CryptoRuble: From Russia with Love

Zura Kakushadze§¶1 and Jim Kyung-Soo Liew†‡2

§ Quantigic® Solutions LLC,3 1127 High Ridge Road, #135, Stamford, CT 06905

¶ Free University of Tbilisi, Business School & School of Physics 240, David Agmashenebeli Alley, Tbilisi, 0159, Georgia

† SoKat Consulting, LLC,4 Woodstock, MD 21163

‡ The Johns Hopkins Carey Business School, 100 International Drive, Baltimore, MD 21202

November 2, 2017

“Government’s view of the economy could be summed up in a few short phrases: If it moves, tax it. If it keeps moving, regulate it. And if it stops moving, subsidize it.” – Ronald Reagan5

Abstract

We discuss Russia’s underlying motives for issuing its government- backed , CryptoRuble, and the implications thereof and of other likely-soon-forthcoming government-issued to some stakeholders (populace, governments, economy, finance, etc.), existing decentralized cryptocurrencies (such as and ), as well as the future of the world monetary system (the role of the U.S. therein and a necessity for the U.S. to issue CryptoDollar), including a future algorithmic universal world currency that may also emerge. We further provide a comprehensive list of references on cryptocurrencies.

1 Zura Kakushadze, Ph.D., is the President and CEO and a Co-Founder of Quantigic® Solutions LLC and a Full Professor in the Business School and the School of Physics at Free University of Tbilisi. Email: [email protected] 2 Jim Kyung-Soo Liew, Ph.D., is the CEO and Founder of SoKat Consulting, LLC and an Assistant Professor in Finance at the Johns Hopkins Carey Business School. Email: [email protected] and [email protected] 3 DISCLAIMER: This address is used by the corresponding author for no purpose other than to indicate his professional affiliation as is customary in publications. In particular, the contents of this paper are not intended as an investment, legal, tax or any other such advice, and in no way represent views of Quantigic® Solutions LLC, the website www.quantigic.com or any of their other affiliates. 4 DISCLAIMER: This address is used by the corresponding author for no purpose other than to indicate his professional affiliation as is customary in publications. The contents of this paper are not intended as an investment, legal, tax or any other such advice, and in no way represents the views of SoKat Consulting, LLC, the website www.SoKat.co or any of their other affiliates. 5 [GOP, 2017].

1

“A cryptocurrency is a digital or that uses cryptography for security. A cryptocurrency is difficult to counterfeit because of this security feature. A defining feature of a cryptocurrency, and arguably its most endearing allure, is its organic nature; it is not issued by any central authority, rendering it theoretically immune to government interference or manipulation.” [Investopedia, 2017] A plethora of decentralized cryptocurrencies has emerged since the inception of Bitcoin (BTC) in 2009 following a seminal white paper by Nakamoto [2008],6 with the total market capitalization now exceeding $170B [CoinMarketCap, 2017].7 Decentralization and anonymity of transactions make cryptocurrencies appealing to a range of users,8 but, unsurprisingly, not to central banks or sovereign governments. However, decentralization and technology [Nakamoto, 2008] are not synonymous. Blockchain is a ledger for keeping a record of all transactions. Fiat money, albeit imperfectly, can be viewed as an attempt to approximate such recordkeeping9 [Kocherlakota, 1998].10 However, there are impeding factors such as fragmented recordkeeping prone to errors and fraud.11 Even with electronic transactions,12 notwithstanding the existence of central banking systems, recordkeeping is still local by nature. Blockchain provides a robust (albeit not infallible)13 technological solution to this problem.14 Government-issued cryptocurrencies? Recent reports suggest that Russia will soon issue its government-backed cryptocurrency, CryptoRuble (see, e.g., [Coldewey, 2017]). Unlike decentralized cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin

6 For a much earlier work on an anonymous cryptographic electronic money or electronic cash system known as “ecash”, see [Chaum, 1983, 1985], which served as a basis for Chaum’s electronic money company DigiCash, Inc. founded in 1989. In 1998 DigiCash filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy and was sold for assets in 2002 [Pitta, 1999]. 7 Cryptocurrency prices are volatile. The $170B figure above is as of October 17, 2017. As of said date, Bitcoin had approximately 55% of the total market share. Table 1 summarizes top 5 cryptocurrencies by market capitalization. 8 Including those with nefarious intentions, such as money laundering, tax evasion and other illegal activities. 9 In the U.S. the Bank Secrecy Act of 1970 (or BSA) [Meltzer, 1991], among other things, requires financial institutions to file a Currency Transaction Report (CTR) with the Financial Crimes Enforcement Network (FinCEN) for all transactions exceeding $10,000. The U.S. Government records and stores information about all such transactions internally. This information is invaluable in light of USD being the default reserve currency. 10 Also see [Kocherlakota and Wallace, 1998]. In the context of Bitcoin, see, e.g., [Luther and Olson, 2015]. Sometimes, the concepts of “ideal money” and “asymptotically ideal money” by Nash [2002] are cited in this context, albeit it is unclear whether there is any direct connection to Bitcoin or cryptocurrencies in general. 11 A long list of other factors includes irrationality of markets in setting prices, socio-political inequalities, etc. 12 Which theoretically should be less affected by such issues than physical money. 13 Mt. Gox’s $460M disaster [McMillan, 2014] is only one example of cryptocurrency exchanges being hacked. 14 See Appendix A for a partial list of literature on Bitcoin, blockchain and cryptocurrencies, and references therein.

