Do Preferential Trade Agreements Matter?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Do Preferential Trade Agreements Matter? Trade and conflicts: Do preferential trade agreements matter? Arslan Tariq RANA* Abstract A long debate continues whether international trade institutions (specifically preferential trade agreements, (PTAs)) affect security relations between states. Contradicting theories and empirical claims are put forward by realists and liberals. The former posit that the institutions are epiphenomenal and possess no power to constrain state behavior whereas the latter claim that the institutions are likely to promote cooperation by supplying forums for consultation, arbitration and adjudication, thus reducing the risk of war between states. This study identifies an important channel through which the legal dimension of trade agreements (hence Dispute Settlement Mechanisms in PTAs) may have pacifying effects on the outbreaks of war. Dispute Settlement Mechanisms of PTAs do have strong implications for MIDs, although not directly, but through low-level of foreign policy disputes, such as economic sanctions. If economic sanctions are believed to escalate to violent conflict, PTA DSMs may reduce the probability of war by mitigating the escalation of economic sanctions. However, the level of legalism differs among DSMs in PTAs. The present study first confirms empirically that sanction disputes escalate to militarized disputes and further, addresses the selection issue by using bivariate probit model. I find a sizeable impact of medium level of legalism reducing the sanctions escalation into war whereas high level of legalism, in which the state sovereignty is limited, do reduce the probability of sanctions but have no impact on war probability. Further, the interstate political cooperation proves to be a strong determinant for highly legalistic PTAs but not in the case of medium level of legalism. JEL classification: D74, F15, F51 Keywords: international relations, trade, dispute settlement mechanisms, war * Laboratoire d’Economie d’Orléans (LEO) UMR 7322 - CNRS, Faculté de Droit, d’Economie et de Gestion Rue de Blois – BP 26739, 45067, Orléans Cedex 2, France. Cell # 33(0) 6 26 55 39 30. Email: [email protected] 1 1. Introduction In 1945 A.O. Hirschman launched a timely debate on the role of international trade as a major factor influencing conflicts and even wars between states. This was also the time when the international community had to be reconstructed through complex cooperation mechanisms with the view to build on lessons of past errors. Two centuries before, the German philosopher I. Kant, trying to devise a scheme for perpetual peace, had seen in international trade a powerful mean to consolidate peaceful relationship between states, thus praising sweet trade. There is no contest on the fact that trade is central in antagonistic or cooperative relationships of nations pursuing legitimately their own interests. Still the ways through which trade institutions, trading arrangements and more recently the ever growing various types of free trade agreements, orientate states towards resolution of conflicts or stalemate, has to be revisited. Specifically, the legal dimension of trade institutions (hence Preferential Trade Agreements) plays an important role for the preservation of peace. Also it is important to identify the ways through which the institutional (legal) dimension in PTAs (Duina and Morano-Foadi, 2011) may or may not have a profound effect on peace. The aim of this chapter is to identify statistically the contribution of various form of institutionalization of trade relationship on conflict outbreaks of varying intensities (including wars), to identify also the channels through which these institutions mitigate or eventually exacerbate latent conflicts. The literature in international relations identifies three pillar, based on so-called Kantian tripod, through which peace can be preserved (Russett and Oneal, 2001) which are democracy, economic (trade) interdependence and international institutionalization. Indeed, realists believe that trade induces conflict (Hirschman, 1945) or have no impact on the establishment of peace (Keshk et al, 2010) due to the existence of asymmetries in trade relationship whereas for the liberals, trade increases the opportunity cost of war and thus promotes peace (Hegre et al., 2010; Martin et al., 2008). Obviously, it is not possible 2 to claim that all military conflicts originate in confrontation of trading interest. But trade would nonetheless play a central part in the set up of latent or developing conflicts. For this reason, the effects of trade interdependence on military conflict have become a widely discussed issue in economic and political literature. Furthermore, the role of institutions devised to organize trading relations, to set up rules to solve conflicts and to provide a legal framework to commercial exchanges, was viewed as central in these processes of cooperation and confrontation among nations. After 1945, institutions developed predominantly as multilateral organizations, but more recently, regional organizations and even bilateral preferential trade