Mirowski As Critic of the Digital

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Mirowski As Critic of the Digital David Golumbia Virginia Commonwealth University boundary 2 symposium, “Neoliberalism, Its Ontology and Genealogy: The Work and Context of Philip Mirowski” University of Pittsburgh March 16-17, 2017 Mirowski as Critic of the Digital Although Philip Mirowski’s work has been profoundly influential in fields as diverse as economics, history of science, political science, and even literary studies, it is somewhat surprisingly less well-known in the emerging complex of fields which are sometimes referred to as “Digital Studies,” meaning all the fields that directly analyze the social, cultural, and political- economic impacts of the computer. This is unfortunate enough from the perspective of political economy, since Mirowski’s writings on neoliberalism resonate strongly with some of the most incisive political-economic work in Digital Studies, and since Mirowski frequently writes directly about digital technology. At the same time, Mirowski’s work cuts against the grain of some of the myths that circulate not just around Silicon Valley and other industry promoters of digital technology, but among the rather large part—it may even be the majority—of Digital Studies scholars who choose not to interrogate critically the sources and functions of technology and the culture surrounding it. In addition to the intersection of Mirowski’s work with Digital Studies, I will also occasionally refer in what follow to Digital Humanities, the sub-discipline or para-discipline of English and History (among other fields) that purports to focus on the use of Mirowski as Critic of the Digital - 2 what it calls “digital tools” in the service of humanities scholarship, and that is even more prone to an uncritical adoption of digital industry and cyberlibertarian truisms, but my main focus will be on Digital Studies taken as the critical analysis, or at least the analysis, of the effects of digital technology on culture. Even in these formulations it is hard to be as precise as one would like, not least since “the digital” in all respects is a constantly-moving target, something Mirowski’s work is particularly sensitive to, as I’ll try to mention as I go along. I’m going to approach Mirowski’s work on the digital in four parts: to begin with, two longer parts focusing on Never Let a Crisis Go to Waste and Mirowski’s 2002 opus, Machine Dreams; and then I’ll conclude with two brief sections on Mirowski’s concept of “market automata” and his recent work on how concepts of information function in economics.1 i. Neoliberalism and the Digital The aspect of Mirowski’s work that is touched on at least occasionally in Digital Studies is the one on which this symposium focuses, namely neoliberalism in its various political, institutional and intellectual forms. Despite this influence, it remains remarkable how often Mirowski’s 1 I use page numbers along with these abbreviations in what follows for references to the following works by Mirowski: IE: “Information in Economics” (2016) MCTB: “Markets Come to Bits” (2007a) MD: Machine Dreams (2002) NLCW: Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste (2013) Mirowski as Critic of the Digital - 3 arguments are either misunderstood or deliberately misconstrued in Digital Studies, sometimes along lines that he specifically guards against. Computers and digital media do not figure centrally in Mirowski’s key work on neoliberalism, Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste, but they do come up fairly regularly. One important idea, that comes up in other works of his as well, is that at the heart of neoliberal economic doctrine is the notion of the market as computer—or more specifically “information processor”—that is at once both the apotheosis of human cognition (but only because humans participate in the market) and the thing that renders human cognition nearly useless: the marketplace is deemed to be a superior information processor, so therefore all human knowledge can be used to its fullest only if it is comprehensively owned and priced. This was deployed in a myriad of ways to suggest what might seem a string of strident non sequiturs: for instance, some neoliberals actually maintained that the solution to perceived problems in derivatives and securitization was redoubled “innovation” in derivatives and securitization, and not their curtailment. (65-6) This leads to a host of paradoxes with deep resonance for digital culture, perhaps chief among them that “a society dedicated to rational discourse about a market conceived as a superior information processor ended up praising and promoting ignorance” (70); it famously leads Mirowski to observe that the “the major ambition of the Neoliberal Thought Collective is to sow doubt and ignorance among the populace, because it helps foster the ‘spontaneous order’ that is Mirowski as Critic of the Digital - 4 the object of all their endeavors” (224).One place this can be seen in recent technology is in Bitcoin and the blockchain: I have argued (Golumbia 2016), following Mirowski, that these are assemblages of software and hardware as well as discourse one of whose main purposes is to sow a deeply dogmatic and even conspiratorial kind of ignorance about many philosophical and political matters in favor of the “wisdom” of a “radically decentralized” market. One of the phenomena this line of thinking helps to illuminate, and here I will echo Mirowski’s talk from yesterday a bit, is the otherwise-unaccountable insistence among digital advocates that knowledge needs to be “democratized” and that the way to achieve this democratization is to remove what digital enthusiasts call “gatekeepers” or even “elites” who are said to maintain illegitimate control over the dissemination of knowledge. Many of the most vocal pundits of the digital revolution have made good livings by selling the public on the view that journalism and academic research are being inevitably disrupted by the supposedly inexorable digital revolution. These pundits specialize in telling us that on the one hand they rank intellectual inquiry and responsible investigative journalism as among the most important characteristics of a free society, and that on the other hand we just have to deal with the fact that the roles of those who specialize in these activities are being decimated by the “democratization” of the internet. Quite a few of these pundits don’t also tell us that they very literally sell this dogma to the most “disruptive” of Silicon Valley capitalists, while continuing to take advantage of academic institutions that appear only too happy to let them portray themselves as Mirowski as Critic of the Digital - 5 disinterested observers of the contemporary scene. It is no stretch to see in this work a distinct echo of the core NTC doctrine of ignorance, here framed as a kind of superior crowd-based knowledge that improves on any form of prior expertise, without any grounding for such claims—in fact, if anything, with plenty of reason to doubt it. This should not be taken to imply that Clay Shirky and Jeff Jarvis and others of their ilk are consciously deceiving their audiences (although I would not rule this out entirely either, especially for the pundits who also work as industry consultants), or that they recognize in any deep way the degree to which they rely on something like Hayekian epistemology. Rather, another of the ideas Mirowski introduces in Never Let a Serious Crisis serves us in good stead here, the idea we heard mentioned yesterday of a “special structure of intellectual discourse” Mirowski calls the “’Russian doll’ approach to the integration of research and praxis in the modern world” (NLCW 43). The point of this analysis is to suggest that there are layers to neoliberal doctrine, and that as we progress from layer to layer—from doll to larger doll, or as he often calls them, from shell to larger shell—the doctrine may appear in translated or altered form. As Mirowski explains it, the innermost doll was (or is) the Mont Pelerin Society itself, “constituted as a closed, private members-only debating society whose participants were hand- picked (originally primarily by Hayek, but later through a closed nomination procedure) and which consciously sought to remain out of the public eye” (NLCW 43). Some MPS members were academics but some were not; “One then might regard specific academic departments Mirowski as Critic of the Digital - 6 where the neoliberals came to dominate before 1980…as the next outer layer” of the Matryoshka doll, “one emergent public face of the thought collective—although one rarely publicly acknowledging links to the MPS” (NLCW 44); another shell includes “special-purpose foundations for the education and promotion of neoliberal doctrines” (NLCW 44); “the next shell would consist of general-purpose ‘think tanks’ … and satellite organizations… that sheltered neoliberals, who themselves might or might not also be members in good standing of various academic disciplines and universities” (NLCW 44). The point of referring to these groups and others as shells or Matryoshka dolls is to emphasize that they are not a uniform bloc espousing a unitary neoliberal doctrine as handed down from on high, but rather that with each increasing layer of the dolls we get an increasingly diffuse and plausibly deniable connection to the innermost circles, even if this means that on some issues—typically more peripheral to the deepest concerns of the MPS—the outer shells may recommend positions that do not entirely jibe with theirs. Mirowski’s conception of Matryoshka Dolls proves incredibly useful for analyzing the phenomenon that I and other scholars refer to as “cyberlibertarianism.” Despite the way the word sounds, we use it to point not (just) at the presence of political libertarians in Silicon Valley and the rest of digital culture, but instead the often-blind adoption of “libertarian”—in the vaguest and most general sense possible—principles, ideas, and definitions even among those who claim, and may earnestly believe, that they aren’t libertarians at all.