2 and Ethereum, with CryptoRuble (and other expected government-issued cryptocurrencies) there is no mining, all transactions are recorded via blockchain and verified by a centralized government authority. Blockchain (cf. traditional bank ledgers) can help prevent/reduce fraud, errors, etc. However, the aforesaid benefit of using blockchain is only the tip of the iceberg. With decentralized cryptocurrencies, one of the key concerns of central banks and sovereign governments is ceding control. With government-issued cryptocurrencies, central banks and sovereign governments will gain even more control, not less, than with the current banking system. Blockchain maintained by a centralized government authority provides a centralized, un-fragmented ledger of all transactions and other information (such as meta-data) associated therewith. This is any government’s dream come true! This will make keeping tabs even easier… Moreover, as the saying goes, “If you can’t beat them, tax them.”15 This is what Russia in part appears to be doing with CryptoRuble. Reportedly (see, e.g., [Coldewey, 2017]),16 “undocumented” CryptoRubles (those without proof of origin) will be subject to a 13% tax. This is akin to a government-mandated money laundering machine and with such a low overhead should be extremely attractive to all sorts of shady players. Russia will attract not only Russian but also foreign money (including dirty money, but not only). CryptoRuble will likely act as a tax shelter for U.S. and other subjects. One imbedded bonus for the Russian government is that it will own the information encoded in blockchain, including potentially shady transactions, and it can use this information in the future as Kompromat17 against such (unsuspecting) transactors. However, Russia’s (or another at-odds-with-the-West state’s) primary goal in issuing a government cryptocurrency is to free their monetary system from the controls exerted by the Federal Reserve (Fed), European Central Bank (ECB) and their allied central banks. CryptoRuble creates a buffer layer (see Figure 1) that only the Russian government has control over with pertinent information inaccessible to the U.S., the E.U., etc. Russian elite/oligarchs can launder

15 A parallel with an argument for legalizing cannabis/other illicit drugs and regulating and taxing them (as opposed to fighting them) can be drawn here. We should stress that we are not advocating for or against such legalization here, nor are we making an argument for or against state-mandated money laundering. We merely draw a parallel. Another, somewhat different parallel can be drawn with taxing disruptive businesses, e.g., Uber [McArdle, 2016]. 16 The original report appeared on October 14, 2017 in a Russian newspaper “Argumenti i Fakti” [AiF, 2017]. 17 In Russian, Kompromat is a shorthand for “compromising material” and stands for damaging information that may be used to blackmail or coerce someone. (There are many such shorthand words in the Russian language.)

3 their money using CryptoRuble, become impervious to (or less affected by) economic sanctions, make their assets currently tied up because of the U.S./E.U. controls (more) liquid, and so on. For instance, consider an oligarch targeted by sanctions. With the advent of CryptoRuble this oligarch could setup a new shell company (e.g., via a convoluted web of trusts) to continue a prior line of business (e.g., exports of Russian oil or some other commodity). Revenues of this shell company can be legally converted into CryptoRubles. These CryptoRubles can then be converted into funds (or property, good/services, etc.) accessible by the oligarch. Since CryptoRuble uses a centralized blockchain as a non- only available to the Russian government, the conversion of the CryptoRubles into the funds accessible by the oligarch remains hidden from the Fed/ECB/U.S./E.U. The Russian government may tax these funds at 13% if the oligarch does not disclose their origin, but this is a small price to pay. Thus, CryptoRuble will allow various individuals and companies to skirt sanctions. Reportedly, North Korea is already suspected of using Bitcoin for precisely this purpose [Boylan and Taylor 2017]. Undoubtedly, CryptoRuble will disrupt the current world monetary system, the Fed, ECB, U.S. and E.U. policies, their law enforcement operations, etc. Drug money will be easier to clean. Anti-money laundering (AML) controls and efforts will be adversely affected – with the anticipated 13% haircut, this Russian government-sponsored money laundry is simply too attractive to those with nefarious intents and will undoubtedly incent shady players.18 Money will flow away from the U.S./E.U./U.K. and into Russia. Other countries will likely issue their own cryptocurrencies. Other BRICS members (Brazil, China, India and South Africa)19 are natural candidates. Reportedly, China is also considering issuing its own cryptocurrency [Yanfei, 2017]. Other countries that could jump on the bandwagon might be Switzerland (considering its history of banking secrecy largely dismantled by the U.S. efforts), Baltic states (which tend to be forward-thinking), Nordic states, Singapore, and perhaps some others. Reportedly, even Spain is considering creating a national blockchain-based ledger [Shieber, 2017], although it is unclear what impact this might have for the (E.U.) monetary system as Spain is part of the Eurozone.

18 Multiple government-issued cryptocurrencies (see below) will only exacerbate deterioration of AML controls. 19 Reportedly, India is considering introducing government-issued cryptocurrency “Lakshmi” [Bhayani, 2017]. Dubai is contemplating government-issued cryptocurrency “emCash” [Dubai DED, 2017]. Estonia [Browne, 2017a] and Kazakhstan [Browne, 2017b] are also looking into government-issued cryptocurrencies. Japanese banks are eyeing their own called “J-Coin” (to be pegged with JPY) [Kharpal, 2017]. And the list is ever growing.

