Capitalist Crises and the Crisis This Time

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Capitalist Crises and the Crisis This Time CAPITALIST CRISES AND THE CRISIS THIS TIME LEO PANITCH AND SAM GINDIN I xactly a hundred and fifty years before the current crisis began in August E2007, the collapse of the Ohio Life Insurance Company in New York triggered what became known as ‘the great crisis of 1857-8’. As it quickly spread to Europe’s main financial centres, Karl Marx ‘was delighted and thrilled by the prospects for another revolutionary upsurge on the continent’. As Michael Kratke notes, ‘the crisis started exactly as Marx had predicted already in 1850 – with a financial crisis in New York’ and the crisis itself led Marx to extend ‘the scope and scale of his study’ for the Grundrisse notebooks he was working on, so as to take account of ‘the first world economic crisis, affecting all regions of the world’. In their correspondence, Marx and Engels agreed that ‘the crisis was larger and much more severe than any crisis before’, viewing the financial crisis as ‘only the foreplay to the real crisis, the industrial crisis that would affect the very basis of British prosperity and supremacy’.1 In October 1857, Engels wrote to Marx: ‘The American crash is superb and will last for a long time... Now we have a chance’. And two weeks later: ‘…in 1848 we were saying: now our moment is coming, and in a certain sense it was, but this time it is coming completely and it is a case of life or death’.2 As the crisis abated and began to fade away in mid-1858, Marx tried to understand why it had not turned out as expected. He came to the conclusion that the relatively rapid recovery could be largely explained by the sharp depreciation of capital on a large scale and an equally sharp and major shift in the structure of exports from Europe towards the colonies, with this especially applying to British industry which was then so central to global capital accumulation. This allowed for a return to dynamic capitalist growth, while at the same time reproducing the contradictions which, as Marx wrote in the Grundrisse, would lead again to ‘crises in which momentary suspension of all labour and annihilation of a great part of the 2 SOCIALIST REGISTER 2011 capital violently lead it back to the point where it is enabled [to go on] fully employing its productive powers without committing suicide. Yet, these regularly recurring catastrophes lead to their repetition on a higher scale, and finally to its violent overthrow’. Capitalist production, Marx noted, ‘moves in contradictions which are constantly overcome but just as constantly posited’.3 Fifty years later – a full century before the onset of today’s crisis – the great financial crisis of 1907 that also started on Wall Street and included a stock market crash, accelerating runs on the banks and an 11 per cent decline in US GDP, once again quickly spread to ‘an extremely severe monetary and banking crisis such as Europe had not experienced for a long time’.4 But since this crisis was even more short-lived than 1857-8, it provided little fodder for the theories of crises that had become so prevalent in Marxism in the wake of capitalism’s ‘first great depression’ that began in the mid-1870s, and which led Engels in 1884 to speak in terms of the ‘inevitable collapse of the capitalist mode of production which is daily taking place before our eyes’.5 II The Marxist search for a general theory of capitalist crises was intensified in the late 19th century in a context that confirmed deep crisis tendencies in the sphere of production, centred on the contradictions associated with capitalism’s constant drive to accumulation. But this begged the question of why the resultant overaccumulation was sometimes readily corrected and other times not. The appeal of Marx’s identification of a tendency towards a falling rate of profit (FROP), based on the rising organic composition of capital, was partly that it seemed to offer an answer to this, but aside from empirical controversies there was a basic conceptual problem that revolved around the many ‘counter-tendencies’ that were adduced, starting with Marx, to explain why the FROP does not always manifest itself. The problem lay in these counter-tendencies being, as often as not, the very substance of capitalism’s dynamics: i.e., higher rates of class exploitation, the development of new technologies and commodities, the emergence of new markets, international expansion, and innovations in credit provision, not to mention state interventions of various kinds. What the FROP offered in terms of theoretical certainty it lost as an expression of historical materialism. Too often its presentation as an economic law tended to be ahistorical and its materialism tended to be mechanical. The recognition of this was why, at least between the first great depression that ended in the mid-1890s and the even greater one that was triggered at CAPITALIST CRISES AND THE CRISIS THIS TIME 3 the end of the 1920s, the FROP was ‘long neglected or rejected by Marxist theorists’.6 The sense that capitalism had