Mr. Keynes on the Causes of Unemployment<Article-Title>The

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Mr. Keynes on the Causes of Unemployment<Article-Title>The Review: Mr. Keynes on the Causes of Unemployment Author(s): Jacob Viner Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 51, No. 1 (Nov., 1936), pp. 147-167 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1882505 . Accessed: 12/06/2011 11:43 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly Journal of Economics. http://www.jstor.org MR. KEYNES ON THE CAUSES OF UNEMPLOYMENT' The indebtednessof economiststo Mr. Keynes has been greatlyincreased by this latest addition to his series of bril- liant, original,and provocativebooks, whose contributionto our enlightenmentwill prove, I am sure, to have been even greaterin the long than in the short run. This book deals with almost everything,but the causes of and the future prospects of unemployment,cyclical and secular, are its centraltheme. It bringsmuch new light,but its display of dialecticalskill is so overwhelmingthat it will have probably morepersuasive power than it deserves,and a concentration on the pointswhere I thinkI can detect defectsin the argu- ment,tho it would be unfairif presentedas an appraisal of the meritsof the book as a whole,may be more usefulthan would a catalogue -which would have to be long to be complete- of its points of outstandingintellectual achieve- ment. Writtentho it is by a stylistof the firstorder, the book is not easy to read, to master, or to appraise. An extremely wide range of problems,none of them simple ones, are dealt with in an unnecessarilysmall number of pages. Had the book been made longer,the time requiredfor reading it with a fair degree of understandingwould have been shorter,for the argumentoften proceeds at breakneckspeed and repeated rereadingsare necessarybefore it can be grasped. The book, moreover,breaks with traditionalmodes of approach to its problemsat a numberof points- at the greatestpossible numberof points,one suspects- and no old termfor an old concept is used when a new one can be coined, and if old termsare used new meaningsare generallyassigned to them. The definitionsprovided, moreover, are sometimesof unbe- lievable complexity. The old-fashionedeconomist must, therefore,struggle not onlywith new ideas and new methods 1. John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment Interestand Money,Macmillan and Co., London,1936. 147 148 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS of manipulatingthem, but also with a new language. There is ample reward,however, for the expenditureof time and attentionnecessary for even partialmastery of the argument. 1. " INVOLUNTARY" UNEMPLOYMENT Mr. Keynes claims that the "classical"2 economistsrecog- nized the possibilityonly of "frictional"and of "voluntary" unemployment,and that a vitally important chapter of economictheory remains to be writtenabout a thirdclass of unemployment,for which there was no place in the "classical" scheme of things, namely, "involuntary" unemployment. The concept of "frictional" unemploymentrelates to the inevitable loss of time between jobs, and presentsno diffi- culties. "Voluntary" unemploymentis definedas the unem- ployment"due to the refusalor inabilityof a unit of labor ... to accept a reward correspondingto the value of the product attributableto its marginal productivity,"but is used in such manneras to requirethe additionto this defini- tion of the provisothat the moneywage offeredmust not be below what the laborerregards as a properminimum rate of moneywages. If laborersrefuse available employmentat a money rate below this minimum,or if employed laborers refuseto permita prevailingmoney rate to be loweredand unemploymentresults for themselves or forothers from this refusal,Keynes would apparentlyregard it as "involuntary" unemployment,but deny its possibilityor probability. He defines"involuntary" unemployment as follows:"Men are involuntarilyunemployed if, in the event of a small rise in the price of wage-goodsrelatively to the moneywage, both the aggregatesupply of labor willingto workfor the current money-wageand the aggregatedemand for it at that wage would be greaterthan the existingvolume of employment." (p. 15). What he seems to mean by this is that any unem- ploymentwhich would disappear if real wages were to be reducedby a rise in the prices of wage-goods,money wages remainingthe same or risingin less proportion,but not falling, 2. Used by him to mean the later economists, such as J. S. Mill, Marshall, Edgeworth, Pigou, who in the main were adherents of the Ricardian tradition; a usage which I shall followhere. CAUSES OF UNEMPLOYMENT 149 would be involuntary. It is with "involuntary"unemploy- mentso understood,its causes and its remedies,that Keynes' analysisof unemploymentis primarily-and almost solely- concerned. In Keynes' classificationof unemploymentby its causes, unemploymentdue to downward-rigidityof money-wages, which for the "classical" economistswas the chief type of cyclical unemploymentand the only important type of secular or persistentunemployment, therefore finds no place. As will be seen later,it is