Trade Theory and Trade Facts∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Trade Theory and Trade Facts∗ Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 284 March 2001 (First version October 1999) Trade Theory and Trade Facts∗ Raphael Bergoeing ILADES-Georgetown University, Universidad Alberto Hurtado Timothy J. Kehoe University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis ABSTRACT This paper quantitatively tests the “new trade theory” based on product differentiation, increasing returns, and imperfect competition. We employ a standard model, which allows both changes in the distribution of income among industrialized countries, emphasized by Helpman and Krugman (1985), and nonhomothetic preferences, emphasized by Markusen (1986), to effect trade directions and volumes. In addition, we generalize the model to allow changes in relative prices to have large effects. We test the model by calibrating it to 1990 data and then “backcasting” to 1961 to see what changes in crucial variables between 1961 and 1990 are predicted by the theory. The results show that, although the model is capable of explaining much of the increased concentration of trade among industrialized countries, it is not capable of explaining the enormous increase in the ratio of trade to income. Our analysis suggests that it is policy changes, rather than the elements emphasized in the new trade theory, that have been the most significant determinants of the increase in trade volume. ∗ c 2001, Raphael Bergoeing and Timothy J. Kehoe. This paper grew out of the Bergoeing’s 1996 Ph.D. thesis at° the University of Minnesota. The authors thank the McKnight Foundation and the National Science Foundation for financial support. Useful comments and suggestions have been provided by participants in numerous seminars and conferences, especially Caroline Betts, Harold Cole, Barbara Craig, Patrick Kehoe, David Hummels, Robert Lucas, Moshe Syrquin, Nancy Stokey, and Jaume Ventura. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. 1. Introduction This paper investigates the extent to which the “new trade theory” can quantitatively match some of the facts that it was designed to explain. It does so by calibrating a standard model,basedonMarkusen(1986), to 1990 data and then “backcasting” to 1961 to see what changes in crucial variables between 1961 and 1990 are predicted by the theory. Thenewtradetheory,developedbyresearcherslikeHelpman(1981), Krugman (1979), and Lancaster (1980) in the late 1970s and 1980s, was motivated by the failure of more traditional theories to explain some of the most significant facts about post World War II trade data. As Deardorff (1984) and Helpman and Krugman (1985) explain, the new trade theory was designed to account for three major facts: The ratio of trade to income has increased. • Trade has become more concentrated among industrialized countries. • Trade among industrialized countries has been largely intraindustry trade. • Figure 1 presents evidence for the first fact, showing how much faster world trade has increased than world income. To make comparisons easy in the figure, data on both world trade volume, measured by summing up exports throughout the world, and world income have been expressed as indices where 1950=100. Over the period 1950-1990, the ratio of trade to income worldwide increases by 86.1 percent. The data for both trade and income used to derive the indices in Figure 1 are measured in constant 1970 U.S. dollars. Alternatively, we could look at trade as a fraction of income, dividing the current value of trade by the current value of income. As a fraction of the value of GDP, the value of trade increased from 7.9 percent in 1950 to 15.4 percent in 1990, a 94.9 percent increase. To make the second fact precise, we identify industrialized countries with the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), which was formed in 1961. Figure 2 shows how much faster trade within the OECD has increased than OECD trade with the rest of the world. The ratio of OECD-OECD trade to OECD-RW trade went from 0.84 in 1961 to 1.58 in 1990. Evidence for the third fact can be found in the high Grubel-Lloyd indices of international trade in industrialized countries. For this sort of data it is more difficult to calculate long time series. In 1990 though, Grubel-Lloyd indices based on two-digit SITC data from the OECD say that 68.4 percent of OECD-OECD trade was intraindustry compared with only 38.1 percent of OECD-RW trade. Closely related to the first two facts is yet a fourth fact: The ratio of trade to income withintheOECDincreasedevenfasterthantheratiooftradetoincomeworldwide. Figure3 presents the relevant data. Trade within the OECD went from 5.3 percent of OECD income in 1961 to 11.2 percent in 1990. The ratio of trade to income within the OECD increased by 111.5 percent. By comparison the United Nations data say that the ratio of trade to income worldwide increased by only 59.3 percent over 1961-1990. That the new trade theory was developed to explain these facts is explicit in textbook expositions by the developers of the theory. Helpman and Krugman (1985), for example, point out that conventional trade models like the Ricardian model and the Heckscher-Ohlin model cannot hope to explain these facts and go on to say, These ... empirical weaknesses of conventional trade theory ... become under- standable once economies of scale and imperfect competition are introduced into our analysis. 