survived the first depression and entered a new stage was ‘a decisive factor in the “crisis of Marxism” which erupted at the end of the century’.7 Labriola’s assessment at the time captured the weakness of mechanical theories of economic breakdown: ‘The ardent, energetic, and precocious hopes of several years ago – have now come up against the more complex resistance of economic relations and the ingenuity of political contrivances’.8 Nevertheless, even though the mid-1890s economic recovery helped foster social democratic evolutionary revisionism, the language of crisis and collapse was never far from earshot in Marxist debates before the First World War. The very prescience with which Marxism in this period theorized inter-imperial rivalry leading to destructive war was now rooted in an expectation that continuing limits to domestic accumulation would drive further the export of capital and the colonization that had come to define the fragmented process of capitalist globalization in the last decades of the 19th century. It is well known that Marxists theorists were influenced in this respect by Hobson’s 1902 classic, Imperialism: A Study, while rejecting his notions, anticipating Keynes, that reformist redistributive measures would solve the domestic underconsumption that spawned external expansion. What is less well known is that Hobson himself was influenced by the writings of US business economists who, in the wake of the deep recession of the early 1890s, drew on Frederick Jackson Turner’s ‘closing of the American frontier’ thesis to argue that the domestic market was no longer able to sustain the enormous productive capacity of the newly-emerged corporate form.9 Their claims were soon to prove wildly wrong. By 1898 the US recession had ended, and home markets continued to dwarf exports. The frontier may have been filled territorially but accumulation within it was only in its very early stages when Turner identified its ‘closing’.10 Marxist crisis theorists at the time not only seriously misinterpreted the kind of capitalism developing in the United States, they more generally underestimated the long-term potential for domestic consumption and accumulation within the leading capitalist states. This was partly due to their failure to appreciate the extent to which working-class industrial and political organizations then emerging would undermine the thesis of the ‘immiseration of the proletariat’. But it was also due to their undeveloped theory of the state, which reduced it to an instrument of capital and underestimated its relative autonomy in relation to both imperial and domestic interventions. This shortcoming was also much in evidence among those Marxist theorists who, 4 SOCIALIST REGISTER 2011 unlike Luxemburg, began not with underconsumptionist tendencies but, like Hilferding, with the implications of the concentration and centralization of capital and the consequent fusion of industry and finance. This, they argued, led to limited competition at home alongside the recruitment of the state to aggressively support expansion abroad, and gave rise not only to the export of capital but also to the politicization of competition among the leading capitalist states – the ultimate outcome being cataclysmic inter- imperial rivalry. As we have argued in these pages before, the penetration and incorporation of the other developed capitalist states by the US imperial state in the second half of the 20th century rendered this old theory of inter-imperial rivalry increasingly anachronistic.11 And even as applied to pre-First World War capitalism, the political economy of underconsumption on the one hand and finance capital on the other was problematic; the understanding of the capitalist state was reductionist; and the explanation of imperial expansion was at best partial. It was ironic that Hilferding’s Finance Capital (1910), so highly influential despite mistakenly generalizing from German developments at the time, actually recognized that it was ‘impossible to derive general laws about the changing character of crises from the history of crises in a single country… [or from] specific phenomena peculiar to a particular phase of capitalism which may perhaps be purely accidental’.12 Many of these limitations in classical Marxist crisis theories have lingered to this day, and helped keep alive the notion that capitalism is in a late, if not quite final, stage. Since the Great Depression of the 1930s, there has especially been a propensity to see a permanent overaccumulation crisis whose consequences have been consistently delayed by special circumstances like war, waste or bubbles. This runs counter to the insight Marx arrived at shortly after the 1857-8 crisis that ‘permanent crises do not exist’, even while insisting that capitalism would repeatedly throw up new crises.13 Indeed, insofar as crises are ‘turning-points’, a very important question for Marxists today, especially given the impasse of the Left in face of the first capitalist crisis of the 21st century, is whether this crisis will also be a turning-point in the way the Left thinks about crises.