excluded on the groundthat resist- ance to reductionsin money wage-ratesgenerally does not involve a reductionin the volume of employmentand is, if anything,favorable to employmentrather than the reverse. The omissioncharged against the "classical" economists is theirfailure to note the lesserresistance of labor to reductions in real wages if unassociatedwith reductions in moneywages per se, and theirfailure to recognizethe existenceof a large volumeof unemployment for which the formeris an available and practicableremedy, but not the latter. Keynes' reason- ing points obviously to the superiorityof inflationary remediesfor unemployment over money-wagereductions. In a world organizedin accordance with Keynes' specifications therewould be a constantrace betweenthe printingpress and the businessagents of the trade unions,with the problemof unemploymentlargely solved ifthe printingpress could main- tain a constant lead and if only volume of employment, irrespectiveof quality, is consideredimportant. The only clash here between Keynes' position and the orthodoxone is in his denial that reductionof money wage rates is a remedyfor unemployment.Keynes even follows the classical doctrine too closely when he concedes that "with a given organization,equipment and technique,real wages and the volume of output (and hence of employment) are uniquely correlated,so that, in general, an increase in employmentcan onlyoccur to the accompanimentof a decline in the rate of real wages" (p. 17). This conclusion results fromtoo unqualifiedan application of law-of-diminishing- returnsanalysis, and needs to be modifiedfor cyclical unem- 150 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS ployment,as well as for the possibilitythat the prices of wage-goodsand of other goods may have divergentmove- ments. If a plant geared to workat say 80 per cent of rated capacity is being operated at say only 30 per cent, both the per capita and the marginaloutput of labor may well be lower at the low rate of operationsthan at the higherrate, the law of diminishingreturns notwithstanding. There is the further emDirical considerationthat if employersoperate in their wage policy in accordance with marginalcost analysis, it is done only imperfectlyand unconsciously,and the level of wages they can be persuaded to establish is stronglyinflu- enced by the profitabilityof theiroperations as a whole,and not solely if at all - by calculationsof the marginalcon- tributionsof labor to output. Keynes uses the term "full employment"to signifythe absence of any involuntary unemployment(p. 16). He describesit also as the conditionwhich would prevail "when output has risento a level at whichthe marginalreturn from a representativeunit of the factorsof productionhas fallen to the minimumfigure at which a quantity of the factors sufficientto producethis output is available" (p. 303). There are impliedhere several questionablepropositions. The con- cept of diminishingmarginal productivity is generallyused in economics in a partial differentialsense to indicate the diminishingincrements of output which would result when some particularfactor or groupof factors was beingincreased, the remainderof the workingcombination being held con- stant. If all the factorsare being increased simultaneously and in uniformproportions, it requiressome such assumption as that of the general prevalence of external technical dis- economiesfrom increased
Recommended publications
  • HLA MYINT 105 Neoclassical Development Analysis: Its Strengths and Limitations 107 Comment Sir Alec Cairn Cross 137 Comment Gustav Ranis 144
    Public Disclosure Authorized pi9neers In Devero ment Public Disclosure Authorized Second Theodore W. Schultz Gottfried Haberler HlaMyint Arnold C. Harberger Ceiso Furtado Public Disclosure Authorized Gerald M. Meier, editor PUBLISHED FOR THE WORLD BANK OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Public Disclosure Authorized Oxford University Press NEW YORK OXFORD LONDON GLASGOW TORONTO MELBOURNE WELLINGTON HONG KONG TOKYO KUALA LUMPUR SINGAPORE JAKARTA DELHI BOMBAY CALCUTTA MADRAS KARACHI NAIROBI DAR ES SALAAM CAPE TOWN © 1987 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of Oxford University Press. Manufactured in the United States of America. First printing January 1987 The World Bank does not accept responsibility for the views expressed herein, which are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank or to its affiliated organizations. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Pioneers in development. Second series. Includes index. 1. Economic development. I. Schultz, Theodore William, 1902­ II. Meier, Gerald M. HD74.P56 1987 338.9 86-23511 ISBN 0-19-520542-1 Contents Preface vii Introduction On Getting Policies Right Gerald M. Meier 3 Pioneers THEODORE W. SCHULTZ 15 Tensions between Economics and Politics in Dealing with Agriculture 17 Comment Nurul Islam 39 GOTTFRIED HABERLER 49 Liberal and Illiberal Development Policy 51 Comment Max Corden 84 Comment Ronald Findlay 92 HLA MYINT 105 Neoclassical Development Analysis: Its Strengths and Limitations 107 Comment Sir Alec Cairn cross 137 Comment Gustav Ranis 144 ARNOLD C.
