The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth By DARON ACEMOGLU,SIMON JOHNSON, AND JAMES ROBINSON* The rise of Western Europe after 1500 is due largely to growth in countries with access to the Atlantic Ocean and with substantial trade with the New World, Africa, and Asia via the Atlantic. This trade and the associated colonialism affected Europe not only directly, but also indirectly by inducing institutional change. Where “initial” political institutions (those established before 1500) placed significant checks on the monarchy, the growth of Atlantic trade strengthened merchant groups by constraining the power of the monarchy, and helped merchants obtain changes in institutions to protect property rights. These changes were central to subsequent economic growth. (JEL F10, N13, O10, P10) The world we live in was shaped by the rapid There is little agreement, however, on why this economic growth that took place in nineteenth- growth took place in Western Europe and why century Western Europe. The origins of this it started in the sixteenth century. growth and the associated Industrial Revolution This paper establishes the patterns of eco- are generally considered to lie in the economic, nomic growth in Western Europe during this political, and social development of Western era, develops a hypothesis on the origins of the Europe over the preceding centuries. In fact, rise of (Western) Europe and provides historical between 1500 and 1800, Western Europe expe- and econometric evidence supporting some of rienced a historically unprecedented period of the implications of this hypothesis. sustained growth, perhaps the “First Great Di- We document that the differential growth of vergence” (i.e., the first major sustained diver- Western Europe during the sixteenth, seven- gence in income per capita across different teenth, eighteenth, and early nineteenth centu- regions of the world), making this area substan- ries is almost entirely accounted for by the tially richer than Asia and Eastern Europe. growth of nations with access to the Atlantic Ocean, and of Atlantic traders. Throughout the paper, the term Atlantic trader refers to Britain, * Acemoglu: Department of Economics, Massachusetts In- France, the Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain, stitute of Technology, E52-371, Cambridge, MA 02142 the nations most directly involved in trade and (e-mail: [email protected]); Johnson: Sloan School of Manage- colonialism in the New World and Asia. Atlan- ment, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial tic trade, in turn, means trade with the New Drive, Cambridge, MA 02139 (e-mail: [email protected]); World, as well as trade with Asia via the Atlan- Robinson: Department of Government, Harvard University, 1875 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138 (e-mail: tic, and includes colonialism- and slavery- 1 [email protected]). We thank Thomas Becker and related activities. The differential growth of Rui Pedro Esteves for outstanding research assistance and Josh Atlantic traders suggests a close link between Angrist, Abhijit Banerjee, Dora Costa, Jan de Vries, Stanley Atlantic trade and the First Great Divergence. In Engerman, Philip Hoffman, Peter Lindert, Sebastia´n Mazzuca, Joel Mokyr, Larry Neal, Steve Pincus, Christina Romer, David fact, it appears that the rise of Europe between Romer, Andrei Shleifer, Alan Taylor, Hans-Joachim Voth, two 1500 and 1850 is largely the rise of Atlantic anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the University of California, Berkeley, the Canadian Institute of Advanced Research, University of Chicago Graduate School of Business 1 Atlantic trade opportunities became available only dur- and Department of Political Science, George Mason Univer- ing the late fifteenth century, thanks to the discovery of the sity, Harvard Business School, the Harvard Economic History New World and the passage to Asia around the Cape of Seminar, the London School of Economics, MIT, the National Good Hope. These discoveries resulted from a series of Bureau of Economic Research economic history, inequality, innovations in ship technology, primarily pioneered by the and economic growth groups, New York University, and Portuguese, that changed the rigging and hull design of Princeton University for comments and suggestions. ships and developed knowledge of oceanic navigation. 