2 Helpman and Krugman stress the changes in the distribution of income among industrialized countries as a major cause of the expansion of trade relative to income. In the early post war period the United States accounted for much of the world’s income and consumption. As the distribution of national income became more equal, their model predicts that trade volumes should rise. Focusing on the increase in trade among industrialized countries, Markusen (1986) stresses unequal income elasticity of demands that result from nonhomothetic preferences. If demand for differentiated products is superior to that for homogeneous products, then intraindustry trade should expand as income rises; and, if industrialized countries are net ex- porters of these differentiated products, then intraindustry trade among industrialized coun- tries should expand faster than other trade. As Markusen et al. (1995) point out, it was to match the facts listed above that the theory had been formulated: Thus, nonhomogeneous demand leads to a decrease in North-South trade and to an increase in [intraindustry trade] among the northern industrialized countries. These are precisely the facts there were to be explained. Our model generalizes those developed by Helpman and Krugman (1985) and Markusen (1986) in that it allows changes in relative prices to have large effects on trade volumes. Be- cause of faster total factor productivity growth in the manufacturing sector, the relative prices of manufactured goods have fallen sharply from 1961 to 1990 compared to the prices of primary goods and services. Our numerical experiments show that, although the model can explain the increased concentration of trade among industrialized countries, it is not capable of explaining the 3 enormous increase in the ratio of trade to income. The simple fact is that it has been the trade of manufactured goods among OECD countries that accounts for most of the expansion of trade over the period 1961-1990. Over this same period, however, the consumption of manufactures in these countries has gone down as a fraction of income. A model that relies on the taste for variety approach developed by Spence (1976) and Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) links increases in trade to increases in consumption. It seems that it is policy changes, rather than the elements emphasized in the new trade theory, that have been the most significant determinants of the increase in trade volume. In related literature, Hunter (1991) estimates that nonhomothetic preferences accounts for about one fourth of observed interindustry trade. Helpman (1987) reports regression results that he interprets as support for the Helpman-Krugman explanation of the distribution of national income as the driving force behind trade increases. Hummels and Levinsohn (1995), however, argue that Helpman’s results are not related to the Helpman-Krugman theory. Haveman and Hummels (1999) argue that the new trade theory models rely on taste for variety that is not consistent with the data and predict too much trade. Yi (1999) argues that the new trade theory models cannot account for the increase in trade unless they incorporate changes in both trade policy and international vertical integration. It is worth noting that lack of data on trade in services in 1961 forces us to restrict our attention to merchandise trade in both our data analysis and in our theory. Information on sources for all of the data presented in this paper are included in the data appendix. 4 2. A “New Trade Theory” Model Consider a world in which there are n developed countries, identified with the 23 countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) in 1990, and a rest of the world. (There were actually 24 countries in the OECD in 1990, but, since data for Belgium and Luxembourg are aggregated together, we treat them as one country.) Table 1 OECD in 1990 Country Share of Income (percent) Australia 1.3209 Austria 0.7153 Belgium/Luxembourg 0.9254 Canada 2.5475 Denmark 0.5791 Finland 0.6046 France 5.3609 Germany 7.3549 Greece 0.3718 Iceland 0.0280 Ireland 0.2042 Italy 4.9059 Japan 13.3195 Netherlands 1.2721 New Zealand 0.1933 Norway 0.5177 Portugal 0.3027 Spain 2.2189 Sweden 1.0304 Switzerland 0.1274 Turkey 0.6757 United Kingdom 4.3747 United States 24.9076 In each country or region, there are three types of goods, a primary good that is tradable and homogeneous, manufactured goods that are tradable and differentiated by the firm that produces them, and a service good that is nontradable and homogeneous within the 5 country where it is produced.