    [Show full text]
  • Redalyc.Recovering Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Under A
    Investigación Económica ISSN: 0185-1667 [email protected] Facultad de Economía México Ferreira de Mendonça, Helder; Caldas Montes, Gabriel Recovering Effectiveness of Monetary Policy under a Deflationary Environment Investigación Económica, vol. LXVII, núm. 265, julio-septiembre, 2008, pp. 121-144 Facultad de Economía Distrito Federal, México Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=60126504 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative investigación económica, vol. LXVII, 265, julio-septiembre de 2008, pp. 121-144 Recovering Effectiveness of Monetary Policy under a Deflationary Environment H����� F������� �� M������� G������ C����� M�����* I����������� In the last decade several countries have adopted a strategy for the conduction of a monetary policy based on central bank independence and inflation targeting. Generally speaking, the results suggest success in controlling inflation in several emerging and industrialized economies. Nonetheless, under this new environment, a new problem emerges: the risk of deflation. The main problem, as shown by the Japanese experience, is that falling prices may lock countries into a spiral of economic decline. The core of the idea is: once consumers expect falling prices, they decide to postpone purchases, implying a decrease in demand and a consequent fall in prices by producers, threatening the start of a spiral of fall in output and demand. Furthermore, based on the results presented by a profit maximizing behavior, both prices and output are influenced by expected future prices.
    [Show full text]
  • NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IS-LM and MONETARISM Michael
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IS-LM AND MONETARISM Michael D. Bordo Anna J. Schwartz Working Paper 9713 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9713 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May 2003 This paper was presented at the 2003 HOPE Conference on “The IS/LM Model: Its Rise, Fall, and Strange Persistence” at Duke University, April 25-27. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2003 by Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. IS-LM and Monetarism Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz NBER Working Paper No. 9713 May 2003 JEL No. B22, B31, B41, E12, N12 ABSTRACT This paper discusses monetarist objections to the IS-LM model. We explore the views of two principal spokesmen for monetarism: Milton Friedman and the team of Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer. Friedman did not explicitly state the reasons he generally chose not to use the IS-LM model in rejecting Keynesian views on the demand function for money, the role of autonomous expenditures in cyclical fluctuations, the potency of fiscal policy as against monetary policy, etc. He presented statistical findings, historical evidence, and econometric results to support his alternative analysis of macroeconomics, but his critics were unconvinced. In 1970, in an effort to use his critics’ common language, he set up a model with explicit terms for IS-LM to encompass both the quantity theory and the income-expenditure theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Institutions, History and Wage Bargaining Outcomes: International Evidence from the Post-World War Two Era
    Chris Minns and Marian Rizov Institutions, history and wage bargaining outcomes: international evidence from the post-World War Two era Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Minns, Chris and Rizov, Marian (2015) Institutions, history and wage bargaining outcomes: international evidence from the post-World War Two era. Business History, 57 (3). pp. 358-375. ISSN 0007-6791 DOI: 10.1080/00076791.2014.983480 © 2015 Taylor & Francis This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/88847/ Available in LSE Research Online: June 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Institutions, History and Wage Bargaining Outcomes: International Evidence from the Post-World War Two Era Chris Minnsa and Marian Rizovb aDepartment of Economic History, London School of Economics, London, United Kingdom; bDepartment of Economics, Middlesex University Business School, London, United Kingdom (Submitted 29th September 2013; accepted 16 July 2014) Abstract This paper uses international evidence to assess the impact of tripartism and other forms of government involvement in bargaining on wage moderation and wage dispersion.