546 VOL. 95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLU ET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 547 FIGURE 1A. WESTERN EUROPE,EASTERN EUROPE, AND ASIA:URBANIZATION RATES,WEIGHTED BY POPULATION, 1300–1850 FIGURE 1B. ATLANTIC TRADERS,WEST EUROPEAN COUNTRIES NOT ATLANTIC TRADERS, AND EASTERN EUROPE: URBANIZATION RATES,WEIGHTED BY POPULATION, 1300–1850 Europe, and is quite different in nature from the easy access to the Atlantic, even such nonabso- European growth that took place before 1500. lutist states as Venice and Genoa, did not expe- Not all societies with access to the Atlantic rience any direct or indirect benefits from show the same pattern of growth, however. The Atlantic trade. data suggest an important interaction between Figures 1 and 2 illustrate the central thesis medieval political institutions and access to the of this paper. Figure 1, panel A, shows that Atlantic: the more rapid economic growth took urbanization in Western Europe grew sig- place in societies with relatively nonabsolutist nificantly faster than in Eastern Europe after initial institutions, most notably in Britain and 1500.2 Figure 1, panel B, shows that these the Netherlands. In contrast, countries where the monarchy was highly absolutist, such as Spain and Portugal, experienced only limited growth 2 For the purposes of this paper, Western Europe is taken in the subsequent centuries, while areas lacking to be all the countries west of the Elbe, i.e., Austria, 548 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 2005 FIGURE 2A. WESTERN EUROPE,EASTERN EUROPE, AND ASIA: GDP PER CAPITA,WEIGHTED BY POPULATION, 1500–1870 FIGURE 2B. ATLANTIC TRADERS,WEST EUROPEAN COUNTRIES NOT ATLANTIC TRADERS, AND EASTERN EUROPE: GDP PER CAPITA,WEIGHTED BY POPULATION, 1500–1870 differential trends are due in large part to 1850. In contrast, Atlantic traders started with a the growth of Atlantic traders. The rest of West- lower average urbanization rate of 8 percent in ern Europe had a relatively high average urban- 1300 (and only 10.1 percent in 1500), which ization rate of 10 percent in 1300 (and 11.4 almost tripled in the subsequent 550 years to percent in 1500), but grew at approximately the reach 24.5 percent in 1850, overtaking average same rate as Eastern Europe from 1500 to 1850, urbanization in the non-Atlantic parts of West- by a factor of less than 2, to reach 17 percent by ern Europe between 1600 and 1700 (see Table 1). Panels A and B in Figure 2 show the same pattern, using Angus Maddison’s (2001) esti- Belgium, Britain, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ire- mates of GDP per capita. While GDP per capita land, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Swe- rose by a factor of almost two among Atlantic den, and Switzerland. Eastern Europe is all European traders between 1500 and 1820, in the rest of countries to the east of the Elbe, including Russia and Western Europe it grew at approximately the excluding Turkey. See Section I A for details on urbaniza- same rate as in Eastern Europe, just under 30 tion and GDP data. All averages are weighted by popula- tion, using numbers from Colin McEvedy and Richard percent. Jones (1978). The patterns depicted in Figures 1 and 2 do VOL. 95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLU ET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 549 TABLE 1—DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS Non- Whole Whole Atlantic Atlantic sample, sample, Western Western Eastern unweighted weighted Europe Europe Europe Asia Weighted by population Urbanization in 1300 6.6 9.9 8.0 10.0 4.1 11.0 (5.2) (3.2) (2.8) (6.1) (3.3) (0.7) Urbanization in 1400 7.6 10.3 8.5 12.1 3.9 11.1 (9.5) (3.6) (2.4) (10.0) (1.5) (0.5) Urbanization in 1500 8.3 10.6 10.1 11.4 4.0 11.5 (7.6) (3.4) (5.3) (6.8) (1.8) (0.7) Urbanization in 1600 9.6 11.7 13.6 14.0 4.4 12.0 (7.6) (4.0) (7.6) (8.8) (2.7) (0.7) Urbanization in 1700 10.7 11.2 14.5 13.1 3.7 11.6 (8.5) (4.1) (6.8) (8.1) (2.2) (0.7) Urbanization in 1800 14.1 10.3 19.8 16.9 7.0 8.9 (9.1) (4.9) (7.9) (7.5) (3.3) (1.4) GDP per capita in 1500 627.54 608.3 721.46 850.73 506.94 575.0 (159.3) (118.0) (31.1) (217.1) (78.2) (35.4) GDP per capita in 1600 740.73 630.5 916.31 908.22 578.29 576.8 (225.6) (144.2) (149.3) (167.3) (112.3) (35.3) GDP per capita in 1700 862.12 622.2 1079.21 980.82 636.0 574.2 (348.4) (208.1) (321.4) (128.2) (136.1) (35.3) GDP per capita in 1820 988.00 691.7 1321.95 1095.40 719.5 575.5 (373.6) (264.5) (348.7) (125.3) (174.9) (45.7) Constraint on executive in 1500 1.67 1.73 1.75 1.99 1.46 (0.76) (0.79) (0.56) (0.99) (0.79) Constraint on executive in 1600 1.67 1.53 1.62 1.54 1.45 (1.01) (0.84) (1.24) (0.59) (0.79) Constraint on executive in 1700 1.83 1.52 1.83 1.41 1.30 (1.31) (1.17) (1.76) (0.94) (0.76) Constraint on executive in 1800 2.25 2.18 4.00 1.90 1.00 (1.82) (1.83) (1.79) (1.78) (0.00) Atlantic coastline-to-area 0.0057 0.0014 0.0118 0.0026 0.00 0.00 (0.0117) (0.0065) (0.0181) (0.0052) Notes: First column is unweighted means; other columns are mean values weighted by total population in year indicated, from McEvedy and Jones (1978).