Recommended publications
  • Global Issues
    Global Issues Bringing Class Back In* Sam Gindin, Adjunct Professor, York University, Toronto, Canada Over the past three decades a rather astonishing change occurred in the trajectory of capitalist societies. Working class achievements that were formerly seen as examples of capitalism’s success – rising standards of living, growing economic security – were suddenly redefined as ‘problems’. Concessions and permanent insecurity became the new norm, rising inequality the new inevitability. The catch-all term to describe this was ‘neoliberalism’ and Adolph Reed, a prominent US political scientist, nicely summarized its essence as ‘capitalism without a working class opposition.’1 This succinctly highlights the kind of society we get when labour is weak. But more important, it pushes us to confront the limited resistance of labour to that rightward shift since the end of the 1970s. This period did of course witness examples of courageous struggles and moments that brought glimpses of labour’s potentials. In fact, the response of Canadian labour was generally more impressive than elsewhere. Yet given the extent of the assault on working people, labour’s response was too sporadic, too timid, and far too narrow in scope. It’s this failure that I want to discuss – not in any spirit of giving up on unions, but as part of demanding more from this crucial institution. The last time there was as profound an economic breakdown as the recent financial crisis was in the 1930s. The contrast between the labour movement’s current reaction and the earlier one couldn’t be starker. Then, with the predominantly craft-based unions reeling and trapped in exclusive, increasingly bureaucratized structures, a rebellion within the labour movement – with communists playing a prominent role – gave birth to industrial unionism, an inclusive unionism committed to organizing across skills, race and gender.
    [Show full text]
  • Annual Report 2009-2010 Institute for the Humanities Annual Report 2009-2010
    University of manitoba institute for the humanities annual report 2009-2010 institute for the humanities annual report 2009-2010 index Introduction 1 message from the director 1 Publications by the Director 2 Including Director’s 2009-10 Research umih research initiative 2 LGBTTQ Archival & Oral History Initiative the research affiliates 4 Including 2009-10 Affiliate Publications the research clusters 5 Law & Society 5 Power & Resistance in Latin America 5 Jewish Studies Research Circle 7 UMIH on-campus programming 7 UMIH off-campus programming 9 Co-Sponsorships with Other Units 9 graduate student training & outreach 9 Graduate Student Public Talks 10 financial report 2009-10 10 2010-11 Asking Budget 11 Board of Management 11 institute for the humanities 12 UNIVERSITY OF MANITOBA INSTITUTE FOR THE HUMANITIES ANNUAL REPORT 2009-2010 Introduction Throughout the year, the UMIH, with support from the Faculty of Arts, held a number of sessions for new scholars that attempted The constitution of the Institute requires the Director to report to provide an informal space to discuss the challenges of being a annually to the Dean of Arts, the Vice-President (Academic) and new faculty member. These sessions, normally held over lunchtime, Provost, and the Vice-President (Research). It is customary for ranged from discussing teaching and University service, to research this report to be presented annually at the year-end meeting of the potential and possibilities, as well as sources of intellectual and Board of Management. Copies are also distributed on campus to collegial support. We intend to continue this series next year and the President, the Associate Deans of Arts, the Institute’s Board of to reach out to new Faculty who are looking for potential linkages Management, and many supporters who are members of the Uni- for interdisciplinary collaboration.