4

A key difference between government-issued and decentralized cryptocurrencies is that the former do not require mining. Mining is a process whereby GPUs/CPUs solve mathematical problems by a brute-force method to verify transactions. Miners are rewarded with small payments in respective cryptocurrencies. One issue with mining is that it is computationally and energy costly and has been argued to be inefficient and possibly even unsustainable (see, e.g., [Bariviera, 2017], [Kostakis and Giotitsas, 2014], [Nadarajah and Chu, 2017], [Urquhart, 2016], [Vranken, 2017]) as blockchain grows with each verified transaction. Centralized government- issued cryptocurrencies do not require mining, in some sense are more “efficient”, should be cheaper to maintain and more readily usable as legal tender in large economies such as Russia. The new era is being ushered in. The world order as we know it is changing, right before our eyes. This disruptive technology – cryptocurrencies – will indeed end up disrupting the status quo. However, at least in the mid-term, forward-thinking sovereign states that embrace and adapt it to their advantage will end up being the disruptors as opposed to disrupted. The U.S. is the sovereign state with most to lose in this process, with a clear policy implication: adapt to the changing reality, issue CryptoDollar now, or risk being marginalized.20 Implications to stakeholders What about other stakeholders? In Table 2 we outline some stakeholders with pros and cons from government-issued cryptocurrencies. E.g., the populace benefits from lower transaction costs, but the price to pay is diminished privacy and a greater control by the government. As another example consider banks and other traditional financial institutions. Government-issued cryptocurrencies will diminish some functions of, e.g., banks since the traditional local-by-nature bank ledgers will become obsolete. So will paper money with the implications to ATMs and bank fees associated with them. Generally, transaction costs will be reduced, a bad news for banks. However, this does not make banks obsolete as they have a number of other functions, e.g., provision of credit (credit cards, mortgages, car loans, etc.). CryptoRuble will have implications for existing decentralized cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin and Ethereum, etc. In the short term, higher volatility for decentralized cryptocurrencies can be expected due to two competing perceptions: i) government-issued cryptocurrencies go

20 For CryptoDollar to be competitive, reducing tax rates and not taxing non-US-derived income might be required.

5 against the key premise of decentralized cryptocurrencies, to wit, decentralization; and ii) on the other hand, they lend increased credibility to blockchain technology. In the beginning there likely will be a lot of noise and uncertainty, political jostling, security concerns, fear-mongering in press coverage, etc. However, it is feasible that in the longer-term decentralized cryptocurrencies will benefit from increased credibility and even more users will jump on the bandwagon, both those motivated by a major world power issuing its own cryptocurrency as well as those perceiving this as sovereign governments attempting to exert more control. Interesting times lie ahead. iCurrency? It is likely not a stretch to imagine that 100 years from now there will be no cash or paper money.21 Just as bronze, silver and gold coins, paper money will soon seem archaic if not barbaric. One may argue that currently used electronic transactions already are replacing cash. However, the current banking system itself is based on an outdated technology. Will blockchain replace it? It is conceivable that other technologies will replace blockchain. Only time will tell. Introduction of government-issued cryptocurrencies is a pivotal moment for humankind. While such cryptocurrencies do not meet the four criteria we set forth in [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015a] for iCurrency, a purely algorithmic universal numeraire and possibly a universal world currency, in the long-term the rise of government-issued cryptocurrencies may well seed the process ultimately leading to iCurrency. Assuming a bright future for humankind devoid of wars, with a truly globalized economy and interplanetary travel with colonies on Mars, it is difficult to imagine that kind of a world without a universal world currency. iCurrency is defined as a universal numeraire subject to the following criteria [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015a]: 1. iCurrency is not a currency issued (or backed) by any government; 2. it is valued based solely on supply and demand; 3. it is easily transferred across regions and globally accepted as a payment method; and 4. it is algorithmic, with no human intervention.

21 Science fiction, for what this is worth, usually predicts some kind of universal “credits”, purely electronic in nature. See, e.g., [Ebert, 1999], [Gliddon, 2005].

6

It is conceivable that a broad consortium of sovereign governments issues iCurrency, in which case Criterion 1 above can still be preserved so long as robust mechanisms are set in place to prevent any government or a group of governments from engaging in possible manipulation of iCurrency, e.g., via (analogs of) central banks artificially increasing or decreasing interest rates, monetary supply manipulation, political influences, and so forth. Criterion 2 above may be most challenging in the context of achieving stability and low volatility.22 In this regard, a staged rollout of iCurrency may be warranted, whereby its value is determined by a combination of supply and demand and regulation by a central authority. E.g., the USD/HKD spread trades between 7.75 and 7.85, a band fixed by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority. iCurrency too could be regulated at first to stay in such a target zone, which could be gradually relaxed and perhaps removed entirely at some future time. Or perhaps some wide target zone could remain.23 iCurrency would allow to more precisely estimate global inflation, global output, global productivity, global labor gains, and other global macroeconomic indicators, as well as GDP (gross domestic product) for various countries and regions and globally. (GDP measured using iCurrency was termed iGDP in [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015a]). With low sovereign government intervention and low fees for global transactions, iCurrency should be a boon to our global economy. Perhaps somewhat ironically, government-issued cryptocurrencies may be a step forward (not backward) in this regard, depending on how the world leaders approach this issue. At first, it may be unexpected that Russia, out of all the countries, has emerged as a “leader” in this process. However, shortly after we published our paper [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015a], it became evident to us that Russia was in a unique position to lead this process [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015b].24 And the reason is not technological but geopolitical. Russia has been subject to sanctions and global pressure due to its various policies w.r.t. its immediate neighbors and elsewhere in the world. Dependence on the existing world monetary order is a major stumbling block for Russia. Its desire to gain a greater degree of independence from the Fed/ECB is by no means a surprise. Cryptocurrencies arguably provide a simple solution for

