Objectivity – a Pipe Dream

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Objectivity – a Pipe Dream 64 OObjectivity - a Pipe Dream ? Ethics & Trust in Finance Global edition 2016-2017 Finalist Mariusz Maziarz On Price Indices The estimates obtained in these three ways are likely to differ more Poland and Objectivity Ph.D. candidate, than the average value of their Wroclaw University of 8IBU XJMM UIF SBUF PG JOËBUJPO ex-post error. Moreover, even an Economics*, be next year? That question can be answer to the question about the Wroclaw answered in several ways. A skeptic JOËBUJPO SBUF UIBU XBT NFBTVSFE who adheres to the Pyrrhonic in the previous year is ambiguous. conviction that it is impossible It can be given by indicating the to make predictions will look at value of the Consumer Price Index MBTU ZFBSkT JOËBUJPO ÊHVSFT XIJDI (CPI) or Producer Price Index assuming random changes in this (PPI) published by the US Bureau macroeconomic indicator, would be of Labor Statistics. Or one might the best estimate. An econometrician VTF UIF WBMVF PG UIF (%1 EFËBUPS will apply his mathematical knowledge whose estimates are delivered by the and modeling ability to analyze how Bureau of Economic Analysis. Then, JOËBUJPOIBTCFFOUSFOEJOHPWFSUIF for the sake of simplicity, one might past years and whether it has been compare the cost of the same basket correlated with other variables. A of shopping bought today and a year * The views expressed herein are those of the (theoretical) economist will build ago. Finally, the value of each of the author and do not neces- a mathematical model determining JOËBUJPOJOEJDBUPSTNFOUJPOFEBCPWF TBSJMZSFËFDUUIPTFPGUIF the essential relationship between can be calculated with the Paasche 0SHBOJ[BUJPOIFJTBGÊMJBUFE UIF FOEPHFOPVT JOËBUJPO SBUF BOE and Laspeyres indices, which will to. exogeous determinants. BMTP JOËVFODF UIF FTUJNBUF "T UIBU FINANCE & THE COMMON GOOD/ BIEN COMMUN 65 shows, any answer to a question to knowledge induction is was concerning an economic fact convincingly argued by Taleb (2010, depends on the methods applied to p. 40), when described the thoughts Quel sera le taux getting that answer. EkJOËBUJPOMkBOO²F of a doomed turkey that took what prochaine ? La réponse 8F DBO ÊOE EFNBOET GPS it had seen of life so far as proof that dépend de la méthode objectivity in many ethical codes it would live forever. Until, that is, de calcul. Les éva- PG DPOEVDU JO ÊOBODJBM TFSWJDFT *O Thanksgiving came along.) luations obtenues de différentes façons sont those from national and international In this essay, I advance a thesis susceptibles de différer bank associations, from supervisory UIBU GVMÊMMJOH TVDI EFNBOET GPS plus que la valeur authorities, and from professional objectivity is impossible. Objectivity moyenne de leur erreur organizations. For instance, Polish is out of the question not because a posteriori. Même une banks have voluntarily agreed to of the malice or greed of the people réponse à la question be bound by the Code of Banking XPSLJOH JO UIF ÊOBODJBM TFDUPS CVU EVUBVYEkJOËBUJPOEF Ethics, which provides that disputes l’année précédente est because an objective or – in other ambiguë, on peut la with clients are resolved “in an words – true viewpoint either does donner en indiquant la objective way” (ZBP 2013, p. 5). not exist or is epistemologically Similarly, the valeur de l’Indice des Code of Ethics and inaccessible. prix à la consommation Standards of Professional Conduct (le CCPP) ou l’Indice published by the CFA Institute It is clear that most of the des prix à la production PCMJHFT ÊOBODJBM BOBMZTUT issues dealt with by the employees (PPI). Ou, au contraire, to “deal fairly and objectively PG UIF ÊOBODJBM TFDUPS BSF OPU utiliser la valeur du matters for philosophical debate. GBDUFVSEFE²ËBUJPO with all clients” (paragraph III.B) du PIB. La valeur de and also “to achieve and maintain For instance, there is an objective chacun des indicateurs independence and objectivity answer to a client’s question about EkJOËBUJPOTVTNFOUJPO - in their professional activities” the commission in a relevant table nés peut être calculée (I.B). Objectivity is mentioned as of fees and commissions. Similarly, avec les indices de principle 2 by the Code of Ethics and there is one mathematical formula Paasche et Laspeyres Professional Responsibility set up by