misdemeanors. Acts 1973, 63rd Leg., p. 883, ch. 399, Sec. 1, eff. Jan. 1, 1974. Amended by Acts 1993, 73rd Leg., ch. 900, Sec. 1.01, eff. Sept. 1, 1994. Sec.A12.03.AACLASSIFICATION OF MISDEMEANORS. (a) Misdemeanors are classified according to the relative seriousness of the offense into three categories: (1)AAClass A misdemeanors; (2)AAClass B misdemeanors; (3)AAClass C misdemeanors. (b)AAAn offense designated a misdemeanor in this code without specification as to punishment or category is a Class C misdemeanor. 1 (c)AAConviction of a Class C misdemeanor does not impose any legal disability or disadvantage. Acts 1973, 63rd Leg., p.
    [Show full text]