22 Generally, government-issued cryptocurrencies are backed by taxation power and expected to be less volatile. 23 In which case iCurrency would not be 100% based on supply and demand, but could be close to it for all practical purposes and the band would ensure some nominal degree of stability in case of unforeseen impactful events. 24 We should have published [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015b] back then. But hindsight is always 20-20…

7

Russia. One could imagine that, if pushed into a corner, Russia could even adopt Bitcoin as a legal tender [Kakushadze and Liew, 2015b]. However, that would mean ceding too much control over information. Somewhat less dramatically, the next natural move for Russia is to issue its own government-backed cryptocurrency, CryptoRuble. If anything, it is surprising it took them so long. It appears that government-issued cryptocurrencies are a foregone conclusion. Large sovereign states have the technological know-how and means to do this. What about small and/or developing countries? If they are forced to outsource issuance of their government- backed cryptocurrencies to larger states, geopolitical and economic implications are evident: less sovereignty and ceding control over crucial information to more powerful countries.25 References AiF (2017) Russia will issue its own cryptocurrency – communications minister. Argumenti i Fakti (October 14, 2017). http://www.aif.ru/money/economy/rossiya_vypustit_sobstvennuyu_kriptovalyutu_ministr_svy azi (in Russian).

Bariviera, A.F. (2017) The inefficiency of Bitcoin revisited: A dynamic approach. Economics Letters 161: 1-4.

Bhayani, R. (2017) Govt considering its own cryptocurrency. Business Standard (September 16, 2017). http://www.business-standard.com/article/economy-policy/govt-considering-its-own- cryptocurrency-117091600051_1.html.

Boylan, D. and Taylor, G. (2017) North Korean hackers suspected of using bitcoin to undermine U.S. sanctions. The Washington Times (September 25, 2017). http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2017/sep/25/north-korea-bitcoin-use-suspected-to- skirt-sanctio/.

Browne, R. (2017a) Estonia wants to launch its own government-backed cryptocurrency called 'estcoin'. CNBS: The FinTech Effect (August 23, 2017). https://www.cnbc.com/2017/08/23/estonia-cryptocurrency-called-estcoin.html.

Browne, R. (2017b) Kazakhstan plans to launch its own cryptocurrency. CNBS: The FinTech Effect (October 17, 2017). https://www.cnbc.com/2017/10/17/kazakhstan-plans-to-launch-its- own-cryptocurrency.html.

25 Alternatively, some countries could partner with the private sector, as appears to be the case with Dubai [Dubai DED, 2017]. This would likely raise its own host of issues.

8

Chaum, D. (1983) Blind Signatures for Untraceable Payments. In: Chaum, D., Rivest, R.L. and Sherman, A.T. (eds.) Advances in Cryptology – Proceedings of Crypto’82. Boston, MA: Springer, pp.199-203.

Chaum, D. (1985) Security without identification: Transaction systems to make big brother obsolete. Communications of the ACM 28(10): 1030-1044.

CoinMarketCap (2017) Cryptocurrency Market Capitalizations. https://coinmarketcap.com/all/views/all/ (data accessed on October 17, 2017).

Coldewey, D. (2017) Russia may soon issue its own official blockchain-based currency, the CryptoRuble. TechCrunch (October 15, 2017). https://techcrunch.com/2017/10/15/russia-may- soon-issue-its-own-official-blockchain-based-currency-the-cryptoruble/.

Dubai DED (2017) Dubai Economy launches partnership to expedite emCash. Dubai Department of Economic Development (press release, September 26, 2017). http://www.dubaided.ae/English/MediaCenter/Pages/PressReleasesDetails.aspx?ItemId=233.

Ebert, R. (1999) Ebert’s bigger little movie glossary. Kansas City, MO: Andrews McMeel Publishing, p.172.

Gliddon, G. (2005) The Greenwood encyclopedia of science fiction and fantasy, Volume 2. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, p.532.

GOP (2017) 9 Ronald Reagan Quotes About Taxes. https://www.gop.gov/9-ronald-reagan- quotes-about-taxes/.

Investopedia (2017) Cryptocurrency. http://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/cryptocurrency.asp.

Kharpal, A. (2017) Japanese banks are thinking of making their own cryptocurrency called the J- Coin. CNBC: Tech Transformers (September 27, 2017). https://www.cnbc.com/2017/09/27/japanese-banks-cryptocurrency-j-coin.html.

Kakushadze, Z. and Liew, J.K-S. (2015a) iGDP? The Journal of Portfolio Management 41(3): 4-6. http://jpm.iijournals.com/content/41/3/4.

Kakushadze, Z. and Liew, J.K-S. (2015b) What if Russia Goes Crypto? Unpublished private communications.

Kocherlakota, N.R. (1998) Money is memory. Journal of Economic Theory 81(2): 232-251.

Kocherlakota, N.R. and Wallace, N. (1998) Incomplete record-keeping and optimal payment

9 arrangements. Journal of Economic Theory 81(2): 272-289.