Recommended publications
  • How European Integration Affects US Exports to the European Union
    Journal of Case Research in Business and Economics The US-EU Relationship: How European Integration Affects US Exports to the European Union Dr. Mustafa Sawani Truman State University Prof. Assma Sawani Westminster College Casey Copeland Truman State University Abstract The past few decades in Europe have been characterized by the integration of European economies. These developments are likely to affect not only the European economy, but the economies of several other countries that have ties with Europe. As the European Union’s largest trading partner, the United States should be aware of how the changes going on in Europe are likely to affect the US economy. The purpose of this paper is to determine the effect of the European integration on US exports to the EU. Data on the GDP of the EU-15 and the exchange rate of the euro and the dollar came from the International Financial Statistics Yearbook and data on the amount of US exports to the EU-15 came from the International Monetary Fund. 25 observations (1980-2004) were used in this study and a linear regression model was used to show the impact of European integration on US exports to the EU. The results show that although the years characterized by integration under the Single Europe Act and the Maastricht Treaty saw an increase in the amount of US exports to the EU (controlling for the exchange rate, EU GDP, and exports lagged one year), exports to the EU decreased in the years characterized by integration after the introduction of the euro. Keywords: European Economic Community, European Integration, Mutual Recognition Agreement, the Single Europe Act, Maastricht Treaty, and the EURO The US-EU Relationship, Page 1 Journal of Case Research in Business and Economics Introduction In the aftermath of World War II, as European leaders noted the destruction, both in economic and human terms, they began looking at ways to keep peace between their nations in the future.
    [Show full text]
  • "East Asia, Europe, and the Industrial Revolution" Kenneth Pomeranz
    "East Asia, Europe, and the Industrial Revolution" Kenneth Pomeranz Dept. of History University of California, Irvine Irvine, CA 92697-3275 [email protected] Work in progress: comments welcomed, but please do not cite without permission This paper has emerged from one very familiar and one less familiar project. The familiar one, which provides the focus for the early part of the paper, involves thinking about how the literature on European economic history could be usefully brought to bear on the much less advanced field of Chinese economic history. This involves generating estimates for China of some things that are more or less known for Europe, such as levels of consumption, real earnings in different kinds of work, and so on. The results greatly undermine any notion -- which still lingers in various ways -- that late Imperial China had a subsistence economy, or that despite massive commercialization, there was no growth in pgi_aaaita output. Well also see that it significantly modifies another of the old war-horses of the China literature: "over-population," suggesting that that term can only be applied in a very restrictive, anachronistic sense -- and that, since in that sense, it could be applied to 18th century Western Europe, too, it will hardly do as an explanation for the longer-term course of Chinese economic development. In fact, my data on living standards, resource shortages, and so on suggest a rough comparability between the more advanced portions of 18th century China and the more advanced portions of 18th century Europe. And that brings up a second, more unusual, project: to think about how, if we describe China and Europe in comparable terms, the Chinese experience may cast light on Europe.