GPSDBMDVMBUJOHUIFQSPÊUPOBEFQPTJU RVJJOËVFODFSPOUBVTTJ UIF$FSUJÊFE'JOBODJBM1MBOOFS#PBSE l’estimation. given its value, maturity, and the of Standards (2016). Being objective interest rate. However, as I intend is also mentioned in the codes of to highlight in this introductory DPOEVDUPGNBOZCBOLTBOEÊOBODJBM section, situations in which an Nous pouvons trouver institutions (cf., for instance, objective answer cannot be reached les exigences d’objec- JPMorgan Chase&Co. 2016). PDDVSNPSFPGUFOJOÊOBODJBMTFSWJDFT tivité dans plusieurs codes de conduite Now, though induction is an than is commonly believed. Below, en matière éthique uncertain source of knowledge, * CSJFËZ SFWJFX UIF QIJMPTPQIJDBM établis tant par des I will take the liberty of claiming sources of the idea of objectivity and associations de banque that objectivity is, if only implicitly, the accessibility of truth and go on internationales que demanded by all ethical codes of to analyze several case studies that nationales, des auto- seem to contradict such a viewpoint. rités de surveillance DPOEVDU FTUBCMJTIFE CZ ÊOBODJBM institutions. (How uncertain a route Finally, I offer a few solutions. DO THE RIGHT THING: INCENTIVISE ETHICS 66 et des organisations by the practically-oriented sophists professionnelles. Par A Few Words on Philosophy that earned popularity. That is why exemple, le Code science is now seen as an activity d’Ethique et de Normes In ancient Greece, beside the aimed at discovering truth. de Conduite Profes- mainstream philosophers we sionnelle publié par This truth is understood as an l’Institut CFA (2014) recognize today, there were also objective description of reality, oblige les analystes sophists, who – as Sophie’s teacher rather than as something that offers ÊOBODJFST©USBJUFS BQUMZ PCTFSWFE JO UIF ÊDUJPOBMJ[FE models to help deal with the world. de manière équitable introduction to the history of The objective of eternal truth was et objective tous les philosophy, Sophie’s World – established by one of the Socrates’ clients» (paragraphe rejected a huge part of philosophical students, Plato, who believed that III.B) et aussi à deliberations (particularly «atteindre et conser- truth, or – in other words – what ver l’indépendance et metaphysics), because “although science produces, should describe l’objectivité dans leurs answers to philosophical questions eternal ideas rather than a changeable activités profession- may exist, man cannot know the everyday experience. Plato (2000, p. nelles» (I.B). truth about the riddles of nature 220) believed that our experience is Dans cet essai, j’avance and of universe” (Gaarder, 1994, mere illusion, similar to the shades la thèse que satisfaire p. 60). One of the sophists making of reality, of ideas on a wall of the les exigences d’objecti- a living out of teaching Athenians, cave seen by the people held inside. vité est impossible. La raison est qu’un point Protagoras, rightly observed that, for de vue objectif ou – en human beings, “man is the measure Mirroring reality d’autres termes – vrai, of all things.” However, it was not the However, Plato optimistically soit n’existe pas, soit philosophical viewpoint supported assumed that, through rational est épistémologique- Graph1: Plato’s Allegory of the cave. inquiries, we can understand the ment inaccessible. reality which, located in front of the entrance to the cave, casts the shade. Indeed, understanding reality, or, in Les sophistes ont rejeté other words, explaining it, is the main une grande partie des goal of the most popular paradigm débats philosophiques of the philosophy of economics – (particulièrement méta- TDJFOUJÊDSFBMJTN5IJTUSFOEFNFSHFE physiques), parce que in the mid-20 th century in an attempt «bien que les réponses UP SFTQPOE UP UIF TFWFSF EJGÊDVMUJFT aux questions philo- sophiques puissent faced by the Vienna Circle positivists. exister, on ne peut It was also a response to the success pas connaître la vérité Source: Saenredam J., Plato’s Allegory of the physical sciences. Even though sur les énigmes de la of the cave, http://www.britishmuseum. calling economics a successful science nature et de l’univers». org/research/collection_online/collec- is a risky and questionable thesis, Protagoras a observé tion_object_details/collection_image_ the methodologists of this particular avec justesse que gallery.aspx?partid=1&assetid=2611 