Kostakis, V. and Giotitsas, C. (2014) The (A)Political Economy of Bitcoin. Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society 12(2): 431-440.

Luther, W.J. and Olson, J. (2015) Bitcoin is Memory. Journal of Prices & Markets 3(3): 22-33.

McArdle, M. (2016) Robbing the New (Uber) to Subsidize the Old (Taxis). Bloomberg View (August 23, 2016). https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2016-08-23/massachusetts-tax- robs-from-uber-to-subsidize-taxis.

McMillan, R. (2014) The Inside Story of Mt. Gox, Bitcoin’s $460 Million Disaster. Wired (March 3, 2014). https://www.wired.com/2014/03/bitcoin-exchange/.

Meltzer, P.E. (1991) Keeping Drug Money from Reaching the Wash Cycle: A Guide to the Bank Secrecy Act. Banking Law Journal 108(3): 230-255.

Nadarajah, S. and Chu, J. (2017) On the inefficiency of Bitcoin. Economics Letters 150: 6-9.

Nakamoto, S. (2008) Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System. Working Paper. https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf.

Nash, Jr., J.F. (2002) Ideal Money. Southern Economic Journal 69(1): 4-11.

Pitta, J. (1999) Requiem for a Bright Idea. Forbes (November 1, 1999). https://www.forbes.com/forbes/1999/1101/6411390a.html.

Shieber, J. (2017) Spain’s biggest companies are charging into crypto. TechCrunch (October 17, 2017). https://techcrunch.com/2017/10/17/spains-biggest-companies-are-charging-into- crypto/?ncid=rss.

Urquhart, A. (2016) The inefficiency of Bitcoin. Economics Letters 148: 80-82.

Vranken, H. (2017) Sustainability of Bitcoin and . Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 28: 1-9.

Yanfei, W. (2017) PBOC inches closer to digital currency. China Daily (October 14, 2017). http://usa.chinadaily.com.cn/business/2017-10/14/content_33236132.htm.

Appendix A: Further Reading The literature cited below constitutes a partial list, mostly (but with some exceptions) consists of peer-reviewed articles, and intentionally avoids ubiquitous conference proceedings articles. There are other (mostly unpublished) papers available from SSRN, arxiv.org and other sources.

10

Abramowicz, M. (2016) Cryptocurrency-Based Law. Arizona Law Review 58(2): 359-420.

Abramowicz, M. (2016) Autonocoin: A Proof-of-Belief Cryptocurrency. Ledger 1: 119-133.

Ali, R., Barrdear, J., Clews, R. and Southgate, J. (2014) Innovations in payment technologies and the emergence of digital currencies. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 54(3): 262–275.

Ali, R., Barrdear, J., Clews, R. and Southgate, J. (2014) The Economics of Digital Currencies. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 54(3): 276-286.

Andreesen, M. (2014) Why Bitcoin Matters. The New York Times (January 21, 2014). https://dealbook.nytimes.com/2014/01/21/why-bitcoin-matters/.

Baek, C. and Elbeck, M. (2014) as an Investment or Speculative Vehicle? A First Look. Applied Economics Letters 22(1): 30-34.

Bariviera, A.F. (2017) The inefficiency of Bitcoin revisited: A dynamic approach. Economics Letters 161: 1-4.

Bariviera, A.F., Basgall, M.J., Hasperué, W. and Naiouf, M. (2017) Some stylized facts of the Bitcoin market. Physica A 484: 82-90.

Barkatullah, J. and Hanke, T. (2015) Goldstrike 1: CoinTerra’s First-Generation Cryptocurrency Mining Processor for Bitcoin. IEEE Micro 35(2): 68-76.

Barrdear, J. and Kumhof, M. (2016) The Macroeconomics of Central Bank Issued Digital Currencies. Bank of England Working Paper No. 605. www.bankofengland.co.uk/research/Documents/workingpapers/2016/swp605.pdf.

Böhme, R., Christin, N., Edelman, B. and Moore, T. (2015) Bitcoin: Economics, Technology, and Governance. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29(2): 213-238.

Bouoiyour, J., Selmi, R. and Tiwari, A.K. (2015) Is Bitcoin business income or speculative foolery? New ideas through an improved frequency domain analysis. Annals of Financial Economics 10(1): 1-23.

Bouoiyour, J. and Selmi, R. (2015) What Does Bitcoin Look Like? Annals of Economics and Finance 16(2): 449-492.

Bouoiyour, J., Selmi, R., Tiwari, A.K. and Olayeni, O.R. (2016) What drives Bitcoin price? Economics Bulletin 36(2): 843-850.

11

Bouri, E., Azzi, G. and Dyhrberg, A.H. (2017) On the return-volatility relationship in the Bitcoin market around the price crash of 2013. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E- Journal 11(2): 1-16.

Bouri, E., Molnár, P., Azzi, G., Roubaud, D. and Hagfors, L.I. (2017) On the hedge and safe haven properties of Bitcoin: Is it really more than a diversifier? Finance Research Letters 20: 192-198.

Bradbury, D. (2013) The problem with Bitcoin. Computer Fraud & Security 2013(11): 5-8.

Brandvold, M., Molnár, P., Vagstad, K. and Valstad, O.C.A. (2015) Price discovery on Bitcoin exchanges. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 36: 18-35.