agreements began to occupy the front stage (e.g. Mansfield and Pevehouse, 2000). Consequently, the legal dimension of PTAs became essential to contain possible conflicts (Russett and Oneal, 1998). Indeed, Robert Schuman accentuated the idea of a governing body, during the creation of European Steel and Coal Community, a predecessor to today’s European Union. In his words: “By pooling basic production and by instituting a new High Authority, whose decisions will bind France, Germany and other member countries; this proposal will lead to the realization of the first concrete foundation of a European federation indispensable to the preservation of peace.” The Schuman Declaration – 9 May 19501. The basis of this High Authority, as well as in other trade agreements, lies in the creation of Dispute Settlement Mechanisms (DSMs) that perform numerous functions reducing transaction costs through restraining norm-breakers, mediating among the conflicting parties, arbitrating and adjudicating. 1 http://europa.eu/about-eu/basic-information/symbols/europe-day/schuman-declaration/index_en.htm 3 Preferential Trade Agreements, however, differ greatly in terms of legalization. Low level of legalism leaves to political/diplomatic negotiation the responsibility to resolve disputes, whereas medium level of legalism organizes the establishment of ad hoc panels (third party), whose arbitration is legally binding. These institutions are referred as quasi-judicial (Chase et al., 2013). Finally, the highly legalistic mechanisms allow for standing tribunals and courts. These represent the highest form of institutionalization. This chapter will provide an empirical analysis of the impact of various types of dispute settlement mechanisms in PTAs on militarized disputes. A two-stage approach is proposed, where the link between DSMs and sanctions is combined with the link between sanctions and militarized disputes. First, the effects of threat and imposition of economic sanctions are analyzed using a simple probit model. Then, the selection issue is addressed in order to analyze the escalation of lower-level of disputes (economic sanctions) to the higher level of disputes (militarized interstate disputes) across country pairs using a bivariate probit model covering the period 1950-2001. Correlates of War (COW) database is used for the information on Militarized Interstate Disputes at country-pair level2. The data on economic sanctions is extracted from Threats and Imposition of Sanctions (TIES) database. The paper proceeds as follows. The next section offers a broad review on the relationship between different aspects of international institutions (notably Preferential Trade Agreements) and militarized interstate disputes. Section 3 presents the analysis of the effects of sanctions on militarized conflicts. Section 4 presents the analysis on the impact of institutionalization of PTAs on war probabilities through sanctions, section 5 analyses the determinants of institutionalization of PTAs whereas section 6 concludes. 2 Currently the Correlates of War (COW) database offers the data till 2001, however, it will be updated till 2010 in the near future. It will then be possible to extend the analysis, to include the important wave of PTAs post 2001. 4 2. Trade institutions and interstate conflict The literature in international relations on economic interdependence has recently renewed its attention on the relationship between international trade institutions and agreements and interstate conflict, introducing econometric methods. Like in the old debate, a controversy exists between realists and liberals, who theorize contradictory effects of trade institutions on violent conflict. The so-called realist school of thought considers international institutions to have little impact on the propensity of states to engage in conflicts. In the presence of powerful nations and international anarchy, organizations have little importance and reflect the interests of powerful states. The realists note that customary international law is very weak, so is the regulatory power of supranational institutions to protect the rights of states in the international system. This is the reason why these institutions could not play a vital role in reducing international conflict. Even in the context of European Union (which in the most advanced stage towards political union), Mearsheimer (1990) casts doubt on the belief that EU, as an institution, has played a major role
Recommended publications
  • Socio-Economic and Political Consequences of Economic Sanctions for Target and Third-Party Countries
