BIG DATA Handbook | Chapter 1 — IP Rights
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Fracking Patents: the Mee Rgence of Patents As Information-Containment Tools in Shale Drilling Daniel R
Michigan Telecommunications and Technology Law Review Volume 19 | Issue 2 2013 Fracking Patents: The meE rgence of Patents as Information-Containment Tools in Shale Drilling Daniel R. Cahoy Pennsylvania State University Joel Gehman University of Alberta Zhen Lei Pennsylvania State University Follow this and additional works at: http://repository.law.umich.edu/mttlr Part of the Environmental Law Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, and the Oil, Gas, and Mineral Law Commons Recommended Citation Daniel R. Cahoy, Joel Gehman & Zhen Lei, Fracking Patents: The Emergence of Patents as Information-Containment Tools in Shale Drilling, 19 Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. 279 (2013). Available at: http://repository.law.umich.edu/mttlr/vol19/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Michigan Telecommunications and Technology Law Review by an authorized editor of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FRACKING PATENTS: THE EMERGENCE OF PATENTS AS INFORMATION-CONTAINMENT TOOLS IN SHALE DRILLING Daniel R. Cahoy* Joel Gehman** Zhen Lei*** Cite as: Daniel R. Cahoy, Joel Gehman & Zhen Lei, Fracking Patents: The Emergence of Patents as Information-Containment Tools in Shale Drilling, 19 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REv 279 (2013), available at http://www.mttlr.org/volnineteen/cahoy.pdf The advantages of new sources of energy must be weighed against en- vironmental, health, and safety concerns related to new production technology. The rapid development of unconventional oil and gas fields, such as the Barnett and Marcellus Shales, provide an excellent context for these contrasting goals. -
PATENT PLEDGES Jorge L. Contreras*
PATENT PLEDGES Jorge L. Contreras* ABSTRACT An increasing number of firms are making public pledges to limit the enforcement of their patents. In doing so, they are entering a little- understood middle ground between the public domain and exclusive property rights. The best-known of these patent pledges are FRAND commitments, in which patent holders commit to license their patents to manufacturers of standardized products on terms that are “fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory.” But patent pledges have been appearing in settings well beyond standard-setting, including open source software, green technology and the life sciences. As a result, this increasingly prevalent private ordering mechanism is beginning to reshape the role and function of patents in the economy. Despite their proliferation, little scholarship has explored the phenomenon of patent pledges beyond FRAND commitments and standard- setting. This article fills this gap by providing the first comprehensive descriptive account of patent pledges across the board. It offers a four-part taxonomy of patent pledges based on the factors that motivate patent holders to make them and the effect they are intended to have on other market actors. Using this classification system, it argues that pledges likely to induce reliance in other market actors should be treated as “actionable” * Associate Professor, S.J. Quinney College of Law, University of Utah and Senior Policy Fellow, American University Washington College of Law. The author thanks Jonas Anderson, Clark Asay, Marc Sandy Block, Mark Bohannon, Matthew Bye, Michael Carrier, Michael Carroll, Colleen Chien, Thomas Cotter, Carter Eltzroth, Carissa Hessick, Meredith Jacob, Jay Kesan, Anne Layne-Farrar, Irina Manta, Sean Pager, Gideon Parchomovsky, Arti Rai, Amelia Rinehart, Cliff Rosky, Daniel Sokol and Duane Valz for their helpful comments, suggestions and discussion of this article and contributions of data to the Patent Pledge Database at American University. -
THE DEFENSIVE PATENT PLAYBOOK James M
THE DEFENSIVE PATENT PLAYBOOK James M. Rice† Billionaire entrepreneur Naveen Jain wrote that “[s]uccess doesn’t necessarily come from breakthrough innovation but from flawless execution. A great strategy alone won’t win a game or a battle; the win comes from basic blocking and tackling.”1 Companies with innovative ideas must execute patent strategies effectively to navigate the current patent landscape. But in order to develop a defensive strategy, practitioners must appreciate the development of the defensive patent playbook. Article 1, Section 8, Clause 8 of the U.S. Constitution grants Congress the power to “promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries.”2 Congress attempts to promote technological progress by granting patent rights to inventors. Under the utilitarian theory of patent law, patent rights create economic incentives for inventors by providing exclusivity in exchange for public disclosure of technology.3 The exclusive right to make, use, import, and sell a technology incentivizes innovation by enabling inventors to recoup the costs of development and secure profits in the market.4 Despite the conventional theory, in the 1980s and early 1990s, numerous technology companies viewed patents as unnecessary and chose not to file for patents.5 In 1990, Microsoft had seven utility patents.6 Cisco © 2015 James M. Rice. † J.D. Candidate, 2016, University of California, Berkeley, School of Law. 1. Naveen Jain, 10 Secrets of Becoming a Successful Entrepreneur, INC. (Aug. 13, 2012), http://www.inc.com/naveen-jain/10-secrets-of-becoming-a-successful- entrepreneur.html. -