Brière, M., Oosterlinck, K. and Szafarz, A. (2015) Virtual currency, tangible return: Portfolio diversification with Bitcoin. Journal of Asset Management 16(6): 365-373.

Brito, J., Shadab, H.B. and Castillo, A. (2015) Bitcoin financial regulation: securities, derivatives, prediction markets, and gambling. The Columbia Science and Technology Law Review XVI: 144- 221.

Bryans, D. (2014) Bitcoin and money laundering: Mining for an effective solution. Indiana Law Journal 89(1): 441-472.

Cheah, E.T. and Fry, J. (2015) Speculative Bubbles in Bitcoin markets? An Empirical Investigation into the Fundamental Value of Bitcoin. Economics Letters 130: 32-36.

Cheung, A., Roca, E. and Su, J.-J. (2015) Crypto-currency Bubbles: an Application of the Phillips- Shi-Yu (2013) Methodology on Mt. Gox Bitcoin Prices. Applied Economics 47(23): 2348-2358.

Chu, J., Nadarajah, S. and Chan, S. (2015) Statistical Analysis of the Exchange Rate of Bitcoin. PLoS ONE 10(7): e0133678.

Ciaian, P., Rajcaniova, M. and Kancs, D.A. (2016) The economics of Bitcoin price formation. Applied Economics 48(19): 1799-1815.

Cocco, L. and Marchesi, M. (2016) Modeling and Simulation of the Economics of Mining in the Bitcoin Market. PLoS ONE 11(10): e0164603.

Cocco, L., Concas, G. and Marchesi, M. (2017) Using an Artificial Financial Market for studying a Cryptocurrency Market. Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 12(2): 345-365.

Coeckelbergh, M. and Reijers, W. (2015) Crypto currencies as narrative technologies. SIGCAS Computers & Society 45(3): 172-178.

Cusumano, M.A. (2014) The Bitcoin ecosystem. Communications of the ACM 57(10): 22-24.

12

Dimitri, N. (2017) Bitcoin Mining as a Contest. Ledger 2: 31-37.

Dion, D.A. (2013) I’ll Gladly Trade You Two Bits on Tuesday for a Byte Today: Bitcoin, Regulating Fraud in the E-Conomy of Hacker-Cash. University of Illinois Journal of Law, Technology & Policy 2013(1): 165-201.

Donier, J. and Bouchaud, J.-P. (2015) Why Do Markets Crash? Bitcoin Data Offers Unprecedented Insights. PLoS ONE 10(10): e0139356.

Dowd, K. and Hutchinson, M. (2015) Bitcoin Will Bite the Dust. Cato Journal 35(2): 357-382.

DuPont, Q. (2014) The Politics of Cryptography: Bitcoin and The Ordering Machines. Journal of Peer Production 1(4): 1-10.

Dwyer, G.P. (2015) The Economics of Bitcoin and Similar Private Digital Currencies. Journal of Financial Stability 17: 81-91.

Dyhrberg, A.H. (2015) Bitcoin, gold and the dollar – a GARCH volatility analysis. Finance Research Letters 16: 85-92.

Dyhrberg, A.H. (2015) Hedging capabilities of Bitcoin. Is it the virtual gold? Finance Research Letters 16: 139-144.

European Central Bank (2012) Virtual Currency Schemes. Technical Report. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/virtualcurrencyschemes201210en.pdf.

Evans, C.W. (2015) Bitcoin in Islamic Banking and Finance. Journal of Islamic Banking and Finance 3(1): 1-11.

Fantazzini, D., Nigmatullin, E., Sukhanovskaya, V. and Ivliev, S. (2016) Everything you always wanted to know about Bitcoin modelling but were afraid to ask. Part I. Applied Econometrics 44: 5-24 (in Russian).

Fantazzini, D., Nigmatullin, E., Sukhanovskaya, V. and Ivliev, S. (2017) Everything you always wanted to know about Bitcoin modelling but were afraid to ask. Part II. Applied Econometrics 45: 5-28 (in Russian).

Feld, S., Schönfeld, M. and Werner, M. (2014) Analyzing the deployment of Bitcoin’s P2P network under an AS-level perspective. Procedia Computer Science 32: 1121-1126.

Folkinshteyn, D., Lennon, M. and Reilly, T. (2015) A tale of twin tech: Bitcoin and the www. Journal of Strategic and International Studies X(2): 82-90.

13

Folkinshteyn, D., Lennon, M. and Reilly, T. (2015) The Bitcoin Mirage: An Oasis of Financial Remittance. Journal of Strategic and International Studies X(2): 118-124.

Folkinshteyn, D. and Lennon, M. (2016) Braving Bitcoin: A technology acceptance model (TAM) analysis. Journal of Information Technology Case and Application Research 18(4): 220-249.

Fry, J. and Cheah, E.T. (2016) Negative bubbles and shocks in cryptocurrency markets. International Review of Financial Analysis 47: 343-352.

Garcia, D. and Schweitzer, F. (2015) Social signals and algorithmic trading of Bitcoin. Royal Society Open Science 2(9): 150288.

Garcia, D., Tessone, C.J., Mavrodiev, P. and Perony, N. (2014) The digital traces of bubbles: feedback cycles between socioeconomic signals in the Bitcoin economy. Journal of The Royal Society Interface 11(99): 0623.