discipline seem to be those most «l’homme est la mesure 45001&objectid=1490634 , (CC BY- TVQQPSUJWF PG UIF JEFB PG TDJFOUJÊD de toutes choses ». NC-SA 4.0). Access: 1 March 2016. realism. FINANCE & THE COMMON GOOD/ BIEN COMMUN 67 According to this approach, which and ontological indeterminism 1 is gets its strongest underpinning from negligible for the purposes of further the work done on the philosophy BSHVNFOU &WFO UIPVHI TDJFOUJÊD of economics by Uskali Mäki realism is the most popular approach (2011), an analytic philosopher among philosophers of economics, La science est mainte- from Helsinki, the primary aim of thinkers interested in other, usually nant considérée comme a scientist is to explain analyzed more successful sciences, do not une activité destinée phenomena. The truth or rightness support this viewpoint (Tegmark, à découvrir la vérité PG UIFPSJFT BOE NPEFMT JT EFÊOFE 1998). comprise en consé- with reference to “essesimilitude”,
Recommended publications
  • Researchers Finally Replicated Reinhart- Rogoff, and There Are Serious Problems
    Researchers Finally Replicated Reinhart- Rogoff, and There Are Serious Problems. APR 16, 2013Mike Konczal In 2010, economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff released a paper, "Growth in a Time of Debt."… Countries with debt-to-GDP ratios above 90 percent have a slightly negative average growth rate, in fact. This has been one of the most cited stats in the public debate during the Great Recession. Paul Ryan's Path to Prosperity budget states their study "found conclusive empirical evidence that [debt] exceeding 90 percent of the economy has a significant negative effect on economic growth." … In a new paper, "Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff," Thomas Herndon, Michael Ash, and Robert Pollin of the University of Massachusetts, Amherst successfully replicate the results. After trying to replicate the Reinhart-Rogoff results and failing, they reached out to Reinhart and Rogoff and they were willing to share their data spreadsheet. This allowed Herndon et al. to see how Reinhart and Rogoff's data was constructed. They find that three main issues stand out. First, Reinhart and Rogoff selectively exclude years of high debt and average growth. Second, they use a debatable method to weight the countries. Third, there also appears to be a coding error that excludes high-debt and average-growth countries. All three bias in favor of their result, and without them you don't get their controversial result. Let's investigate further: Selective Exclusions. Reinhart-Rogoff use 1946-2009 as their period, with the main difference among countries being their starting year.
    [Show full text]
  • Austerity After Reinhart and Rogoff - FT.Com
    4/18/13 Austerity after Reinhart and Rogoff - FT.com April 17, 2013 2:37 pm Austerity after Reinhart and Rogoff By Robert Pollin and Michael Ash A main policy plank is riddled with faults, write Robert Pollin and Michael Ash n 2010, two Harvard economists published an academic paper that spoke to the world’s I biggest policy question: should we cut public spending to control the deficit or use the state to rekindle economic growth? “Growth in a Time of Debt” by Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff has served as an important intellectual bulwark in support of austerity policies in the US and Europe. It has been cited by politicians ranging from Paul Ryan, the US congressman, to George Osborne, the UK chancellor. But we have shown that several critical findings advanced in this paper are wrong. So do we need to rethink austerity economics more broadly? The Reinhart­Rogoff research is best known for its result that, across a broad range of countries and historical periods, economic growth declines dramatically when a country’s level of public debt exceeds 90 per cent of gross domestic product. In their work with a sample of 20 advanced economies over the postwar period, they report that average annual GDP growth ranges between about 3 per cent and 4 per cent when the ratio of public debt to GDP is below 90 per cent. But average growth collapses to ­0.1 per cent when the ratio rises above a 90 per cent threshold. In a new working paper, co­authored with Thomas Herndon, we found that these results were based on a series of data errors and unsupportable statistical techniques.