    [Show full text]
  • Marx's Critique of Ideology: Its Uses and Abuses Keynote Speaker
    Society for Socialist Studies Congress of the Humanities and Social Sciences June 2 – 5, 2015, University of Ottawa http://www.socialiststudies.ca Program, 28 February 2015 Kapital Ideas: analysis, critique, praxis. Kapital Ideas are theories and analyses that help point us toward a better world through critique of the unequal, violent and exploitative one we now inhabit. They take inspiration from the author of Das Kapital, though they range widely over many issues which include ecology and political economy, gender and sexuality, colonization and imperialism, communication and popular struggles, but also movements and parties, hegemony and counter hegemony, governance and globalization and, of course, class struggle and transformation. Kapital Ideas are interventions that contribute to what Marx, in 1843, called the ‘self-clarification of the struggles and wishes of the age.’ In an era of deepening crisis and proliferating struggles, of grave threats and new possibilities, the need for these ideas, and for the praxis they can inform, could not be more acute. Conference Highlights Keynote Address: Marx’s Critique of ideology: its uses and abuses Keynote Speaker: Himani Bannerji, York University Wednesday, 3 June 2015 @ 16:30-18:00 Montpetit Hall 203 Chair: TBA SSS Book Prize Wednesday, 3 June 2015 @ 18:10-19:10 Venue TBA The Rik Davidson/Studies in Political Economy 2014 Book Prize Lecture Leo Panitch and Sam Gindin, York University The Unmaking of Global Capitalism? Tuesday, 2 June 2015 @ 17:30-19:00 Montpetit Hall 201 Chair: TBA Registration TBA Tuesday, 2 June @ 8:30-10:00 a.m. Note: our first sessions begin at 9:00, so register early, or during lunch break.
    [Show full text]
  • Gindin Pamphlet FINAL
    GLOBAL ISSUES: BRINGING CLASS BACK IN Sam Gindin Socialist Interventions Pamphlet Series This pamphlet series is meant to encourage principled debate amongst the left and the working class to advance a viable socialist movement in Canada. Democratic debate is encouraged within and beyond the Socialist Project. 1. Sam Gindin (2004). The Auto Industry: Concretizing Working Class Solidarity: Internationalism Beyond Slogans. 2. Leo Panitch (2005). Whose Violence? Imperial State Security and the Global Justice Movement. 3. Carlos Torres, et al (2005). The Unexpected Revolution: The Venezuelan People Confront Neoliberalism. 4. Hugh Armstrong, et al (2005). Whose Health Care? Challenging the Corporate Struggle to Rule Our System. 5. Labour Committee (2007). The Crisis in Manufacturing Jobs. 6. Richard Roman and Edur Velasco Arregui (2008). The Oaxaca Commune: The Other Indigenous Rebellion in Mexico. 7. Labour Committee - Socialist Project (2008). Labour Movement Platform. 8. Michael A. Lebowitz (2009). The Path to Human Development: Capitalism or Socialism? 9. Socialist Project (2009). Financial Meltdown: Canada, the Economic Crisis and Political Struggle. 10. Marta Harnecker (2010). Ideas for the Struggle. 11 . Angela Joya, et al (2011). The Arab Revolts Against Neoliberal Economies: Confronting Capitalism? 12. Stefan Kipfer, et al. (2012). Free Transit. 13. Greg Albo and Carlo Fanelli (2014). Austerity Against Democracy: An Authoritarian Phase of Neoliberalism? 14. Sam Gindin (2015). Global Issues: Bringing Class Back In To download these pamphlets and to learn more about the Socialist Project, see our website at www.socialistproject.ca Global Issues Bringing Class Back In Making Workers ………………………………. 6 Canadian Exceptionalism ……………………. 11 Disorganizing the Class ………………………. 13 Getting From Here to There ………………….