PAEW-0059 Korea Semiconductor Industry Association
Comments of the Korea Semiconductor Industry Association On Patent Assertion Entity (PAE) Activities April 5, 2013 The Korea Semiconductor Industry Association (KSIA) welcomes the opportunity to submit these comments to the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, and the U.S. Federal Trade Commission, regarding the activities of Patent Assertion Entities (PAEs). The KSIA hopes that these comments are helpful to the agencies’ analysis of this important issue and respectfully requests that these comments be taken into account as policies are developed to address these serious concerns. The KSIA is an industry association, based in Seoul, Korea, which represents more than 300 companies in the semiconductor manufacturing sector, involved in all aspects of semiconductor device manufacturing as well as semiconductor equipment, materials, and design. Many of its member companies are world leaders in developing advanced semiconductor technologies. The KSIA's primary objectives include promotion of its members’ products and the further advancement of technological development in Korea's semiconductor industry. The KSIA is dedicated to providing opportunities for promoting cooperation among its members and members of international organizations in the areas of device, equipment and material suppliers. The world’s semiconductor industry, of which KSIA members are an important part, plays a vital role in the technological advancement and increased efficiency of nearly every facet of society. In addition to the well-known advances in computers, -
Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty
Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal Volume 27 Volume XXVII Number 1 Article 1 2016 Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty Eli Greenbaum Yigal Arnon & Co., [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/iplj Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons Recommended Citation Eli Greenbaum, Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty, 27 Fordham Intell. Prop. Media & Ent. L.J. 1 (2016). Available at: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/iplj/vol27/iss1/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty Cover Page Footnote Partner, Yigal Arnon & Co. J.D., Yale Law School; M.S., Columbia University. This article is available in Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal: https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/iplj/vol27/iss1/1 Puzzles of the Zero-Rate Royalty Eli Greenbaum* Patentees increasingly exploit their intellectual property rights through royalty-free licensing arrangements. Even though patentees us- ing such frameworks forfeit their right to trade patents for monetary gain, royalty-free arrangements can be used to pursue other significant commercial and collaborative interests. This Article argues that modern royalty-free structures generate tension between various otherwise well- accepted doctrines of patent remedies law that were designed for more traditional licensing models. -
Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro† 30 March 2013 ABSTRACT
LEMLEY & SHAPIRO A SIMPLE APPROACH TO SETTING REASONABLE ROYALTIES FOR STANDARD-ESSENTIAL PATENTS∗ Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro† 30 March 2013 ABSTRACT Standard Setting Organizations (SSOs) typically require their members to license any standard- essential patent on Fair, Reasonable, and Non-Discriminatory (FRAND) terms. Unfortunately, numerous high-stakes disputes have recently broken out over just what these “FRAND commitments” mean and how and where to enforce them. We propose a simple, practical set of rules regarding patents that SSOs can adopt to achieve the goals of FRAND commitments far more efficiently with far less litigation. Under our proposed approach, if an standard-essential patent owner and an implementer of the standard cannot agree on licensing terms, the standard-essential patent owner is obligated to enter into binding baseball-style (or “final offer”) arbitration with any willing licensee to determine the royalty rate. This obligation may be conditioned on the implementer making a reciprocal FRAND Commitment for any standard-essential patents it owns that read on the same standard. If the implementer is unwilling to enter into binding arbitration, the standard-essential patent owner’s FRAND commitment not to go to court to enforce its standard- essential patents against that party is discharged. We explain how our proposed FRAND regime would work in practice. Many of the disputes currently arising around FRAND commitments become moot under our approach. ∗ © 2013 Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro. We speak only for ourselves. We thank Robert Barr, Jorge Contreras, Thomas Cotter, Joseph Farrell, Richard Gilbert, Rose Hagan, Robert Harris, Brian Love, Gil Ohana, Fiona Scott- Morton, Jeffrey Wilder, and participants at a workshop at the Federal Trade Commission for helpful comments on an earlier draft. -
Inhibiting Patent Trolling: a New Approach for Applying Rule 11 Eric Rogers Molecular Templates, Inc
Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Volume 12 | Issue 4 Article 2 2014 Inhibiting Patent Trolling: A New Approach for Applying Rule 11 Eric Rogers Molecular Templates, Inc. Young Jeon e-Litecom Co., Ltd. Recommended Citation Eric Rogers and Young Jeon, Inhibiting Patent Trolling: A New Approach for Applying Rule 11, 12 Nw. J. Tech. & Intell. Prop. 291 (2014). https://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njtip/vol12/iss4/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern Pritzker School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property by an authorized editor of Northwestern Pritzker School of Law Scholarly Commons. NORTHWESTERN JOURNAL OF TECHNOLOGY AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY Inhibiting Patent Trolling: A New Approach for Applying Rule 11 Eric Rogers & Young Jeon November 2014 VOL. 12, NO. 4 © 2014 by Northwestern University School of Law Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Copyright 2014 by Northwestern University School of Law Volume 12, Number 4 (November 2014) Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Inhibiting Patent Trolling: A New Approach for Applying Rule 11 By Eric Rogers & Young Jeon* There has been an alarming rise in the number of litigious entities—commonly referred to as patent trolls or non-practicing entities—that make no products but file dubious patent infringement lawsuits merely to extract money from commercially productive companies. High litigation costs provide a fertile environment for an exploitive business model that uses shotgun tactics to threaten patent infringement claims against numerous companies, many of which will make a purely financial decision to pay patent trolls rather than expend even more money in litigation. -
Patent Portfolios As Securities
RISCH IN PRINTER (FN CORRECTION) (DO NOT DELETE) 9/18/2013 8:26 AM PATENT PORTFOLIOS AS SECURITIES MICHAEL RISCH† ABSTRACT Companies of all types are buying, selling, and licensing patents— not just individual patents, but many patents bundled into large portfolios. A primary problem with these transactions is that the market is illiquid: parties cannot identify holders of relevant portfolios, they cannot agree on the value of portfolios, and the specter of litigation taints every negotiation. This Article presents a new way to improve market formation and integrity by proposing that patent portfolios be treated as securities. If patent-portfolio transactions are treated like stock transactions, sellers steering clear of fraud laws may be forced to disclose information about patent value. Furthermore, patent transactions previously consummated in “dark markets” might now be traded in public clearinghouses. Ultimately, parties that openly transact will develop objective pricing methodologies that reduce the costs of negotiation and decrease the leverage that portfolio holders exert on potential licensees. TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction ............................................................................................... 90 I. Nonpracticing Entities, Product Companies, and Patent Aggregation ..................................................................................... 96 A. Nonpracticing Entities and Invention ................................... 97 B. Product-Company Patent Aggregation ................................ 99 -
Predictably Expensive:Ac Ritical Look at Patent
PREDICTABLY EXPENSIVE: A CRITICAL LOOK AT PATENT LITIGATION IN THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF TEXAS Brian J. Love* James Yoon† CITE AS 20 STAN. TECH. L. REV. 1 (2017) ABSTRACT In this Article, we compare U.S. patent litigation across districts and consider possible explanations for the Eastern District of Texas’ popularity with patent plaintiffs. Rather than any one explanation, we conclude that what makes the Eastern District so attractive to patent plaintiffs is the accumulated effect of several marginal advantages—particularly with respect to the relative timing of discovery deadlines, transfer decisions, and claim construction—that make it predictably expensive for accused infringers to defend patent suits filed in East Texas. These findings tend to support ongoing efforts to pass patent reform legislation that would presumptively stay discovery in patent suits pending claim construction and motions to transfer or dismiss. However, we also observe that courts in the Eastern District of Texas have exercised their discretion in ways that dampen the effect of prior legislative and judicial reforms that were aimed (at least in part) at deterring abusive patent suits. Given courts’ broad discretion to control how cases proceed, this additional finding suggests that restricting venue in patent cases may well be the single most effective reform available to Congress or the courts to limit patentees’ ability to impose unnecessary and unwarranted costs on companies accused of patent infringement. * Assistant Professor and Co-Director of the High Tech Law Institute, Santa Clara University School of Law. My work on this Article was supported in part by the INPRECOMP Project of the Center for Law, Science & Innovation (LSI) at the Arizona State University Sandra Day O’Connor College of Law. -
Artikelen PRIVATEERS and TROLLS JOIN the GLOBAL PATENT WARS; CAN COMPETITION AUTHORITIES DISARM THEM?