    [Show full text]
  • Kenneth Rogoff Harvard University October 1, 2013
    FAQ on Herndon, Ash and Pollin's Critique of "Growth in a Time of Debt" Kenneth Rogoff Harvard University October 1, 2013 On April 16, 2013, University of Massachusetts scholars Thomas Herndon, Michael Ash and Robert Pollin (HAP) released a paper claiming to find mission-critical coding errors in my 6- page 2010 American Economic Association proceedings note with Carmen Reinhart, that constituted our first explicit work on debt and growth. (We received their paper on the same day.) They suggested that their results called for a sweeping reassessment of “austerity” in the United States and Europe. As this FAQ shows, they make a number of claims based on misrepresentation, selective omission, and failure to cite the literature, including our later work, and the large body of supporting work by other scholars, as well as work by earlier critics. (1) Did our first 2010 paper contain a mistake? Yes, it contains a coding error that omits some countries from the overall averages. However, as HAP correctly state in the main body of their paper, and our Errata correction confirms, the coding error has relatively minor quantitative consequences. Most of the quantitative difference they highlight in one result is due to a different weighting scheme. Importantly, the coding error does not carry over to our main paper on growth and debt, “Public Debt Overhangs” (2012, joint with Vincent Reinhart), which is much longer and more complete. The 2012 paper appears as a full journal article, not as a conference proceedings note. Our 2012 paper, which HAP do not cite, had long superseded our short May 2010 paper in academic and policy research discussions, as noted for example in the June 2013 Bank for International Settlements annual report.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Debt, GDP Growth, and Austerity: Why Reinhart and Rogoff Are Wrong
    blogs.lse.ac.uk http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/usappblog/2014/03/05/public-debt-gdp-growth-and-austerity-why-reinhart-and-rogoff-are-wrong/ Public debt, GDP growth, and austerity: why Reinhart and Rogoff are wrong Since the beginning of the financial crisis in 2008 austerity has been the cornerstone of economic policies in the U.S. and Europe. In 2010, these policies were given a significant boost by the publication of research by Harvard University Professors Reinhart and Rogoff, which stated that cutting public spending to control deficits, would help to restart economic growth. Robert Pollin discusses new research which shows that several of Reinhart and Rogoff’s critical findings were incorrect. He argues that after compensating for the mistakes made, the data shows that that the relationship between growth and public debt varies widely over time and between countries, and that countries that are approaching a 90 percent ratio of public debt to GDP may not necessarily be at a danger point for economic growth. In 2010, the Harvard University economics professors Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff published a paper in the American Economic Review, “Growth in a Time of Debt,” that spoke to the world’s biggest policy question: should we cut public spending to control the deficit or use the state to rekindle economic growth? This paper subsequently served as an important intellectual bulwark in support of austerity policies in the United States and Europe. It has been frequently cited by major economic policymakers, including the US Congressman Paul Ryan, the UK Chancellor George Osborne, and Olli Rehn, the leading economic official of the European Commission.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt and Growth in a Time of Controversy Salim Furth, Phd
    ISSUE BRIEF No. 3926 | MAY 1, 2013 Debt and Growth in a Time of Controversy Salim Furth, PhD he weight of the evidence indicates that high debt less stark but no less compelling result. They did not, Tslows growth, but there is no magic threshold however, “debunk” the paper, nor did their analysis above which any country at any time will experience speak to the many other papers on the same topic, slower growth. This truth has been illustrated in several of which are more rigorous than “Growth in the recent controversy around “Growth in a Time of a Time of Debt” and come to similar conclusions. Debt,” an academic paper by Carmen Reinhart and Debunking Debunked. In their paper and sub- Kenneth Rogoff.1 sequent discussions, Reinhart and Rogoff report the Reinhart, Rogoff, and Rebuttals.“Growth in average performance of low-, medium-, high-, and a Time of Debt” has been widely cited in the policy very-high-debt countries using two statistics: medi- world for its conclusion that gross debt above 90 per- an and mean average. They emphasize the median cent of gross domestic product (GDP) is associated because it is less sensitive to extremes. In the repli- with lower economic growth. “Growth in a Time of cation paper, however, Herndon et al. do not mention Debt” argues that episodes of high debt tend to last medians; instead, they focus only on mean averages. a long time. The most embarrassing mistake that Reinhart Thomas Herndon and two professors at the and Rogoff made was to exclude five countries from University of Massachusetts attempted to replicate calculations of mean averages.