    [Show full text]
  • Wage Restraint, Employment, and the Legacy of the General Theory's
    Wage Restraint, Employment, and the Legacy of the General Theory’s Chapter 19 Oliver Landmann University of Freiburg i.Br. 1. Introduction The role of wages in the determination of aggregate employment remains one of the most hotly debated public policy issues in many European countries, and in Germany in particular. This is not surprising in view of the high-profile collective bargaining process in which organized labor and employers negotiate over wages under conditions of persistent high unemployment. Of course, neither side wishes to be seen as merely pursuing its narrow self-interest. Both employers and unions make every effort to argue as convincingly as possible that their respective bargaining positions are conducive to employment growth and macroeconomic stability. Employers invoke neoclassical labor market theory to reject any demands for wage increases in excess of labor productivity growth. Such wage increases, they argue, mean rising labor costs and hence cause job losses. Unions, in contrast, emphasize demand-side repercussions and appeal to the keynesian notion of the circular flow of income. They maintain that any attempt to boost employment through wage restraint is doomed to fail, mainly because this would reduce the purchasing power of consumers and thus domestic demand. Accordingly, they tend to put the blame for high unemployment on misguided fiscal and monetary policies. In contrast, the mainstream consensus regards the longer-term trends of output and employment as supply-determined and, therefore, rejects demand-side explanations of unemployment, except for the very short-run cyclical movements. Keynes (1936) devoted an entire chapter of his General Theory, the famous Chapter 19, to the macroeconomic effects of changes in money-wages.
    [Show full text]
  • GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58Th Street, Chicago, Ill
    THE PROCESS AND PROGRESS OF ECONOMICS Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December, 1982 by GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, Ill. 60637, USA In the work on the economics of information which I began twenty some years ago, I started with an example: how does one find the seller of automobiles who is offering a given model at the lowest price? Does it pay to search more, the more frequently one purchases an automobile, and does it ever pay to search out a large number of potential sellers? The study of the search for trading partners and prices and qualities has now been deepened and widened by the work of scores of skilled economic theorists. I propose on this occasion to address the same kinds of questions to an entirely different market: the market for new ideas in economic science. Most economists enter this market in new ideas, let me emphasize, in order to obtain ideas and methods for the applications they are making of economics to the thousand problems with which they are occupied: these economists are not the suppliers of new ideas but only demanders. Their problem is comparable to that of the automobile buyer: to find a reliable vehicle. Indeed, they usually end up by buying a used, and therefore tested, idea. Those economists who seek to engage in research on the new ideas of the science - to refute or confirm or develop or displace them - are in a sense both buyers and sellers of new ideas. They seek to develop new ideas and persuade the science to accept them, but they also are following clues and promises and explorations in the current or preceding ideas of the science.
    [Show full text]
  • Glory Liu | Stanford University Writing Sample—Please Do Not Cite Or Circulate Without Permission Last Updated: June 2016
    Glory Liu | Stanford University Writing Sample—please do not cite or circulate without permission Last updated: June 2016 Abstract: This paper is an excerpt from my dissertation on the reception of Adam Smith in American political thought and intellectual history (table of contents on next page), and focuses on the historical and intellectual forces in the twentieth century that produced an image of Smith as the “father of economics.” I argue that the Chicago School of Economics is largely responsible for producing an image of Smith associated with the politics and economics of American neoliberalism, and that this image emerged out of competing discourses around the nature of economic science from the 1930s onward. In the early 1930s and 40s, figures such as Frank Knight and Jacob Viner crafted an image of Smith as the intellectual forbearer of neoclassical price theory, and an economic science that could be “useful for guiding conduct.” From the 1950s onward, the generation of economists that included Milton Friedman, George Stigler, and Ronald Coase constructed an image of Smith associated with a narrower definition of economic expertise—namely, empirical testing, prediction, and its application to public policy. The notions of self-interest and “the invisible hand” became central to their approach, and ultimately opened the doors for the heavy politicization of Smith’s ideas. 1 Glory Liu | Stanford University Writing Sample—please do not cite or circulate without permission Last updated: June 2016 “Inventing the Invisible Hand: Adam Smith and the Making of an American Creed” Table of Contents and Chapter Summaries Chapter 1: Who was Adam Smith? This is an introductory chapter that outlines the scope of the project, provides a brief biographical sketch of the life of Smith and his immediate reception in Great Britain, and surveys current Smith scholarship.