    Socio-Economic and Political Consequences of Economic Sanctions for Target and Third-Party Countries Dursun Peksen, Ph.D. Assistant Professor University of Memphis Possible Effects of Economic Sanctions on Human Rights, Democratic Freedoms, and Press Freedom in Target Countries Economic sanctions fail between 65-95% of the time in achieving their intended goals. Evidence suggests sanctions are also counterproductive in advancing human rights, democracy, and press freedom. Why? 1. Imposed sanctions often fail to impair the capacity of the government in part because the target elites might respond to foreign pressure by: * changing their public spending priorities by shifting public resources to military equipment and personnel to enhance their coercive capacity * redirecting the scarce resources and services to its supporters such as those in police, military, and civil services to maintain their loyalty and support; and * actively involving themselves in sanction busting activities through illegal smuggling and other underground transnational economic channels. Thus, trade and financial restrictions imposed on the target government are unlikely to exact significant damage on the coercive capacity of the government to induce behavioral change from the targeted elites. 2. When an external actor demands political reforms from another regime, the targeted leadership usually perceives the foreign pressure as a threat to sovereignty and particularly to regime survival. To mitigate any possible domestic “audience costs” caused by conceding to the sanctions, the regime has an incentive to put greater pressure on opposition groups to show its determination against any external pressure for reform and policy change. Socio-economic and Political Effects of Sanctions on the Vulnerable Segments (Women, Children, and Minorities) of Target Populations Sanctions, conditional on the severity of the coercion, might cause significant civilian pain by worsening public health conditions, economic well-being, and physical security of the populace in target countries.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Economic Sanctions*
    Chapter 27 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF ECONOMIC SANCTIONS* WILLIAM H. KAEMPFER Academic Affairs, Campus Box 40, University of Colorado, Boulder, Boulder, CO 80309-0040, USA e-mail: [email protected] ANTON D. LOWENBERG Department of Economics, California State University, Northridge, 18111 Nordhoff Street, Northridge, CA 91330-8374, USA e-mail: [email protected] Contents Abstract 868 Keywords 868 1. Introduction 869 2. Economic effects of sanctions 872 3. The political determinants of sanctions policies in sender states 879 4. The political effects of sanctions on the target country 884 5. Single-rational actor and game theory approaches to sanctions 889 6. Empirical sanctions studies 892 7. Political institutions and sanctions 898 8. Conclusions and avenues for further research 903 References 905 * The authors thank Keith Hartley, Irfan Nooruddin and Todd Sandler for valuable comments. Derek Lowen- berg provided technical assistance in preparation of the final manuscript. All errors remain the responsibility of the authors alone. Handbook of Defense Economics, Volume 2 Edited by Todd Sandler and Keith Hartley © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved DOI: 10.1016/S1574-0013(06)02027-8 868 W.H. Kaempfer and A.D. Lowenberg Abstract International economic sanctions have become increasingly important as alternatives to military conflict since the end of the Cold War. This chapter surveys various approaches to the study of economic sanctions in both the economics and international relations literatures. Sanctions may be imposed not to bring about maximum economic damage to the target, but for expressive or demonstrative purposes. Moreover, the political effects of sanctions on the target nation are sometimes perverse, generating increased levels of political resistance to the sanctioners’ demands.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Sanctions and Globalization: Assessing the Impact of the Globalization Level of Target State on Sanctions Efficacy1
    Journal of Economics, Finance and Accounting – JEFA (2019), Vol.6(1). p.41-54 Duzcu ECONOMIC SANCTIONS AND GLOBALIZATION: ASSESSING THE IMPACT OF THE GLOBALIZATION LEVEL OF TARGET STATE ON SANCTIONS EFFICACY1 DOI: 10.17261/Pressacademia.2019.1027 JEFA- V.6-ISS.1-2019(4)-p.41-54 Murad Duzcu Hatay Mustafa Kemal University, Department of International Relations, Tayfur Sökmen Kampüsü, 31060, Antakya, Hatay, Turkey. [email protected] , ORCID: 0000-0001-5587-4774 Date Received: November 30, 2018 Date Accepted: March 18, 2019 To cite this document Duzcu, M. (2019). Economic sanctions and globalization: Assessing the impact of the globalization level of target state on sanctions efficacy. Journal of Economics, Finance and Accounting (JEFA), V.6(1), p.41-54. Permemant link to this document: http://doi.org/10.17261/Pressacademia.2019.1027 Copyright: Published by PressAcademia and limited licenced re-use rights only. ABSTRACT Purpose - When do states resist the threat of sanctions or comply with the demands of the political unit imposing sanctions? This article argues that if the target has a high globalization index, it conforms to the demands of the sender. Therefore, the article examines the impact of target’s globalization level on the initiation and success of economic sanctions as a frequently used foreign policy tool. Methodology - In combination of two datasets, (for sanctions cases, Hufbauer et al, 2007; and for globalization index Raab et al, 2007), this article, uses 72 sanctions cases from Hufbauer et al. (2007) dataset to examine some indicators of sanctions efficacy. A probit model is used to analyze the hypotheses.