    [Show full text]
  • C:\Users\John Munro\Documents\Wpdocs\Economistsopinions\Altetnetparramorerogoffreinhart18apt2013
    Alternet Published on Alternet (http://www.alternet.org) Meet the 28-year-old Student Who Exposed Two Harvard Professors Whose Shoddy Research Drove Global Austerity by Lynn Stuart Parramore April 18, 2013 The world of economics has just changed, and somebody has some 'splaining to do! Please savor the following twisted tale of bad math, academic folly and pundit hubris. Since 2010, the names of Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff have become famous in political and economic circles. These two Harvard economists wrote a paper, “Growth in the Time of Debt” that has been used by everyone from Paul Ryan to Olli Rehn of the European Commission to justify harmful austerity policies. The authors purported to show that once a country's gross debt to GDP ratio crosses the threshold of 90 percent, economic growth slows dramatically. Debt, in other words, seemed very scary and bad. Their historical data appeared impressive, as did their credentials. Policy-makers and journalists cited the paper to convince the public that instead of focusing on the jobs crisis that was hampering recovery, we should instead focus on deficits. The deficit hawks jumped up and down with excitement. But something didn’t smell right. Progressive economists I knew were shocked at what appeared to be the shoddiness of the research and the absurdity of the conclusions. In their paper “A World Upside Down? Deficit Fantasies in the Great Recession [3],” Thomas Ferguson and Robert Johnson observed that R&R had truncated their sample of British data in a way that skewed their conclusions, eliminating more than a century of data in which British debt loads exploded but economic growth raced ahead (see pages 11-13).
    [Show full text]
  • Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth?
    Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff Thomas Herndon∗ Michael Ash Robert Pollin April 15, 2013 JEL codes: E60, E62, E65 Abstract We replicate Reinhart and Rogoff (2010a and 2010b) and find that coding errors, selective exclusion of available data, and unconventional weighting of summary statistics lead to serious errors that inaccurately represent the relationship between public debt and GDP growth among 20 advanced economies in the post-war period. Our finding is that when properly calculated, the average real GDP growth rate for countries carrying a public-debt-to-GDP ratio of over 90 percent is actually 2.2 percent, not −0:1 percent as published in Reinhart and Rogoff. That is, contrary to RR, average GDP growth at public debt/GDP ratios over 90 percent is not dramatically different than when debt/GDP ratios are lower. We also show how the relationship between public debt and GDP growth varies significantly by time period and country. Overall, the evidence we review contradicts Reinhart and Rogoff's claim to have identified an important stylized fact, that public debt loads greater than 90 percent of GDP consistently reduce GDP growth. 1 Introduction In \Growth in Time of Debt," Reinhart and Rogoff (hereafter RR 2010a and 2010b) propose a set of \stylized facts" concerning the relationship between public debt and GDP growth. RR's \main result is that whereas the link between growth and debt seems relatively weak ∗Ash is corresponding author, [email protected]. Affiliations at University of Massachusetts Amherst: Herndon, Department of Economics; Ash, Department of Economics and Center for Public Policy and Administration; and Pollin, Department of Economics and Political Economy Research Institute.