Recommended publications
  • Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative
    [Show full text]
  • Philip Mirowski, Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste: How Neoliberalism Survived the Financial Meltdown, New York: Verso, 2013
    Book Review Symposium Philip Mirowski, Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste: How Neoliberalism Survived the Financial Meltdown, New York: Verso, 2013. ISBN: 9781781680797 (cloth); ISBN: 9781781683033 (ebook); ISBN: 9781781683026 (paper) Author’s response I want to thank Antipode and the four participants for lengthy reactions to my book Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste. I think it is apparent it was written in a funk of distress; and the reviewers here invite me to step back from all that, and reflect on how it has been regarded by various readers who do not necessarily share my own particular chagrin nor my axes to grind. The experience has been salutary, and evokes a few short responses. One theme present to a greater or lesser extent in all the reviews is that, as Nick Gane puts it, I never tell the reader “what should happen next”; or, as Geoff Mann writes, “OK. So what now?”. I should confess I also get this a lot when I give talks concerning the subjects in the book. When that happens, I take the occasion to suggest that one of the primary lessons of the book directly informs my self-denying ordinance: the prohibition of offering any ‘remedies’ as conventional bullet points, like those which fill the last chapters of the torrent of crisis books which have fallen from the presses clonedead since 2008. When the Neoliberal Thought Collective (NTC) began to organize itself in the 1930s/40s, it found itself stranded in the intellectual wilderness, exiled from political power by Depression and war, and suffering internal disarray, much as the Left has experienced now.
    [Show full text]
  • 2008-2014 HOPE Center Highlights.Pdf
    The Center for the History of Political Economy Duke University 2008-2014 Highlights The Center for the History of Political Economy began operation in Fall 2008 funded by a grant from the John W. Pope Foundation. The Center has subsequently received funding from a variety of foundations, including the Earhart Foundation, the Institute for New Economic Thinking, the National Endowment for the Humanities, and the Thomas Smith Foundation. The mission of the Center is to promote and support the teaching of, and research in, the history of economics. Our success in fulfilling that mission has been documented in annual reports. Sometimes, however, it makes sense to step back and view the accomplishments of the Center from a longer run perspective. This report offers such a perspective. HOPE Faculty There are five faculty members currently at Duke who specialize in the history of economic thought: Bruce Caldwell, Neil De Marchi, Craufurd Goodwin, Kevin Hoover, and Roy Weintraub. The Center is directed by Bruce Caldwell. He is greatly assisted in his work by the other HOPE faculty, as well as by Angela Zemonek, the Center Administrative Assistant, and Paul Dudenhefer, the General Manager of the journal History of Political Economy. HOPE faculty members are active in both teaching and research, as will be demonstrated below. In the teaching section, some of the courses within the history of political economy that each faculty member teaches are described. This is followed by a summary of each professor’s recent research activity. HOPE Faculty – Teaching HOPE faculty members teach a variety of undergraduate courses that deal with the history of economics.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Entropy in the Development of Economics
    entropy Article The Role of Entropy in the Development of Economics Aleksander Jakimowicz Department of World Economy, Institute of Economics, Polish Academy of Sciences, Palace of Culture and Science, 1 Defilad Sq., 00-901 Warsaw, Poland; [email protected] Received: 25 February 2020; Accepted: 13 April 2020; Published: 16 April 2020 Abstract: The aim of this paper is to examine the role of thermodynamics, and in particular, entropy, for the development of economics within the last 150 years. The use of entropy has not only led to a significant increase in economic knowledge, but also to the emergence of such scientific disciplines as econophysics, complexity economics and quantum economics. Nowadays, an interesting phenomenon can be observed; namely, that rapid progress in economics is being made outside the mainstream. The first significant achievement was the emergence of entropy economics in the early 1970s, which introduced the second law of thermodynamics to considerations regarding production processes. In this way, not only was ecological economics born but also an entropy-based econometric approach developed. This paper shows that non-extensive cross-entropy econometrics is a valuable complement to traditional econometrics as it explains phenomena based on power-law probability distribution and enables econometric model estimation for non-ergodic ill-behaved (troublesome) inverse problems. Furthermore, the entropy economics has accelerated the emergence of modern econophysics and complexity economics. These new directions of research have led to many interesting discoveries that usually contradict the claims of conventional economics. Econophysics has questioned the efficient market hypothesis, while complexity economics has shown that markets and economies function best near the edge of chaos.