Recommended publications
  • Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics After World War I
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER June 2018 Working Paper 2018-06 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2018/06/ Suggested citation: Lopez, Jose A., Kris James Mitchener. 2018. “Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2018-06. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2018-06 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER* May 9, 2018 ABSTRACT. Fiscal deficits, elevated debt-to-GDP ratios, and high inflation rates suggest hyperinflation could have potentially emerged in many European countries after World War I. We demonstrate that economic policy uncertainty was instrumental in pushing a subset of European countries into hyperinflation shortly after the end of the war. Germany, Austria, Poland, and Hungary (GAPH) suffered from frequent uncertainty shocks – and correspondingly high levels of uncertainty – caused by protracted political negotiations over reparations payments, the apportionment of the Austro-Hungarian debt, and border disputes. In contrast, other European countries exhibited lower levels of measured uncertainty between 1919 and 1925, allowing them more capacity with which to implement credible commitments to their fiscal and monetary policies.
    [Show full text]
  • The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers
    Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee Volume 9 Issue 1 Article 7 July 2019 The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers Jenna Demeter The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit Part of the Business Administration, Management, and Operations Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Economic History Commons, Gender and Sexuality Commons, Growth and Development Commons, Income Distribution Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Inequality and Stratification Commons, International and Comparative Labor Relations Commons, International Economics Commons, International Relations Commons, International Trade Law Commons, Labor and Employment Law Commons, Labor Economics Commons, Latin American Studies Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Macroeconomics Commons, Political Economy Commons, Politics and Social Change Commons, Public Economics Commons, Regional Economics Commons, Rural Sociology Commons, Unions Commons, and the Work, Economy and Organizations Commons Recommended Citation Demeter, Jenna (2019) "The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers," Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee: Vol. 9 : Iss. 1 , Article 7. Available at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit/vol9/iss1/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by
    [Show full text]
  • Study Abroad for Economic Majors PSU Allows Students to Participate
    Study Abroad for Economic Majors PSU allows students to participate in any study abroad program that is good for them – the following are only suggestions. Short Term: PSU short term faculty-led programs change from year to year. Keep an eye out for posters and announcements in your classes to learn about short term faculty led programs. K-State and KU and other universities’ short term study abroad programs are open to PSU students. These also change from year to year. Summer Programs available through PSU’s affiliate organizations: (deadline to apply – March 1st for summer abroad): API – most courses taught in English – http://www.apistudyabroad.com/ • England – London: Introductory Macroeconomics, Essential Statistics for Economics and Econometrics, Intermediate Macroeconomics, Introduction to Econometrics, Public Finance, Development Economics, International Economics IFSA Butler – most courses taught in English – www.ifsa-butler.org • England – Cambridge: Introduction to Finance and Methods of Quantitative Analysis, Financial Markets and Institutions • England – Sussex: Global Economic Issues, Introduction to Development Economics, Corporate Finance - Financial Strategic Planning GlobaLinks – most courses taught in English – globalinksabroad.org • Australia – Adelaide: East Asian Economies II, Sports Economics III, Semester Programs: (deadline to apply October 1st for spring abroad, March 1st for fall abroad): Exchange Partner Universities: Finland: University of Oulu – http://www.oulu.fi/english/studentexchange/studying Classes
    [Show full text]
  • Underdevelopment and Unregulated Markets: Seven Reasons Why Unregulated Markets Reproduce Underdevelopment
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Herr, Hansjörg Working Paper Underdevelopment and unregulated markets: Seven reasons why unregulated markets reproduce underdevelopment Working Paper, No. 103/2018 Provided in Cooperation with: Berlin Institute for International Political Economy (IPE) Suggested Citation: Herr, Hansjörg (2018) : Underdevelopment and unregulated markets: Seven reasons why unregulated markets reproduce underdevelopment, Working Paper, No. 103/2018, Hochschule für Wirtschaft und Recht Berlin, Institute for International Political Economy (IPE), Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/178653 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Key words: underdevelopment, financial system, free trade, inequality, Keynesian paradigm, Washington Consensus. JEL classification: B50, F40, O11 Contact: Hansjörg Herr email: [email protected] 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade and Employment Challenges for Policy Research
    ILO - WTO - ILO TRADE AND EMPLOYMENT CHALLENGES FOR POLICY RESEARCH This study is the outcome of collaborative research between the Secretariat of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the TRADE AND EMPLOYMENT International Labour Office (ILO). It addresses an issue that is of concern to both organizations: the relationship between trade and employment. On the basis of an overview of the existing academic CHALLENGES FOR POLICY RESEARCH literature, the study provides an impartial view of what can be said, and with what degree of confidence, on the relationship between trade and employment, an often contentious issue of public debate. Its focus is on the connections between trade policies, and labour and social policies and it will be useful for all those who are interested in this debate: academics and policy-makers, workers and employers, trade and labour specialists. WTO ISBN 978-92-870-3380-2 A joint study of the International Labour Office ILO ISBN 978-92-2-119551-1 and the Secretariat of the World Trade Organization Printed by the WTO Secretariat - 813.07 TRADE AND EMPLOYMENT CHALLENGES FOR POLICY RESEARCH A joint study of the International Labour Office and the Secretariat of the World Trade Organization Prepared by Marion Jansen Eddy Lee Economic Research and Statistics Division International Institute for Labour Studies World Trade Organization International Labour Office TRADE AND EMPLOYMENT: CHALLENGES FOR POLICY RESEARCH Copyright © 2007 International Labour Organization and World Trade Organization. Publications of the International Labour Office and World Trade Organization enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention. Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated.