    [Show full text]
  • The Persistence of American Economic Power in Global Capitalism: from the 1960S Into the Twenty-First Century
    The Persistence of American Economic Power in Global Capitalism: From the 1960s into the Twenty-First Century Sean Kenji Starrs A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF GRADUATE STUDIES IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY GRADUATE PROGRAM IN POLITICAL SCIENCE YORK UNIVERSITY TORONTO, ONTARIO, CANADA June 2014 © Sean Kenji Starrs, 2014 Abstract This dissertation intervenes in the more than four decades-long debate on the decline or persistence of American economic power. It argues that we cannot move forward without reconceptualizing the nature of economic power in global capitalism, especially by moving beyond national accounts (such as GDP). Too many commentators from across the diversity of perspectives assume that the relative rise and decline of national accounts approximates the relative rise and decline of national economic power. In contrast, this dissertation argues that in the era of globalization, national accounts are an inadequate measure of national economic power. Rather, we must investigate the transnational corporations themselves in order to encompass their transnational operations, and analyze the matrix of inter- linkages now characteristic of global capitalism in general, and American power in particular. Therefore, this dissertation draws upon extensive original empirical research, including the following: 1) the first aggregation of the national sales- shares of the world’s top 200 corporations from 1957 to 2013; 2) the first aggregation of the national profit-shares of the world’s top 2,000 corporations across 25 broad sectors from 2006 to 2013; 3) the first aggregation of the top 50 national acquirers and targets of all cross-border mergers and acquisitions worth $1 million or more from 1980 to 2012; and 4) the first national aggregation of the ownership structures of the world’s top 500 corporations.
    [Show full text]
  • The Making of Global Capitalism
    Contents Preface vii INTRODUCTION 1 PART I: PRELUDE TO THE NEW AMERICAN EMPIRE . The DNA of American Capitalism 25 The Dynamic Economy 26 The Active State 31 Internationalizing the American State 35 . American State Capacities: From Great War to New Deal 45 From Wilson to Hoover: Isolationism Not 46 The Great Depression and the New Deal State 53 From New Deal to Grand Truce with Capital 59 PART II: THE PROJECT FOR A GLOBAL CAPITALISM . Planning the New American Empire 67 Internationalizing the New Deal 69 The Path to Bretton Woods 72 Laying the Domestic Foundations 80 . Launching Global Capitalism 89 Evolving the Marshall Plan 91 The American Rescue of European Capitalism 96 “The Rest of the World” 102 PART III: THE TRANSITION TO GLOBAL CAPITALISM . The Contradictions of Success 111 Internationalizing Production 112 Internationalizing Finance 117 Detaching from Bretton Woods 122 . Structural Power Through Crisis 133 Class, Profi ts, and Crisis 135 Transition through Crisis 144 Facing the Crisis Together 152 PART IV: THE REALIZATION OF GLOBAL CAPITALISM . Renewing Imperial Capacity 163 The Path to Discipline 164 The New Age of Finance 172 The Material Base of Empire 183 . Integrating Global Capitalism 195 Integrating Europe 196 Japan’s Contradictions of Success 203 The Rest of the World (Literally) 211 PART V: THE RULE OF GLOBAL CAPITALISM . Rules of Law: Governing Globalization 223 The Laws of Free Trade 224 Global Investment, American Rules 230 Disciplinary Internationalism 234 . The New Imperial Challenge: Managing Crises 247 Firefi ghter in Chief 248 The Asian Contagion 254 Failure Containment 261 PART VI: THE GLOBAL CAPITALIST MILLENNIUM .
    [Show full text]
  • GLOBAL CAPITALISM and AMERICAN EMPIRE Leo Panitch
    1 GLOBAL CAPITALISM AND AMERICAN EMPIRE Leo Panitch and Sam Gindin ‘American imperialism… has been made plausible and attractive in part by the insistence that it is not imperialistic.’ 1 Harold Innis, 1948 Este material aparecerá publicado en Socialist Register del 2004, y la revista nos autorizó a divulgarlo durante seis meses en la web Cuba Siglo XXI The American empire is no longer concealed. In March 1999, the cover of the New York Times Magazine displayed a giant clenched fist painted in the stars and stripes of the US flag above the words: ‘What The World Needs Now: For globalization to work, America can’t be afraid to act like the almighty superpower that it is’. Thus was featured Thomas Friedman’s ‘Manifesto for a Fast World’, which urged the United States to embrace its role as enforcer of the capitalist global order: ‘…the hidden hand of the market will never work without a hidden fist.... The hidden fist that keeps the world safe for Silicon Valley’s technologies is called the United States Army, Air Force, Navy and Marine Corps.’ Four years later, in January 2003, when there was no longer any point in pretending the fist was hidden, the Magazine featured an essay by Michael Ignatieff entitled ‘The Burden’: ‘…[W]hat word but “empire” describes the awesome thing that America is becoming? …Being an imperial power… means enforcing such order as there is in the world and doing so in the American interest.’2 The words, ‘The American Empire: (Get Used To It)’, took up the whole cover of the Magazine.