    [Show full text]
  • On Reviewing Machine Dreams: Zoomed-In Vs. Zoomed-Out
    Review Essay On Reviewing Machine Dreams: Zoomed-in vs. zoomed-out LAWRENCE A. BOLAND, FRSC Simon Fraser University Philip Mirowski, Machine Dreams, Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002. Pp. xiv + 655. When I set out to review this book I began reading the many review essays about Phillip Mirowski’s Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science, I was immediately reminded of the old story about the seven blind men and the elephant. The one who touched its side thought it was a wall; the one who touched its leg thought it was a column holding up the roof; the one touching an ear thought it was a chapatti; and so on. That this book has been so extensively reviewed seems to be an interesting fact that by itself needs to be examined. While one could categorize the various reviews by noting which parts they focused on – since almost every reviewer chose a different aspect of Machine Dreams (MD) – I will instead categorize them by their seeming purpose as book reviews. My experience with reviews suggests to me that there are three major purposes for a book review: (1) a simple report of the contents of the book that someone could read to learn what is in the book, (2) a launch pad to present the reviewer’s own views on the topics covered in the book, and of course, (3) a means to criticize the author’s views. Also, one could distinguish between audiences for the book as well as the audiences for the review and how a review might be tailored for each.
    [Show full text]
  • Can an Interdisciplinary Field Contribute to One of the Parent
    Eur. Phys. J. Special Topics 225, 3127–3135 (2016) © EDP Sciences, Springer-Verlag 2016 THE EUROPEAN DOI: 10.1140/epjst/e2016-60115-x PHYSICAL JOURNAL SPECIAL TOPICS Regular Article Can an interdisciplinary field contribute to one of the parent disciplines from which it emerged? Anirban Chakraborti1,a, Dhruv Raina2,b, and Kiran Sharma1,c 1 School of Computational and Integrative Sciences, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi-110067, India 2 Zakir Husain Centre for Educational Studies, School of Social Sciences, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi-110067, India Received 15 April 2016 / Received in final form 15 September 2016 Published online 22 December 2016 Abstract. In the light of contemporary discussions of inter and trans disciplinarity, this paper approaches econophysics and sociophysics to seek a response to the question – whether these interdisciplinary fields could contribute to physics and economics. Drawing upon the literature on history and philosophy of science, the paper argues that the two way traffic between physics and economics has a long history and this is likely to continue in the future. 1 Introduction “And how long do you think we can keep up this coming and going” he asked. Florentina Aziza had kept his answer ready... “Forever” he said. – Gabriel Garcia M´arquez, Love in the Time of Cholera In order to answer the question whether econophysics could contribute to physics and/or economics, we shall begin by charting out the emergence of interdisciplinar- ity, so as to comprehend the nature of exchange and circulation of concepts and metaphors between disciplines. It is these transactions that provide the conceptual bedrock for the emergence of interdisciplinarity.
    [Show full text]
  • Minsky, Markomata, and the Tendency of Markets to Undermine Themselves
    Journal of Institutional Economics (2010), 6: 4, 415–443 C The JOIE Foundation 2010 doi:10.1017/S1744137409990397 First published online 16 July 2010 Inherent Vice: Minsky, Markomata, and the tendency of markets to undermine themselves PHILIP MIROWSKI∗ University of Notre Dame, Indiana, USA Abstract: Most current explanations of the crisis which began in 2007/8 tend to search for scapegoats, in the format of behavioral flaws. Their treatment of ‘risk’ is an important signpost to where such theories go awry. This paper suggests a structural theory of the crisis, informed by Institutionalist themes. We insist there is an alternative to a neoclassical macroeconomics, in the guise of possible alternative heterodox microfoundations for Minsky’s account of economic crises, beyond the Kaleckian markup model. The sketch is based upon elevation of some formal notions of computational complexity to pride of place, and characterization of crises as a collapse of complexity. It is an attempt to portray a market system evolving to a point of ‘inherent vice’: an endogenous development which by its very nature, cannot be tamed through conventional insurance or risk models. Inherent vice (n., insurance terminology): An exclusion found in most property insurance policies eliminating coverage for loss caused by a quality in property that causes it to damage or destroy itself. ...the economy is a complex system of interacting individuals – and these individuals themselves are complex systems. Neoclassical economics radically oversimplifies both the individuals and the system – and gets a lot of mileage by doing that; I, for one, am not going to banish maximization-and-equilibrium from my toolbox.