Gervais, A., Karame, G.O., Capkun, V. and Capkun, S. (2014) Is Bitcoin a decentralized currency? IEEE Security & Privacy 12(3): 54-60.

Grinberg, R. (2012) Bitcoin: an innovative alternative digital currency. Hastings Science and Technology Law Journal 4(1): 159-207.

Gupta, V. (2017) A Brief History of Blockchain. Harvard Business Review (February 28, 2017). https://hbr.org/2017/02/a-brief-history-of- blockchain?referral=03759&cm_vc=rr_item_page.bottom.

Harvey, C.R. (2014) Bitcoin Myths and Facts. Working Paper. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2479670.

Harvey, C.R. (2016) Cryptofinance. Working Paper. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2438299.

Houy, N. (2014) It will cost you nothing to ‘kill’ a proof-of-stake crypto-currency. Economics Bulletin 34(2): 1038-1044.

Houy, N. (2016) The Bitcoin mining game. Ledger 1: 53-68.

Hurlburt, G.F. and Bojanova, I. (2014) Bitcoin: Benefit or Curse? IT Professional 16(3): 10-15.

Jacobs, E. (2011) Bitcoin: A Bit Too Far? Journal of Internet Banking and Commerce 16(2): 1-4.

Kakushadze, Z. and Liew, J.K-S. (2015) iGDP? The Journal of Portfolio Management 41(3): 4-6. http://jpm.iijournals.com/content/41/3/4.

14

Kaplanov, N.M. (2012) Nerdy money: Bitcoin, the private digital currency, and the case against its regulation. Loyola Consumer Law Review 25(1): 111-174.

Karlstrøm, H. (2014) Do libertarians dream of electric coins? The material embeddedness of Bitcoin. Distinktion: Journal of Social Theory 15(1): 23-36.

Kim, Y.B., Kim, J.G., Kim, W., Im, J.H., Kim, T.H., Kang, S.J. and Kim, C.H. (2016) Predicting Fluctuations in Cryptocurrency Transactions Based on User Comments and Replies. PLoS ONE 11(8): e0161197.

Kristoufek, L. (2013) Bitcoin meets Google Trends and Wikipedia: quantifying the relationship between phenomena of the Internet era. Scientific Reports 3: 3415.

Kristoufek, L. (2015) What Are the Main Drivers of the Bitcoin Price? Evidence from Wavelet Coherence Analysis. PLoS ONE 10(4): e0123923.

Kondor, D., Csabai, I., Szüle, J., Pósfai, M. and Vattay, G. (2014) Inferring the interplay of network structure and market effects in Bitcoin. New Journal of Physics 16: 125003.

Kondor, D., Pósfai, M., Csabai, I. and Vattay, G. (2014) Do the rich get richer? An empirical analysis of the Bitcoin transaction network. PLoS ONE 9(2): e86197.

Kostakis, V. and Giotitsas, C. (2014) The (A)Political Economy of Bitcoin. Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society 12(2): 431-440.

Krugman, P. (2013) Bitcoin Is Evil. The New York Times (December 28, 2013). https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/12/28/bitcoin-is-evil/.

Lee, L. (2015) New Kids on the Blockchain: How Bitcoin’s technology could reinvent the stock market. Hastings Business Law Journal 12(2): 81-132.

Lennon, M. and Folkinshteyn, D. (2017) From Bit Valley to Bitcoin: The NASDAQ odyssey. Global Journal of Business Research 11(1): 85-103.

Lischke, M. and Fabian, B. (2016) Analyzing the Bitcoin Network: The First Four Years. Future Internet 8(1): 7.

Luther, W.J. and Olson, J. (2015) Bitcoin is Memory. Journal of Prices & Markets 3(3): 22-33.

Ly, M.K.-M. (2014) Coining Bitcoin’s “legal-bits”: Examining the regulatory framework for Bitcoin and virtual currencies. Harvard Journal of Law and Technology 27(2): 587-608.

Lo, S. and Wang, J.C. (2014) Bitcoin as Money? Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Current Policy Perspectives 14(4): 1-28.

15

Maurer, B., Nelms, T.C. and Swartz, L. (2013) ‘When perhaps the real problem is money itself!’: The practical materiality of Bitcoin. Social Semiotics 23(2): 261-277.

McCallum, B.T. (2015) The Bitcoin Revolution. Cato Journal 35(2): 347-356.

Moore, T. (2013) The promise and perils of digital currencies. International Journal of Critical Infrastructure Protection 6(3–4): 147-149.

Muftic, S. (2016) BIX Certificates: Cryptographic Tokens for Anonymous Transactions Based on Certificates Public Ledger. Ledger 1: 19-37.

Nadarajah, S. and Chu, J. (2017) On the inefficiency of Bitcoin. Economics Letters 150: 6-9.

Nakamoto, S. (2008) Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System. Working Paper. https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf.

Ober, M., Katzenbeisser, S. and Hamacher, K. (2013) Structure and anonymity of the Bitcoin transaction graph. Future Internet 5(2): 237-250.

Ortisi, M. (2016) Bitcoin Market Volatility Analysis Using Grand Canonical Minority Game. Ledger 1: 111-118.

Papilloud, C. and Haesler, A. (2014) The veil of economy: electronic money and the pyramidal structure of societies. Distinktion: Journal of Social Theory 15(1): 54-68.

Pedro, F. (2014) Understanding Bitcoin: Cryptography, Engineering and Economics. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.