    [Show full text]
  • The Stagflation of the 1970S Начало Падения Америки
    Vestnik RUDN. International Relations 2021 Vol. 21 No. 2 243—251 http://journals.rudn.ru/international‐relations Вестник РУДН. Серия: МЕЖДУНАРОДНЫЕ ОТНОШЕНИЯ DOI: 10.22363/2313-0660-2021-21-2-243-251 Research article / Научная статья Prelude to America’s Downfall: The Stagflation of the 1970s Vassilis K. Fouskas 1 University of East London, London, Great Britain [email protected] Abstract. Since the end of the Bretton Woods system and the stagflation of the 1970s, the transatlantic core, under the leadership of the United States of America, has been trying to expand its model of free market capitalism embracing every part of the globe, while addressing its domestic overaccumulation crisis. This article follows a historical methodological perspective and draws from the concept of Uneven and Combined Development (UCD), which helps us consider the structural reasons behind the long and protracted decline of the American economic power. In this respect, according to the UCD concept, there is no global power that can enjoy the privilege for being at the top of the global capitalist system forever in a world which develops unevenly and in a combined way. Power shifts across the world and new powers come to challenge the current hegemonic power and its alliance systems. The novelty of the article is that it locates this decline in the 1970s and considers it as being consubstantial with the state economic policy of neo-liberalism and financialisation (supply-side economics). However the financialised capitalism of the transatlantic assemblage lack industrial base producing, reproducing and recycling real commodity values. Further, the article shows that this attempt to remain at the top of the global capitalist system forever has not been successful, not least because the regime which the recovery of the core had rested upon, that of neo-liberal financialisation represents a major vulnerability of the transatlantic assemblage eroding the primacy of the United States of America in it.
    [Show full text]
  • University of Manitoba Department of Economics
    University of Manitoba Department of Economics Economics 7690 Structuralist Theories of Development John Loxley Fall 2013 505 Fletcher Argue 474-9769 e-mail, [email protected] Objectives To acquaint students with competing non-orthodox theories of development and their evolution over time. The course will begin with a review of the main currents in orthodox theories of, and approaches to, development economics. It will then consider a variety of alternative approaches beginning with Latin American structuralism and its differences from ‘Anglo-Saxon’ structuralism. The debates about the original transition to capitalism will then be examined as will the Japanese transition which differed significantly from that in Europe. This will be followed by analysis of Marx’s writings on colonialism and their validity, as a segué into Neo-Marxian theories and the Staple Theory (as applied to Canadian and Aboriginal economic development). Feminist and ecological theories of development will also be studied. Theoretical issues in contemporary capitalism and the new imperialism will be addressed, as will the debates about structural adjustment and its role in the neo-liberal re-shaping of the global economy. The reasons behind the growing power of India and China will also be looked at. Post-development theory will be appraised critically. Other possible topics will be the role of institutions in development, contemporary debates about the role of aid, the nature and role of social capital, sustainable livelihoods and social inclusion. Where appropriate, the course will examine the strategies of development which appear to follow logically from the various theories. It will emphasise the richness of debate within the literature and highlight the principal issues which remain controversial or unresolved.