    [Show full text]
  • Export Controls and Economic Sanctions
    BUSINESS REGULATION Export Controls and Economic Sanctions JAMES W REED, ALAN WH. GOURLEY, LORRAINE B. HALLOWAY, AND JEFFREY L. SNYDER* I. Introduction Changes in U.S. export controls and economic sanctions during the year 2003 were largely a reflection of three main forces that shaped U.S. security policy: (1) the war in Iraq; (2) continued efforts to deny financial and logistical support to terrorist groups; and (3) a renewed emphasis on stemming the flow of sensitive products and technologies to proli- ferators of weapons of mass destruction. These three themes played out not only in new regulations and policies emanating from the three principal agencies that regulate activity in this area-the Departments of Commerce, State, and Treasury-but they were evident in more aggressive patterns of export enforcement activity. In the sections that follow, we adopt the framework of previous year-end summaries in this journal to trace the highlights of regulatory developments that affected economic sanc- tions and export controls during 2003. While this brief survey does not offer a compendium of all of the developments in this area over the past year, the summaries below describe noteworthy developments that warrant the attention of practitioners in this field. II. Trade and Economic Sanctions A. IRAQ As the United States and its coalition parmers brought major hostilities to a close in Iraq, governments and international organizations strained to adjust the multinational embargo on Iraq to match the realities on the ground. A necessary predicate was achieved when the United Nations Security Council adopted Resolution 1483, which formally lifted all UN sanctions, except those that related to the sale and supply to Iraq of arms and material.' Immediately thereafter, the Treasury Department's Office of Foreign Assets Control (OFAC) issued a new General License on May 23, 2003, which substantially-although not completely-lifted the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • International Economic Sanctions: Improving the Haphazard U.S. Legal Regime
    Georgetown University Law Center Scholarship @ GEORGETOWN LAW 1999 International Economic Sanctions: Improving the Haphazard U.S. Legal Regime Barry E. Carter Georgetown University Law Center This paper can be downloaded free of charge from: https://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub/1585 Barry E. Carter, International Economic Sanctions: Improving the Haphazard U.S. Legal Regime, 75 Cal. L. Rev. 1159 (1987) This open-access article is brought to you by the Georgetown Law Library. Posted with permission of the author. Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub Part of the International Law Commons California Law Review VOL. 75 JULY 1987 No. 4 Copyright © 1987 by California Law Review, Inc. International Economic Sanctions: Improving the Haphazard U.S. Legal Regime Barry E. Carter TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE I. INTRODUCTION ........................................... 1163 Scope of the Article ....................................... 1166 II. THE PURPOSES AND EFFECTIVENESS OF ECONOMIC SANCTIONS ................................................ 1168 A. The Purposes of Sanctions ............................. 1170 B. Effectiveness of Sanctions .............................. 1171 1. Effectiveness as a Function of Purpose .............. 1173 2. Effectiveness of Sanctions by Type .................. 1177 3. Costs to the Sender Country ....................... 1180 III. THE NONEMERGENCY LAWS .............................. 1183 A. Bilateral Government Programs........................ 1183 B. Exports from the United
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Sanctions Against Human Rights Violations Buhm Suk Baek J.S.D
    Cornell Law Library Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository Cornell Law School Inter-University Graduate Conferences, Lectures, and Workshops Student Conference Papers 4-14-2008 Economic Sanctions Against Human Rights Violations Buhm Suk Baek J.S.D. candidate, Cornell Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/lps_clacp Part of the Economics Commons, Human Rights Law Commons, and the International Law Commons Recommended Citation Baek, Buhm Suk, "Economic Sanctions Against Human Rights Violations" (2008). Cornell Law School Inter-University Graduate Student Conference Papers. Paper 11. http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/lps_clacp/11 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Conferences, Lectures, and Workshops at Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cornell Law School Inter-University Graduate Student Conference Papers by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ECONOMIC SANCTIONS AGAINST HUMAN RIGHTS VIOLATIONS By Buhm-Suk Baek* March 2008 * Candidate for J.S.D., Cornell Law School; I am deeply