    [Show full text]
  • Econophysics: Bridges Over a Turbulent Current
    Econophysics: Bridges over a Turbulent Current Shu-Heng Chena, Sai-Ping Lib aAI-ECON Research Center, Department of Economics, National Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan. [email protected] bInstitute of Physics, Academia Sinica, Taipei, Taiwan. [email protected] Abstract In this editorial guide for the special issue on econophysics, we give a unique review of this young but quickly growing discipline. A suggestive taxonomy of the development is proposed by making a distinction between classical econophysics and modern econophysics. For each of these two stages of de- velopment, we identify the key economic issues whose formulations and/or treatments have been affected by physics or physicists, which includes value, business fluctuations, economic growth, economic and financial time series, the distribution of economic entities, interactions of economic agents, and economic and social networks. The recent advancements in these issues of modern econophysics are demonstrated by nine articles selected from the pa- pers presented at the Econophysics Colloquium 2010 held at Academia Sinica arXiv:1107.5373v1 [q-fin.GN] 27 Jul 2011 in Taipei. Keywords: Econophysics, Sociophysics, Distribution, Thermodynamics, Statistical Mechanism, Networks Preprint submitted to Elsevier July 28, 2011 1. Introduction Despite their very different ages, physics and economics have been de- veloped and extended along the two sides of the same river for a long time. Crossing the river signifies the efforts made to connect the side of physics with the side of economics, or more generally, the side of the natural sciences and the side of the social sciences. More than one century ago, crossing the river had already started, but over the years, particularly in recent years, the scale and organization of the crossings have changed, from individuals to communities and from traveling to immigrating.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Introduction
    i i Sitabhra Sinha, Arnab Chatterjee, Anirban Chakraborti, and Bikas K. Chakrabarti: Econophysics — Chap. sinhac01 — 2010/9/22 — page 1 — le-tex i i 1 1 Introduction “Economic theorists, like French chefs in regard to food, have developed stylized models whose ingredients are limited by some unwritten rules. Just as traditional French cooking does not use seaweed or raw fish, so neoclassical models do not make assumptions derived from psychology, anthropology, or sociology. I disagree with any rules that limit the nature of the ingredients in economic models”. – George A. Akerlof, An Economic Theorist’s Book of Tales (1984) Over the past couple of decades, a large number of physicists have started explor- ing problems which fall in the domain of economic science. The common themes that are addressed by the research of most of these groups have resulted in coining a new term “econophysics” as a collective name for this venture. Bringing togeth- er the techniques of statistical physics and nonlinear dynamics to study complex systems along with the ability to analyze large volumes of data with sophisticated statistical techniques, the discoveries made in this field have already attracted the attention of mainstream physicists and economists. While still somewhat contro- versial, it provides a promising alternative to, and a more empirically based foun- dation for the study of economic phenomena than, the mainstream axiom-based mathematical economic theory. Physicists have long had a tradition of moving to other fields of scientific in- quiry and have helped bring about paradigm shifts in the way research is carried out in those areas.