Plassaras, N.A. (2013) Regulating digital currencies: bringing Bitcoin within the reach of the IMF. Chicago Journal of International Law 14(1): 377-407.

Raiborn, C. and Sivitanides, M. (2015) Accounting Issues Related to Bitcoins. Journal of Corporate Accounting & Finance 26(2): 25-34.

Raymaekers, W. (2015) Cryptocurrency Bitcoin: distribution, challenges and opportunities. Journal of Payments Strategy & Systems 9(1): 30-40.

Reijers, W., O’Brolcháin, F. and Haynes, P. (2016) Governance in Blockchain Technologies & Social Contract Theories. Ledger 1: 134-151.

Rizun, P.R. (2016) Subchains: A Technique to Scale Bitcoin and Improve the User Experience. Ledger 1: 38-52.

16

Rogojanu, A. and Badea, L. (2014) The issue of competing currencies. Case study – Bitcoin. Theoretical and Applied Economics XXI(1): 103-114.

Segendorf, B. (2014) What is Bitcoin? Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review 2014(2): 71-87.

Singh, K. (2015) New wild west: Preventing money laundering in the Bitcoin network. Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property 13(1): 37-64.

Simser, J. (2015) Bitcoin and modern alchemy: In code we trust. Journal of Financial Crime 22(2): 156-169.

Smith, A. and Weismann, M.F. (2014) Are You Ready for Digital Currency? Journal of Corporate Accounting & Finance 26(1): 17-21.

Stokes, R. (2012) Virtual money laundering: the case of Bitcoin and the Linden dollar. Information & Communications Technology Law 21(3): 221-236.

Trautman, L.J. (2014) Virtual Currencies; Bitcoin & What Now after Liberty Reserve, Silk Road, and Mt. Gox? Richmond Journal of Law and Technology 20(4): 1-108.

Tu, K.V. and Meredith, M.W. (2015) Rethinking Virtual Currency Regulation in the Bitcoin Age. Washington Law Review 90: 271-347.

Urquhart, A. (2016) The inefficiency of Bitcoin. Economics Letters 148: 80-82.

Van Alstyne, M. (2014) Why Bitcoin has value. Communications of the ACM 57(5): 30-32.

Velde, F.R. (2013) Bitcoin: A primer. Chicago Fed Letter 317: 1-4.

Vigna, P. and Casey, M.J. (2015) The Age of Cryptocurrency: How Bitcoin and Digital Money Are Challenging the Global Economic Order. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press.

Vranken, H. (2017) Sustainability of Bitcoin and blockchains. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 28: 1-9.

Walsh, A. (2015) The Bitcoin Blockchain As Financial Market Infrastructure: A Consideration of Operational Risk. NYU Journal of Legislation and Public Policy 18(4): 837-893.

Weber, B. (2016) Bitcoin and the legitimacy crisis of money. Cambridge Journal of Economics 40(1): 17-41.

White, L.H. (2015) The Market for Cryptocurrencies. Cato Journal 35(2): 383-402.

17

Yelowitz, A. and Wilson, M. (2015) Characteristics of Bitcoin users: an analysis of Google search data. Applied Economics Letters 22(13): 1030-1036.

Yermack, D. (2015) Is Bitcoin a Real Currency? In: Lee, D.K.C. (ed.) The Handbook of Digital Currency. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press (Elsevier), pp.31-44.

Yli-Huumo, J., Ko, D., Choi, S., Park, S. and Smolander, K. (2016) Where Is Current Research on Blockchain Technology? – A Systematic Review. PLoS ONE 11(10): e0163477.

18

Rank Name Symbol Market Cap, $B Price, $ Volume (24h), $M 1 Bitcoin BTC 94.165 5662.60 1,817 2 Ethereum ETH 30.484 320.36 459 3 Ripple XRP 9.374 0.243270 518 4 BCH 6.045 361.91 854 5 LTC 3.223 60.34 199 Table 1. Top 5 cryptocurrencies by market capitalization. The data (market capitalization and volume are rounded) is taken from [CoinMarketCap, 2017] as of approximately 1:00 PM EDT on October 17, 2017.

Stakeholder Pros Cons Populace Low transaction costs Security and privacy concerns, government control Issuing governments Control over transactions, Cannibalization of the existing information monetary system Other governments Loss of control (for some) Lower regulatory burdens Banks Low error and fraud rates Lower fees Small Businesses (including Higher growth, increased Reputational risks (money FinTech, but not only) opportunities for new laundering, fraud, etc.) technological developments Finance Higher growth, new asset Destabilization of the current classes business models Economy Higher growth, facilitated Learning curve, reputational internet commerce risks Non-government Injecting technology into Learning curve organizations (NGOs) developing countries Heads of states Forward-looking/progressive Resistance from opposition thought leadership, control (to authoritarian tendencies, over information and etc.) monetary transactions Marketplace participants Simpler/more transparent Increased government control monetary transactions and potential interference Decentralized Creating perception of Even higher volatility then cryptocurrencies (BTC, ETH, legitimacy (longer-term) currently (short-term) etc.) Table 2. Potential pros and cons to some stakeholders from government-issued cryptocurrencies.

19

Figure 1. A schematic depiction of the money flow into and from CryptoRuble. CryptoRuble creates a buffer layer that only the Russian government has control over with pertinent information inaccessible to the Fed/ECB (or their allied central banks), the U.S., the E.U., etc.

20