    [Show full text]
  • Models of International Economics - Giancarlo Gandolfo
    MATHEMATICAL MODELS IN ECONOMICS –- Vol. II – Models of International Economics - Giancarlo Gandolfo MODELS OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Giancarlo Gandolfo Sapienza University of Rome, Italy, and Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, Rome Keywords: Absorption, balance of payments, comparative cost, factor endowments, flow approaches, Heckscher-Ohlin model, international finance, international trade, international monetary economics, intertemporal approach, non tariff barriers, open economy macroeconomics, optimum tariff, political economy of protectionism, Ricardo, stock approaches, tariffs, trade policy, Walras’ law. Contents 1. Introduction 2. Models of International Trade 2.1. The Orthodox Theory 2.2. Generalizations 2.3. Trade Policy 2.4. The New Theories 2.5. Further Developments 3. Models of International Monetary Economics 3.1. The Basic Models 3.2. Stock Approaches 3.3. The Intertemporal Model 3.4. Models of the Exchange Rate 3.5. Currency Crises and Other Problems Acknowledgements Glossary Bibliography Biographical Sketch Summary The importance of international economics is increasing, owing to the increasing openness of UNESCOthe single national economic system– s:EOLSS on average, at the world level more than 28% of national income is spent on foreign commodities and services. A feature of current international exchanges with respect to those of the past is that exchanges of financial assets have been growing much more rapidly than exchanges of commodities. Moreover, theseSAMPLE financial exchanges, once an cillaryCHAPTERS to commodity trade, have taken on an autonomous importance and are far greater than the value of exchanges of commodities. This situation is also reflected in the theoretical models, which -once mostly concerned with the theory of commercial flows- have had to cope with the theory of financial and macroeconomic flows in an open macroeconomy.
    [Show full text]
  • Standard Theory (Hybrid Heckscher-Ohlin/New Trade Theory) Does Not Well When Matched with the Data on the Growth and Composition of Trade
    Standard theory (hybrid Heckscher-Ohlin/New Trade Theory) does not well when matched with the data on the growth and composition of trade. In the 1980s and 1990s trade economists reached a consensus that North-North trade — trade among rich countries — was driven by forces captured by the New Trade Theory and North-South trade — trade between rich countries and poor countries — was driven by forces captured by Heckscher-Ohlin theory. (South-South trade was negligible.) A. V. Deardorff, “Testing Trade Theories and Predicting Trade Flows,” in R. W. Jones and P. B. Kenen, editors, Handbook of International Economics, volume l, North-Holland, 1984, 467-517. J. Markusen, “Explaining the Volume of Trade: An Eclectic Approach,” American Economic Review, 76 (1986), 1002-1011. In fact, a calibrated version of this hybrid model does not match the data. R. Bergoeing and T. J. Kehoe, “Trade Theory and Trade Facts,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2003. TRADE THEORY Traditional trade theory — Ricardo, Heckscher-Ohlin — says countries trade because they are different. In 1990 by far the largest bilateral trade relation in the world was U.S.-Canada. The largest two-digit SITC export of the United States to Canada was 78 Road Vehicles. The largest two-digit SITC export of Canada to the United States was 78 Road Vehicles. The New Trade Theory — increasing returns, taste for variety, monopolistic competition — explains how similar countries can engage in a lot of intraindustry trade. Helpman and Krugman (1985) Markusen (1986) TRADE THEORY AND TRADE FACTS • Some recent trade facts • A “New Trade Theory” model • Accounting for the facts • Intermediate goods? • Policy? How important is the quantitative failure of the New Trade Theory? Where should trade theory and applications go from here? SOME RECENT TRADE FACTS • The ratio of trade to product has increased.