grateful to Professor Muna Ndulo. Without his sincere advice and comments, I could not complete this paper. I would like to extend my thanks to Professor David Wippman for his valuable advices. My deepest appreciation also goes to Kornelia Tancheva for her valuable instructions on this paper. Foremost, I would like to thank my father, KwangSun Baek, to whom I dedicate this paper. ECONOMIC SANCTIONS AGAINST HUMAN RIGHTS VIOLATIONS Buhm-Suk Baek ABSTRACT The idea of human rights protection, historically, has been considered as a domestic matter, to be realized by individual states within their domestic law and national institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • THE ADVERSE CONSEQUENCES of ECONOMIC SANCTIONS on the ENJOYMENT of HUMAN RIGHTS by Em
    THE ADVERSE CONSEQUENCES OF ECONOMIC SANCTIONS ON THE ENJOYMENT OF HUMAN RIGHTS by Em. Prof. Dr. Marc BOSSUYT President of the Constitutional Court of Belgium 1. The working document (E/CN.4/Sub.2/2000/33), prepared “without financial implications” as requested by the UN Sub-Commission on the Promotion and Protection of Minorities on 26 August 1999 in its decision 1999/111 of 26 August 1999, was presented to the Sub- Commission on 16 August 2000. This was the follow-up to resolution 1997/35 of 28 August 1997, in which the Sub-Commission had stressed four specific points concerning such measures: “(i) They should always be limited in time (fourth preambular paragraph); (ii) They most seriously affect the innocent population, especially the most vulnerable (fifth preambular paragraph); (iii) They aggravate imbalances in income distribution (sixth preambular paragraph); (iv) They generate illegal and unethical business practices (seventh preambular paragraph)”. 2. With regard to the nature of the actions undertaken, a brief classification of sanctions was provided : (i) Two basic forms of economic sanctions: (a) Trade sanctions restricting imports and exports to and from the target country; (b) Financial sanctions addressing monetary issues. (ii) Other forms of sanctions include: (a) Sanctions against the travel of certain individuals or groups and sanctions against certain kinds of air transport; (b) Military sanctions including arms embargoes and the termination of military assistance or training; (c) Diplomatic sanctions revoking visas of diplomats and political leaders; (d) Cultural sanctions banning athletes from international sports competitions and artists from international events. 3. A six-pronged test to evaluate sanctions was proposed: (i) Are the sanctions imposed for valid reasons? Sanctions under the United Nations system must be imposed only when there is a threat of or actual breach of international peace and security.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of US Economic Sanctions on Human Rights
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Gutmann, Jerg; Neuenkirch, Matthias; Neumeier, Florian Working Paper Precision-Guided or Blunt? The Effects of US Economic Sanctions on Human Rights ifo Working Paper, No. 229 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Gutmann, Jerg; Neuenkirch, Matthias; Neumeier, Florian (2016) : Precision- Guided or Blunt? The Effects of US Economic Sanctions on Human Rights, ifo Working Paper, No. 229, ifo Institute - Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich, Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/149551 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents
    [Show full text]
  • Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion
    University of Wollongong Research Online Faculty of Business - Economics Working Papers Faculty of Business and Law January 2000 Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion Kankesu Jayanthakumaran University of Wollongong, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ro.uow.edu.au/commwkpapers Recommended Citation Jayanthakumaran, Kankesu, Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion, Department of Economics, University of Wollongong, 2000. https://ro.uow.edu.au/commwkpapers/30 Research Online is the open access institutional repository for the University of Wollongong. For further information contact the UOW Library: [email protected] University of Wollongong Department of Economics Working Paper Series 2000 Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion Kankesu Jayanthakumaran WP 00-09 INDUSTRIALISATION: IMPORT SUBSTITUTION TO EXPORT PROMOTION Kankesu Jayanthakumaran* ABSTRACT Import-substitution policy creates biases in the incentive structure and lowers the growth of potential exports in the long run. Trade reforms in this respect are likely to reduce the gap between domestic and border prices. The expectation is to bring better industrial performance on the lines of comparative advantages. This paper examines the import-substitution policy and the effect and impact of trade liberalisation. INTRODUCTION Neoclassical economic theory focuses on the market or exchange with the assumption that the price mechanism works well and allocates resources efficiently. A focus on the effectiveness of the market mechanism in allocating resources is a core theme of this approach. Promoting foreign trade to access the potential static and dynamic gains and removing the widespread inefficiencies in developing countries due to higher level of protection are some of the issues that the supporters of the market mechanism focus on.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Sanctions in Contemporary International Relations: New Forms of Implementation