Mr. M. Dolmans1 Artikelen Privateers and trolls join the global patent wars; can competition authorities disarm them? Computerrecht 2014/37 a component that is subject to network effects, and you can threaten producers with catastrophic loss. On Halloween of 2013, patent assertion company – Patents proliferate in the ICT sector. This is partially Rockstar, owner of one of the largest patent portfo- due to patent mining and strategic patenting – firms lios in the world, 2 filed patent law suits against seven creating dense thickets of overlapping patent claims mobile phone makers and Google in the Texas ‘rocket covering and surrounding a product to block rivals. As docket’. 3 This heralded an escalation in the mobile patent offices are overwhelmed by applications in new, patent world war raging since 2010. fast-moving and complex technology areas, some think they grant patents without adequate review, leading to This ‘Halloween Attack’ is symptomatic of an in- lower patent quality. 4 Yet, in a portfolio, volume makes creasing problem: opportunistic exploitation of up for weakness. Patents are presumed valid, and chal- patents by Patent Assertion Entities (‘PAEs’, or less lenging patents is costly and time-consuming. More politely, ‘trolls’), and the strategic use of such PAEs important, if one patent is annulled or found not in- by firms to hamper their rivals. The war stories from fringed, patentees will have others. Litigation becomes the mobile phone sector are interesting as examples like a fight against the Hydra: chop off one head and of a competitive game, but even more as a harbin- two more grow. -
BIG DATA Handbook a Guide for Lawyers
W BIG DATA Handbook A Guide for Lawyers Robert Maier, Partner, Baker Botts Joshua Sibble, Senior Associate, Baker Botts BIG DATA Handbook—A Guide for Lawyers Executive Summary BIG DATA AND THE FUTURE OF COMMERCE Big Data is the future. Each year Big Data—large sets of data processed to reveal previously unseen trends, behaviors, and other patterns—takes on an increasingly important role in the global economy. In 2010, the Big Data market was valued at $100 billion worldwide, and it is expected to grow to over $200 billion by 2020. The power of Big Data and artificial intelligence to crunch vast amounts of information to gain insights into the world around us, coupled with the emerging ubiquity of the Internet of Things (IoT) to sense and gather that data about nearly everything on earth and beyond, has triggered a revolution the likes of which have not been seen since the advent of the personal computer. These technologies have the potential to shatter the norms in nearly every aspect of society—from the research into what makes a workforce happier and more productive, to healthcare, to the ways we think about climate change, and to the ways we bank and do business. Not surprisingly, it seems everyone is getting into the Big Data game, from the expected—multinational computer hardware, software, and digital storage manufacturers—to the unexpected—real estate agents, small businesses, and even wildlife conservationists. Within a few years, every sector of the global economy will be touched in some way by Big Data, its benefits, and its pitfalls. -
636KB***Evolving Landscape of Patent Remedies in a Changing
634 Singapore Academy of Law Journal (2012) 24 SAcLJ EVOLVING LANDSCAPE OF PATENT REMEDIES IN A CHANGING MARKETPLACE The principal goal of intellectual property (particularly patent) laws is to foster innovation for the public good. Yet, the proliferation of patents could stifle technological advancement if the incidence and risks of undesirable innovation “hold-ups” are not addressed. This article draws on the recent developments in the information and communication technology sector, such as the ongoing global patent war involving smartphones and tablets, to support the contention that the patent system cannot continue to play the vital role in promoting innovation without recalibrating the balance between the competing, and sometimes conflicting, interests of divergent stakeholders in the patent system. More controversially, it is argued that courts should seriously consider going further to award ongoing royalties or prospective damages as a remedy under national laws. Elizabeth Siew-Kuan NG* LLB (Hons) (London), LLM (First Class) (Cambridge); Barrister-at-Law (Middle Temple, London), Advocate and Solicitor (Singapore); Associate Professor, Faculty of Law, National University of Singapore. I. Introduction 1 The battle scene has changed: traditional patent battles have generally involved a few patents and litigants; going forward, some predict that the ongoing global patent war in smartphones and tablets is “likely a foretaste of more patent wars in the future”.1 The stakes have become phenomenal as the loser faces potential ruin from legal costs and outsize awards of damages,2 or even worse, the disaster of a * The author would like to thank Chao Hick Tin JA for the invitation to contribute to this special issue; Sam Ricketson, guest editor of this special issue, for his very helpful comments and suggestions on earlier drafts; Stephen Phua for his invaluable editorial assistance; and Fatin Nadiah Masud, final-year LLB student, National University of Singapore, for research assistance.