    [Show full text]
  • Hyperinflation in Venezuela
    POLICY BRIEF recovery can be possible without first stabilizing the explo- 19-13 Hyperinflation sive price level. Doing so will require changing the country’s fiscal and monetary regimes. in Venezuela: A Since late 2018, authorities have been trying to control the price spiral by cutting back on fiscal expenditures, contracting Stabilization domestic credit, and implementing new exchange rate poli- cies. As a result, inflation initially receded from its extreme Handbook levels, albeit to a very high and potentially unstable 30 percent a month. But independent estimates suggest that prices went Gonzalo Huertas out of control again in mid-July 2019, reaching weekly rates September 2019 of 10 percent, placing the economy back in hyperinflation territory. Instability was also reflected in the premium on Gonzalo Huertas was research analyst at the Peterson Institute foreign currency in the black market, which also increased for International Economics. He worked with C. Fred Bergsten in July after a period of relative calm in previous months. Senior Fellow Olivier Blanchard on macroeconomic theory This Policy Brief describes a feasible stabilization plan and policy. Before joining the Institute, Huertas worked as a researcher at Harvard University for President Emeritus and for Venezuela’s extreme inflation. It places the country’s Charles W. Eliot Professor Lawrence H. Summers, producing problems in context by outlining the economics behind work on fiscal policy, and for Minos A. Zombanakis Professor Carmen Reinhart, focusing on exchange rate interventions. hyperinflations: how they develop, how they disrupt the normal functioning of economies, and how other countries Author’s Note: I am grateful to Adam Posen, Olivier Blanchard, across history have designed policies to overcome them.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. Falling International Trade Costs
    II D TRADE,THELOCATIONOFPRODUCTIONANDTHEINDUSTRIALORGANIZATIONOFFIRMS DTRADE, THE LOCATION OF PRODUCTION AND THE INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION OF FIRMS Section C has explored the possible reasons why A common denominator in both these phenomena countries trade and highlighted how different is the role of trade costs. Reduction in trade costs modelling approaches, based on comparative can be an important cause of both agglomeration advantages or on economies of scale, explain and fragmentation. But the extent to which they are different types of trade: inter-industry trade among compatible has not yet been explored in economic different countries and intra-industry trade among literature. On the one hand, the new economic similar countries. Traditional trade models and the geography literature predicts that a fall in trade so-called “new” trade theory models can predict costs will lead to an initially greater geographical which countries will specialize in the production of concentration of production and a subsequent certain goods and how many varieties of the same reduction of concentration as trade costs fall to a product they will exchange. However, they cannot sufficiently low level. On the other hand, recent predict the location decisions of firms. Further, theories of fragmentation predict that a reduction they assume that production takes place within the in trade costs will lead to greater fragmentation of boundaries of the firm. Therefore, they can neither production, with firms geographically spreading the explain why production is not randomly distributed different stages of their production process. Much in in space nor what determines the decision of a firm the same way as high trade costs in trading final goods to outsource.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 New Trade Theory
    Increasing Returns to Scale 1 New Trade Theory According to traditional trade theories (Ricardian, spe- ci…c factors and HOS models), trade occurs due to exist- ing comparative advantage between countries (technol- ogy, factor endowment di¤erences). Empirical data shows a signi…cant amount of trade occurs between similar countries, countries with similar technol- ogy and similar factor endowments. With little di¤erence to exploit, these countries should have little to gain from trade, yet seem to have prospered from trading with each other. Given this “unexplainable” portion of trade, trade theo- rists began to look for other reasons for trade, reasons where trade could occur between similar countries and yield sizable gains from trade. The shift in emphasis from looking for reasons for trade to occur between di¤erent countries to looking for reasons for trade to occur between similar countries marks the break between the traditional (old) trade theory and the new trade theory. Newer theories still generally can be interpreted as having trade stem from some type of comparative advantage, but the source of comparative advantage is more subtle, and sometimes does not even existent in autarky, but develops with the opening up to trade. The hallmark of the new theories is that one can construct a scenario where exactly identical countries will trade with each other. Some of the new reasons for trade are increasing re- turns to scale (IRS), imperfect competition (especially oligopoly), and di¤erentiated goods (variety or quality). As we study each of these models, ask: 1. What failures of the traditional theory motivated construction of this model? 2.