    [Show full text]
  • A Review of Philip Mirowski's More Heat Than Light: Economics As Social Physics, Physics As Nature's Economics.' Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990, Pp
    June 1991 Book Review Column Mirowski's Screed: A Review of Philip Mirowski's More Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics.' Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990, Pp. xii+ 450. $59.50 IBSN 0-521;.35042.. s. Kevin D. Hoover consistently uncharitable readings of almost University of California, Davis everyone- Veblen, Georgescu-Roegen and a few obscure figures in the history of economic More Heat Than Light! - that sums it up thought excepted. quite accurately. Alas, it will take more than I four words to convince the reader of the Mirowski's argument is about metaphor soundness of such a stark judgement. and the role of metaphorical exchanges in the Mirowski's book is a sustained .attack on development of physics and economics. In the the foundations of modem neoclassical development of energy physics, which is central economics. He gives a succinct statement of his to this book, accounting notions and notions of thesis: economy of action are borrowed from The only way to fully comprehend economics. Mirowski cites the suggestive value theory in economics is to situate it example of Joule, who may have gotten his wihin .. .. the metaphorical simplex of inspiration for his research into the mechanical energy, motion, body and value, and to equivalent of heat from the carefully maintained regard it as part and parcel of the same accounts of his family's brewery: energy was like structures that undergird Western money - the diligent bookkeeper had to account physics. [pp. 141-2) for every last tuppence. Mirowski maintains If true, this thesis has severe consequences for that economics readily borrowed from physics our understanding of the history of economic· as well, and, by the time of the rise of thought and for the methodology of economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Markets Come to Bits: Computation, Evolution and the Future of Economics
    Markets Come to Bits: Computation, Evolution and the Future of Economics Based upon: Special issue JEBO, 2007 Philip Mirowski A Brief History of Neoclassical Economic Ontology Three Phases of Scientific Models [1] Pure Mechanical Analog {1870-1940} Cf.: Mirowski, More Heat than Light (1989) [2] Agent as Information Processor {1930s- } Cf.: Mirowski, Machine Dreams (2002) [3] Market Structures as Algorithms {now} 2 Was Neoclassical Economics Ever a Theory of “Markets”? qMere synonym for ‘exchange’? qWalras… never described actual market (Walker,2001) qArrow & Hahn take markets for granted qCoase, North, … qAt best, differentiated by commodity identity, or along continuum of ‘monopoly… perfect competition’ qThoroughly ignores computational theory 3 What We Talk about when We Talk about ‘Markets’ * Data dissemination, exclusion * Order routing through time and space * Order execution * Price discovery and assignment * Custody and delivery arrangements * Clearing and settlement, including property rights assignment * Record keeping * Commodity definition and enforcement 4 Five Indicative Post-1980 Trends from agency theory to market automata ÃModern ‘Mechanism Design’ ÃZero-Intelligence Agent offshoot of Experimental Economics ÑMarket Microstructure’ in Finance ÑEngineering Economics’ ÃArtificial Intelligence researchers coding markets 5 Walrasian Mechanism Design C Begins at Cowles with work of Leonid Hurwicz: What is ‘decentralization’? C Heavy ‘welfare’ spin: Stan Reiter (1977) C 1980s shift to Bayes/Nash obsession w/truth-telling or
    [Show full text]
  • The Road from Mont Pèlerin
    the road from mont pèlerin The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective edited by Philip Mirowski Dieter Plehwe harvard university press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England 2009 Contents Introduction 1 Dieter Plehwe part one Origins of National Traditions 1 French Neoliberalism and Its Divisions: From the Colloque Walter Lippmann to the Fifth Republic 45 François Denord 2 Liberalism and Neoliberalism in Britain, 1930–1980 68 Keith Tribe 3 Neoliberalism in Germany: Revisiting the Ordoliberal Foundations of the Social Market Economy 98 Ralf Ptak 4 The Rise of the Chicago School of Economics and the Birth of Neoliberalism 139 Rob Van Horn and Philip Mirowski vi contents part two Arguing Out Strategies on Targeted Topics 5 The Neoliberals Confront the Trade Unions 181 Yves Steiner 6 Reinventing Monopoly and the Role of Corporations: The Roots of Chicago Law and Economics 204 Rob Van Horn 7 The Origins of the Neoliberal Economic Development Discourse 238 Dieter Plehwe 8 Business Conservatives and the Mont Pèlerin Society 280 Kim Phillips-Fein part three Mobilization for Action 9 The Influence of Neoliberals in Chile before, during, and after Pinochet 305 Karin Fischer 10 Taking Aim at the New International Economic Order 347 Jennifer Bair 11 How Neoliberalism Makes Its World: The Urban Property Rights Project in Peru 386 Timothy Mitchell Postface: Defining Neoliberalism 417 Philip Mirowski List of Contributors 457 Index 459 Introduction dieter plehwe Neoliberalism is anything but a succinct, clearly defined political philoso- phy. Both friends and foes have done their share to simplify, if not popularize, neoliberal worldviews. Paradoxically, Margaret Thatcher’s “TINA” (there is no alternative) corresponds with the left-wing critique, which posits that neoliber- alism is best understood as an economic pensée unique (a concept popularized by Pierre Bourdieu).
    [Show full text]