    [Show full text]
  • The Crisis and Economic Alternatives
    THE CRISIS AND ECONOMIC ALTERNATIVES GREG ALBO ince 2008, the world market has been wracked by a degree of economic Sturbulence unusual in its scope, depth and duration. Although uneven in its recessionary impacts, no corner of the global economy has been untouched by this. In the central economies of North America, Japan and Europe, this period has been universally demarcated as a ‘major crisis’, comparable to the ‘great depressions’ of the late nineteenth century and the 1930s and the stagflation of the 1970s. Even as the crisis now presses into its fifth year, economic prospects remain highly uncertain. In cataloguing obstacles to a renewal of economic growth in various parts of the world, the July 2012 IMF World Economic Outlook observes, with a tone of understatement, that ‘the global recovery, which was not so strong to begin with, has shown further signs of weakness’.1 As in other major turning points in the history of capitalism, powerful forces for restructuring the state and the economy have been set in motion. From both sides of the political spectrum, governments have been falling like dominos. In Italy and Greece, ‘technocratic governments’ were struck while in others something like a ‘common front’ formed between centre- right and social democratic parties to back the bailouts of the financial system and secure long-term policies of ‘fiscal consolidation’ (read austerity). This has kept even more interventionist economic policies within the parameters of ‘exceptional monetarism’ (along the lines advocated by Ben Bernanke of the US Federal Reserve), thereby seeking a balance between fiscal austerity and the ‘quantitative easing’ of monetary policy and debt consolidation to stabilize the financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • SOCI 501 Capitalism Socialism Democracy Syllabus Winter 2020
    DEPARTMENT OF SOCIOLOGY SOCI 501: Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy Winter Semester 2020 Meeting Times: Professor: Barry Eidlin Tuesdays 8:35-10:25 ([email protected]) Location: Leacock 819 Office: Leacock 820 Office Hours: Tue. 10:45-12:45 COURSE OBJECTIVES While this course has only recently come to McGill, it arrives with a storied history. It was originally developed in the early 20th century at the University of Wisconsin–Madison by the pioneering labour economist John R. Commons, who passed it down to his student Selig Perlman, also a labour economist of considerable renown. After World War II, the famous German emigré sociologist Hans Gerth, known for his translations of the works of Max Weber, took it over. Perlman’s lectures for this course have been published as Selig Perlman's Lectures on Capitalism and Socialism (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1976). The course was originally designed to explore the distinctive, some would say “exceptional,” U.S. political and economic landscape, and how it came to be that way. While it is a landscape that has fostered historically unprecedented levels of economic growth and prosperity for some, it has also led to levels of poverty and inequality that are unmatched among comparable countries. In this redesigned version of the course, we will be enriching this analysis of American exceptionalism by comparing the U.S. with Canada. While both countries are similar in many ways, they have important differences when it comes to politics and social policy. Exploring and explaining why those differences exist can help us better understand both countries.
    [Show full text]
  • In and out of Crisis
    IN AND OUT OF CRISIS The Global Financial Meltdown and Left Alternatives Leo Panitch, Sam Gindin, and Greg Albo Our world is in the grips of the most calamitous economic crisis since the Great Depression—and its epicenter is the imperial United States, where hallowed investment banks have disappeared overnight, giants of industry have gone bankrupt, and the financial order has been shaken to the core. While many around the globe are increasingly wondering if another world is indeed possible, few are mapping out potential avenues—and flagging wrong turns—en route to a post-capitalist future. In this groundbreaking analysis of the meltdown, renowned radical political economists Albo, Gindin and Panitch lay bare the roots of the crisis, which they locate in the dynamic expansion of capital on a global scale over the last quarter century—and in the inner logic of capitalism itself. With an unparalleled understanding of the inner workings of capitalism, the authors of In and Out of Crisis provocatively challenge the call by much of the Left for a return to a largely mythical Golden Age of economic regulation as a check on finance capital unbound. They deftly illuminate how the era of neoliberal free markets has been, in practice, undergirded by state intervention on a massive scale. With clarity and erudition, they argue persuasively that given the current balance of social forces—as bank bailouts SUBJECT CATEGORY around the globe make evident—regulation is not a means of fundamentally PoLITICS/ activISm/ reordering power in society, but rather a way of preserving markets. EConomICS Contrary to those who believe US hegemony is on the wane, Albo, Gindin PRICE and Panitch contend that the meltdown has, in fact, reinforced the centrality $13.95 of the American state as the dominant force within global capitalism, while simultaneously increasing the difficulties entailed in managing its imperial role.
    [Show full text]