    [Show full text]
  • Of a Princely Court in the Burgundian Netherlands, 1467-1503 Jun
    Court in the Market: The ‘Business’ of a Princely Court in the Burgundian Netherlands, 1467-1503 Jun Hee Cho Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY 2013 © 2013 Jun Hee Cho All rights reserved ABSTRACT Court in the Market: The ‘Business’ of a Princely Court in the Burgundian Netherlands, 1467-1503 Jun Hee Cho This dissertation examines the relations between court and commerce in Europe at the onset of the modern era. Focusing on one of the most powerful princely courts of the period, the court of Charles the Bold, duke of Burgundy, which ruled over one of the most advanced economic regions in Europe, the greater Low Countries, it argues that the Burgundian court was, both in its institutional operations and its cultural aspirations, a commercial enterprise. Based primarily on fiscal accounts, corroborated with court correspondence, municipal records, official chronicles, and contemporary literary sources, this dissertation argues that the court was fully engaged in the commercial economy and furthermore that the culture of the court, in enacting the ideals of a largely imaginary feudal past, was also presenting the ideals of a commercial future. It uncovers courtiers who, despite their low rank yet because of their market expertise, were close to the duke and in charge of acquiring and maintaining the material goods that made possible the pageants and ceremonies so central to the self- representation of the Burgundian court. It exposes the wider network of court officials, urban merchants and artisans who, tied by marriage and business relationships, together produced and managed the ducal liveries, jewelries, tapestries and finances that realized the splendor of the court.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Populist Rule in Post-Crisis Europe: Hungary and Poland
    This is an Accepted Manuscript of a published by Taylor & Francis in New Political Economy on 29 March 2019, available online: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/13563467.2019.1598960 Accepted version downloaded from SOAS Research Online: http://eprints.soas.ac.uk/31127/ The Political Economy of Populist Rule in post-crisis Europe: Hungary and Poland Abstract This paper analyses the economic dimension of populist governance in post-crisis Europe by exploring whether and in what ways populist economic policies diverge from neoliberal orthodoxy. Existing literature on contemporary populism in Central and Eastern Europe is ambivalent on this question and lacks systematic analyses of populist economic policies while in government. The comparative analysis of the Fidesz-led government in Hungary and the Law and Justice government in Poland is used to analyse the policy shifts in different domains. The main claim is that a combination of both domestic ideological change at the level of government and transnationally conditioned structural factors need to be considered to explain the shift towards and the variation in the pursuit of a ‘heterodox’ economic strategy under the two populist governments. The paper concludes by offering a reflection on why the analysed policy changes do not correspond with a more decisive shift towards an alternative trajectory of capitalist development in post-crisis Europe. Alen Toplišek, Department of Politics and International Studies, SOAS University of London, Bloomsbury, London WC1H 0XG, [email protected] Alen Toplišek is a Teaching Fellow in the Department of Politics & International Studies at SOAS University of London. 1 Introduction The aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis has seen the sweep to power in Europe of four new populist governments.
    [Show full text]
  • A Qualitative and Quantitative Assessment
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Buchen, Clemens Doctoral Thesis Emerging economic systems in Central and Eastern Europe – a qualitative and quantitative assessment Suggested Citation: Buchen, Clemens (2010) : Emerging economic systems in Central and Eastern Europe – a qualitative and quantitative assessment, ZBW - Deutsche Zentralbibliothek für Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft, Kiel, Hamburg, http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:101:1-201008171268 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/37141 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Emerging economic systems in Central and Eastern Europe – a qualitative and quantitative assessment Dissertation zur Erlangung des akademischen Grades doctor rerum politicarum eingereicht bei der EBS Universität für Wirtschaft und Recht Wiesbaden von Dipl.-Vwt.
    [Show full text]
  • Attracting Investment to South East Europe
    46177 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Copyright © 2007 The World Bank Group 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433 All rights reserved November 2007 Available online at www.fias.net The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank Group does not make any representations or warranties regarding the completeness or accuracy of the information included this report, or the results which would be achieved by following its recommendations. Rights and permissions The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank Group encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint, please send a request with complete information to: Copyright Clearance Center, Inc. 222 Rosewood Drive Danvers, MA 01923, USA t. 978-750-8400; f. 978-750-4470 www.copyright.com All queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to: The Office of the Publisher The World Bank 1818 H Street NW Washington, DC 20433, USA f. 202-522-2422 E-mail: [email protected] About FIAS FIAS, the multi-donor investment climate advisory service managed by the International Finance Corporation (IFC) and supported by the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) and the World Bank, is an integrator of services to improve the business-enabling environment of member countries.