    [Show full text]
  • Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? a Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff’, PERI Working Paper No
    Cambridge Journal of Economics Advance Access published December 24, 2013 Cambridge Journal of Economics 2013, 1 of 23 doi:10.1093/cje/bet075 Does high public debt consistently stifle economic growth? A critique of Reinhart Downloaded from and Rogoff Thomas Herndon, Michael Ash and Robert Pollin* http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/ We replicate Reinhart and Rogoff (2010A and 2010B) and find that selective exclu- sion of available data, coding errors and inappropriate weighting of summary sta- tistics lead to serious miscalculations that inaccurately represent the relationship between public debt and GDP growth among 20 advanced economies. Over 1946– 2009, countries with public debt/GDP ratios above 90% averaged 2.2% real annual GDP growth, not −0.1% as published. The published results for (i) median GDP growth rates for the 1946–2009 period and (ii) mean and median GDP growth figures over 1790–2009 are all distorted by similar methodological errors, although the magnitudes of the distortions are somewhat smaller than with the mean figures at Fondation nationale des Sciences Politiques on February 3, 2014 for 1946–2009. Contrary to Reinhart and Rogoff’s broader contentions, both mean and median GDP growth when public debt levels exceed 90% of GDP are not dramatically different from when the public debt/GDP ratios are lower. The rela- tionship between public debt and GDP growth varies significantly by period and country. Our overall evidence refutes RR’s claim that public debt/GDP ratios above 90% consistently reduce a country’s GDP growth. Key words: Public debt, Austerity JEL classifications: E60, E62, E65 1. Introduction In ‘Growth in Time of Debt’, Reinhart and Rogoff (hereafter RR; 2010A for their working paper version and 2010B for their published paper) present a set of what they characterise as ‘stylised facts’ concerning the relationship between public debt and GDP growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Shocking Paper Claims That Microsoft Excel Coding Error Is Behind the Reinhart-Rogoff Study on Debt
    Shocking Paper Claims That Microsoft Excel Coding Error Is Behind The Reinhart-Rogoff Study On Debt businessinsider.fr/us/thomas-herndon-michael-ash-and-robert-pollin-on-reinhart-and-rogoff-2013-4/ In 2010, economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff released a paper, "Growth in a Time of Debt." Their "main result is that...median growth rates for countries with public debt over 90 percent of GDP are roughly one percent lower than otherwise; average (mean) growth rates are several percent lower." Countries with debt-to- GDP ratios above 90 percent have a slightly negative average growth rate, in fact. This has been one of the most cited stats in the public debate during the Great Recession. Paul Ryan's Path to Prosperity budget states their study "found conclusive empirical evidence that [debt] exceeding 90 percent of the economy has a significant negative effect on economic growth." The Washington Post editorial board takes it as an economic consensus view, stating that "debt-to-GDP could keep rising — and stick dangerously near the 90 percent mark that economists regard as a threat to sustainable economic growth." Is it conclusive? One response has been to argue that the causation is backwards, or that slower growth leads to higher debt-to-GDP ratios. Josh Bivens and John Irons made this case at the Economic Policy Institute. But this assumes that the data is correct. From the beginning there have been complaints that Reinhart and Rogoff weren't releasing the data for their results (e.g. Dean Baker). I knew of several people trying to replicate the results who were bumping into walls left and right - it couldn't be done.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt and Growth: a Decade of Studies
    POLICY BRIEF Debt and Growth: A Decade of Studies Veronique de Rugy and Jack Salmon April 2020 In the decade following the financial crisis of 2007–2008 and the subsequent European sovereign debt crisis beginning in late 2009,1 academics and economists have been exploring the relation- ship between government debt and economic growth. For example, in 2010 economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff published their notable paper “Growth in a Time of Debt,”2 which became widely cited and influential among commentators, academics, and politicians in the debate surrounding austerity and fiscal policy in debt-burdened economies. In this policy brief, we review the literature on the debt-growth relationship since the publication of “Growth in a Time of Debt” to evaluate the claim that high government-debt-to-GDP ratios have negative or significant (or both) effects on the growth rate of an economy. In addition, we assess the claim that there is a nonlinear threshold, around 90 percent of GDP, above which debt has a significant deleterious impact on growth rates. With several European countries taking action to successfully reduce their debt-to-GDP ratios in recent years,3 it is important for Americans to broaden their understanding of the potential negative effects of debt on growth potential, par- ticularly in light of America’s current fiscal trajectory. A large majority of studies on the debt-growth relationship find a threshold somewhere between 75 and 100 percent of GDP. More importantly, every study except two finds a negative relation- ship between high levels of government debt and economic growth.
    [Show full text]