    [Show full text]
  • 14.581 Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition: Theory
    14.581 MIT PhD International Trade – Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory) – Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Today’s Plan 1 Introduction to “New” Trade Theory 2 Monopolistically Competitive Models 1 Krugman (JIE, 1979) 2 Helpman and Krugman (1985 book) 3 Krugman (AER, 1980) 3 From “New” Trade Theory to Economic Geography “New” Trade Theory What ’s wrong with neoclassical trade theory? In a neoclassical world, differences in relative autarky prices– due to • differences in technology, factor endowments, or preferences– are the only rationale for trade. This suggests that: • 1 “Different” countries should trade more. 2 “Different” countries should specialize in “different” goods. In the real world, however, we observe that: • 1 The bulk of world trade is between “similar” countries. 2 These countries tend to trade “similar” goods. “New” Trade Theory Why Increasing Returns to Scale (IRTS)? “New” Trade Theory proposes IRTS as an alternative rationale for • international trade and a potential explanation for the previous facts. Basic idea: • 1 Because of IRTS, similar countries will specialize in different goods to take advantage of large-scale production, thereby leading to trade. 2 Because of IRTS, countries may exchange goods with similar factor content. In addition, IRTS may provide new source of gains from trade if it • induces firms to move down their average cost curves. “New” Trade Theory How to model increasing returns to scale? 1 External economies of scale Under perfect competition, multiple equilibria and possibilities of losses • from trade (Ethier, Etca 1982). Under Bertrand competition, many of these features disappear • (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg, QJE 2009).
    [Show full text]
  • Oecd Development Centre
    OECD DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Working Paper No. 16 (Formerly Technical Paper No. 16) COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: THEORY AND APPLICATION TO DEVELOPING COUNTRY AGRICULTURE by Ian Goldin Research programme on: Changing Comparative Advantage in Food and Agriculture June 1990 TABLE OF CONTENTS SUMMARY . 9 PREFACE . 11 INTRODUCTION . 13 PART ONE . 14 COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: THE THEORY . 14 The Theory of Comparative Advantage . 14 Testing the theory . 15 The Theory and Agriculture . 16 PART TWO . 19 COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE: THE PRACTICE . 19 Costs and Prices . 19 Land, Labour and Capital . 20 Joint Products . 22 Cost Studies . 22 Engineering Cost Studies . 23 Revealed Comparative Advantage . 25 Trade Liberalisation Simulations . 26 Domestic Resource Cost Analysis . 29 PART THREE . 32 COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE AND DEVELOPING COUNTRY AGRICULTURE . 32 Comparative Advantage and Economic Growth . 32 Conclusion . 33 NOTES . 35 BIBLIOGRAPHICAL REFERENCES . 36 7 SUMMARY This paper investigates the application of the principle of comparative advantage to policy analysis and policy formulation. It is concerned with both the theory and the measurement of comparative advantage. Despite its central role in economics, the theory is found to be at an impasse, with its usefulness confined mainly to the illustration of economic principles which in practice are not borne out by the evidence. The considerable methodological problems associated with the measurement of comparative advantage are highlighted in the paper. Attempts to derive indicators of comparative advantage, such as those associated with "revealed comparative advantage", "direct resource cost", "production cost" and "trade liberalisation" studies are reviewed. These methods are enlightening, but are unable to provide general perspectives which allow an analysis of dynamic comparative advantage.
    [Show full text]