    [Show full text]
  • The Dutch Golden Age and Globalization: History and Heritage, Legacies and Contestations Joop De Jong Maastricht University
    Macalester International Volume 27 Global Citizenship: Human Rights, Urban Diversity, and Environmental Challenges (FDIS 2011: Article 7 The Hague) December 2011 The Dutch Golden Age and Globalization: History and Heritage, Legacies and Contestations Joop de Jong Maastricht University Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.macalester.edu/macintl Recommended Citation de Jong, Joop (2011) "The Dutch Golden Age and Globalization: History and Heritage, Legacies and Contestations," Macalester International: Vol. 27, Article 7. Available at: http://digitalcommons.macalester.edu/macintl/vol27/iss1/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Institute for Global Citizenship at DigitalCommons@Macalester College. It has been accepted for inclusion in Macalester International by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@Macalester College. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Dutch Golden Age and Globalization: History and Heritage, Legacies and Contestations Joop de Jong I. Context In 1579, seven of the seventeen Provinces of the Netherlands unenthusiastically declared their independence from the Habsburg King of Spain, to form the United Provinces, also known as the Union or the Dutch Republic. The new country achieved full international recognition in 1648, even though many states recognized its sovereignty much earlier. The Dutch Republic was small in both size and population. It covered more or less the same territory as the present Dutch state, and had approximately 1.5 million inhabitants in 1600, and about 1.9 million by 1700.1 In 1600, France had 18 million inhabitants, Spain (including Portugal) 11 million, and Great Britain 7 million.2 The province of Holland contributed some 45 percent of the country’s total population.
    [Show full text]
  • After Enlargement: Europe’S New Migration System Adrian Favell
    After enlargement: Europe’s new migration system Adrian Favell To cite this version: Adrian Favell. After enlargement: Europe’s new migration system. 2006. hal-01070589 HAL Id: hal-01070589 https://hal-sciencespo.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01070589 Submitted on 1 Oct 2014 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. DANISH INSTITUTE FOR INTERNATIONAL STUDIES STRANDGADE 56 •1401 Copenhagen K +45 32 69 87 87 • [email protected] • www.diis.dk DIIS Brief After Enlargement: Europe’s New Migration System Adrian Favell December 2006 Policy makers underestimate the importance of underlying demographics and labour market dynamics on future East-West migration in Europe. Flows have generally been demand driven, and have therefore been drawn by European nations with the most open and informal labour markets – such as Britain, Ireland, Italy and Spain – rather than more highly regulated welfare states such as Denmark. They are also more likely to be circular and temporary than one way immigration. I discuss the desirability of the apparently inevitable trend in Europe towards a more US style international labour market that strongly parallels the migration system between the US and Mexico.
    [Show full text]
  • European Integration and the Effects of Country Size on Growth
    European Integration and the Effects of Country Size on Growth jei Journal of Economic Integration jei Vol.30 No.3, September 2015, 501~531 http://dx.doi.org/10.11130/jei.2015.30.3.501 European Integration and the Effects of Country Size on Growth Jörg König Georg-August-University of Goettingen & Stiftung Marktwirtschaft, Berlin, Germany Abstract Does the size of a country affect its economic growth rate? Theory suggests that the existence of a national scale effect is favouring large countries and that small countries may overcome the impediments of smallness once their markets become internationally more integrated. So far, empirical evidence of a distinct impact of country size on economic growth is rather limited. The present study sheds light on this impact from a European perspective. Country size indeed correlates with economic growth and European economic integration enhances the convergence process of the countries. It is further shown that the impact of size varies according to a country’s individual level of economic integration, suggesting that the long-term economic growth path is characterized by multiple transition points. This finding is particularly important given the prevailing imperfections of the European Union Single Market and the increasing number of small European Union member states. JEL Classifications: C23, F15, F43, O52 Keywords: Country Size, European Economic Integration, Economic Growth, Economic Convergence, Panel Data, Fixed Effects * Corresponding Author: Jörg König; Georg-August-University of Goettingen, Platz der Goettinger Sieben 3, 37073 Goettingen, Germany; Tel: +49 551397412, Fax: +49 551397093, E-mail: [email protected]. Acknowledgements: The author is very grateful to the Editor of JEI and the anonymous referees for very useful suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Modern Economic Growth' the GDP of Holland Between 1347 and 1807