    [Show full text]
  • Power, Platforms and the Free Trade Delusion
    Trade and Development Report 2018: Power, Platforms and the Free Trade Delusion Addendum UNDERSTANDING THE GLOBAL ECONOMY ∗ WITH THE UN GLOBAL POLICY MODEL ∗ This UNCTAD Technical Addendum to the Trade and Development Report 2018: Power, Platforms and the Free Trade Delusion was prepared by external consultant Prof. Amitava Dutt (Department of Political Science, University of Notre Dame, USA and FLACSO-Ecuador), with guidance of UNCTAD’s Senior staff members. This paper has not been formally edited. - 1 - 1. Injections and leakages and financing For understanding the growth of an economy, it is useful to start with an accounting identity that shows how final production (net of intermediate goods that are used up in production) of a region, or its Gross Domestic Product (GDP), is purchased by different sectors of the economy, that is, = + + + , where Y is total production, C is consumption, mostly purchased − by households, I is investment, mostly purchases by firms, G is government expenditure on goods and services, E is exports and M imports. This production identity shows that goods and services produced must end up as consumption, investment (which is mostly for adding to the stock of productive capital), government expenditure and exports, with imports subtracted because part of the first three items may represent purchases of what is produced abroad. The value of what is produced is equal to the value of income, and income can be consumed, saved, or taxed. From this we get the income identity = + + , where S is private saving and T is taxes (less transfers), we can use the production identity to get ( ) + ( ) + ( ) = 0, which we will refer to as the identity −.
    [Show full text]
  • Analysis of the Liquidity Preference Theory of Interest
    University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1950 Analysis of the liquidity preference theory of interest Earl M. Stephanson The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Stephanson, Earl M., "Analysis of the liquidity preference theory of interest" (1950). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 4820. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/4820 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected]. m wm&is g f t h e m m m e m ? m mm ® ? ky ..... Bari M . Stephenson. - 1C* A** Montana State University, 1950 Presented, in partial fulfillment of the requirement for the degree of Master of Arte Montana State University Approved* Chairman of Board Of Examiners La >. I- Bean, Graduate School UMI Number: EP40284 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Dissertation Publishing UMI EP40284 Published by ProQuest LLC (2014). Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author.
    [Show full text]
  • James M. Buchanan Jr. [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Niclas Berggren Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 292-299
    James M. Buchanan Jr. [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Niclas Berggren Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 292-299 Abstract James M. Buchanan Jr. is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/718/BuchananIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH James M. Buchanan Jr. by Niclas Berggren6 James M. Buchanan (1919–2013) was born in rural Tennessee under rather simple circumstances: “It was a very poor life,” he says (Buchanan 2009, 91). Still, he ended up, in 1986, as a recipient of the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. The Prize was awarded “for his development of the contractual and constitutional bases for the theory of economic and political decision-making.” Buchanan earned his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Chicago in 1948 and was thereafter a professor at the University of Tennessee, Florida State University, the University of Virginia, UCLA, Virginia Polytechnic Institute, and George Mason University. In spite of his academic accomplishments, Buchanan felt himself to be apart from an established elite—academic, intellectual or political—and he even regarded that elite with suspicion. The attitude can be connected to Buchanan’s ideological convictions and how these changed over the course of his lifetime.
    [Show full text]
  • Macro-Economics of Balance-Sheet Problems and the Liquidity Trap
    Contents Summary ........................................................................................................................................................................ 4 1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................... 7 2 The IS/MP–AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................ 9 2.1 The IS/MP model ............................................................................................................................................ 9 2.2 Aggregate demand: the AD-curve ........................................................................................................ 13 2.3 Aggregate supply: the AS-curve ............................................................................................................ 16 2.4 The AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................................ 17 3 Economic recovery after a demand shock with balance-sheet problems and at the zero lower bound .................................................................................................................................................. 18 3.1 A demand shock under normal conditions without balance-sheet problems ................... 18 3.2 A demand shock under normal conditions, with balance-sheet problems ......................... 19 3.3
    [Show full text]
  • Zero Nominal Interest Rates, Unemployment, Excess Reserves and Deflation in a Liquidity Trap
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Murota, Ryu-ichiro; Ono, Yoshiyasu Working Paper Zero nominal interest rates, unemployment, excess reserves and deflation in a liquidity trap ISER Discussion Paper, No. 748 Provided in Cooperation with: The Institute of Social and Economic Research (ISER), Osaka University Suggested Citation: Murota, Ryu-ichiro; Ono, Yoshiyasu (2009) : Zero nominal interest rates, unemployment, excess reserves and deflation in a liquidity trap, ISER Discussion Paper, No. 748, Osaka University, Institute of Social and Economic Research (ISER), Osaka This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/92845 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under
    [Show full text]