    The character of growth before ‘modern economic growth’ The GDP of Holland between 1347 and 1807 Jan Luiten van Zanden, Utrecht University Bas van Leeuwen, Warwick University, Utrecht University March 2011 Abstract On the basis of a newly constructed dataset of the national accounts of the province of Holland in the period between 1347 and 1800, we analyze the pattern of growth in this region, which was one of the most prosperous and dynamic parts of the pre modern European economy. We demonstrate that this economy was characterized by almost continuous but highly unstable economic growth caused mainly by exogenous shocks related to international trade and shipping, and harvest fluctuations. The causes of this growth vary over time. Yet, the start of the Golden Age was characterized by the increase of total factor productivity. TFP-growth was an important factor behind growth in the period until the 1620s, was negative during the middle decades of the 17th century, and became positive again after the 1660s. This suggests a surge of technological change during the 1540-1620 period, followed by much more incremental changes in the next two centuries. Keywords: GDP, national accounts, Holland, economic growth, historical development JEL Codes: E01, E24, N13, N53, N63, N73 Corresponding author: Jan Luiten van Zanden, [email protected] Acknowledgements: This paper forms part of the project “Reconstructing the National Income of Britain and Holland, c.1270/1500 to 1850”, funded by the Leverhulme Trust, Reference Number F/00215AR, and of the Spinoza-premium-project, funded by NWO. We thank Christiaan van Bochove, Oscar Gelderblom, Peter Koudijs, Matthias van Rossum, Christiaan van der Spek, Milja van Tielhof and dr.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth∗
    The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth∗ Daron Acemoglu Department of Economics, MIT Simon Johnson Sloan School of Management, MIT James Robinson Departments of Political Science and Economics, Berkeley September 10, 2003 ∗We thank Thomas Becker and Rui Pedro Esteves for outstanding research assistance and Josh Angrist, Abhijit Banerjee, Timothy Besley, Dora Costa, Jan de Vries, Stanley Engerman, Philip Hoff- man, Peter Lindert, Sebasti´an Mazzuca, Joel Mokyr, Larry Neal, Steve Pincus, Christina Romer, David Romer, Andrei Shleifer, Alan Taylor, Hans-Joachim Voth, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at Berkeley, the Canadian Institute of Advanced Research, Chicago Business School and Political Science, George Mason University, Harvard Business School, the Harvard Economic History Seminar, the London School of Economics, MIT, the National Bureau of Economic Research economic history, inequality and economic growth groups, New York University and Princeton for comments and suggestions. 1 The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth Abstract This paper documents that the Rise of Western Europe between 1500 and 1850 is largely accounted for by the growth of European nations with access to the Atlantic and, in particular, by those that engaged in colonialism and transoceanic trade. Significant variation in economic performance among Atlantic trading nations is explained by the fact that countries with relatively non-absolutist initial institutions experienced faster growth. We suggest that Atlantic trade and colonialism affected Europe not only directly, but also indirectly by inducing institutional changes. In particular, where initial political institutions placed significant checks on the monarchy, the growth of New World and Asian trade after 1500 strengthened merchant groups in favor of constraining the power of the monarchy further, and enabled them to demand and obtain changes in institutions to protect their property rights.
    [Show full text]
  • How the Marshall Plan Came About
    By Meredith Hindley How the Marshall Pan Came About ON COMME CEMENT DAY at Harvard University in June 1947, Secretary of State George C. Marshall told an audi­ ence of alumni gathered in the yard about a plan to provide Europe with economic aid. The . speech, delivered in the calm, deliberate manner that reflected Marshall's measured approach to life, was not rhetorically dramatic. But what the speech promised-that if the European countries could devise a program to facilitate the economic recov- ery of Europe, the United States would provide the resources­ went on to change the face of postwar Europe. The following excerpts from the George C. Marshall Papers show how the invitation to give an informal talk at Har­ vard became the forum for the ., WERK announcement of the European Recovery Program-better STERK known as the Marshall Plan. T01J-Ccorgc C Marshall Fa/illdatio/l 22 NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1998 nthe spring of 1947, aEuropean aid program was I already in the works, but Under Secretary Will Clayton's memo, with its vivid descriptions of Europe's destruction and economic needs, speeded up the announcement of :::z: the Marshall Plan. May 27,1947 c::::I MEMORANDUM :::z: BY THE UNDER SECRETARY c:::e • 10­ FOR ECONOMIC AFFAIRS CD --' THE EUROPEAI CRISIS ~ It is now obvious that we grossly underestimated the desh"uc­ TR~GT'N~ tion to the European economy by the war. We understood the physical destruction, but we failed to take fully into account the effects of economic dislocation on production­ A 1950 COMPETITJO TO DESIGN A POSTER nationalization of industries, drastic land reform, severance of long-standing commercial ties, disappearance of private CELEBRATING J TRA-EuROPEAN COOPERA- commercial firms through death or loss of capital, etc., etc.
    [Show full text]