    5 Myron Yankiv, Kostyantyn Flissak Economic sanctions in contemporary international relations: new forms of implementation Summary: The article discusses the application of economic sanctions in the context of current international economic relations which are evolving along with the development of new relations between states, their integration groups, and international economic and financial organisations. The current phase of globalization is unable to meet earlier expectations, as there are more and more disputes arising from conflicts of national inter- ests, and in some cases, as a response to the above, sanctions are being applied. Most of the research in this area focuses on the legal basis for economic sanctions, while their economic features resulting from the peculiarities of the development of interna- tional economic relations are not given sufficient attention. This article addresses the problem of defining sanctions clearly, taking into account their specificity, legal status, the legality of application, and the effectiveness of regulations. Justification and unifica- tion of the economic definition of the category of “sanctions” may be a premise for pre- venting their abuse by individual states pursuing their own interests and may serve the purposes of proper legal interpretations within international organisations, primarily the UN. The authors suggest that the principles of the application of international sanctions should be made more precise in UN and EU regulatory documents. They draw attention to the new characteristics of international economic sanctions, in particular, to attribut- ing protectionist features to these sanctions and using aggressive protectionism by states as a tool to promote national interests in order to achieve a competitive advantage.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of the Sanctions in Diplomacy Introduction
    ODUMUNC 2020 Issue Brief UN General Assembly Fourth Committee: Disarmament The Role of the Sanctions in Diplomacy ODU United Nations Society Introduction: The Sanction determination of oppressed people. But a Dilemma growing consensus of UN Member States, including countries most affected by UN sanctions and their allies in the Non-Aligned Sanctions are one of the most common tools of Movement (NAM), is increasingly skeptical of international diplomacy and one of the most sanctions, though. Most UN Member States see controversial. Although they have ben in use sanctions as economic warfare by Western ford decades, in recent years, pushing the Governments—many of them their formal sanction button has been become a standard colonial and imperial rulers—to assert control response to international controversies.1 Is this over their domestic affairs and political choice. tool effective? Does it cause more harm than Other UN Member States support sanctions good? Should UN Member States be when they support national self-determination discouraged from using tehm, or asked to use against colonialism and imperialism. them exclusively through the UN? Even for the country that uses sanctions most of To their advocates, sanctions are way of raising all—the United States—they are highly pressure on governments violating international controversial. In the words of a prominent normative principles without resort to outright American foreign policy analyst: warfare. To their critics they are ineffectual, little more than political theater, more likely to ‘Sanctions don't work’ is an often-heard harm the innocent than their intended targets. refrain… What cannot be disputed, though, is that economic sanctions are fast But sanctions are extremely controversial.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Sanctions Sharpening a Vital Foreign Policy Tool
    Atlantic Council GLOBAL BUSINESS & ECONOMICS PROGRAM ISSUE BRIEF Economic Sanctions Sharpening a Vital Foreign Policy Tool JUNE 2017 JOHN FORRER Economic Sanctions Initiative Under the leadership of Andrea Montanino, director of the Atlantic Council’s Global Business & Economics Program, and Ambassador Daniel Fried, distinguished fellow at the Atlantic Council and former coordinator for sanctions policy at the US State Department, the Economic Sanctions Initiative is building a platform for dialogue between the public and the private sector to investigate how to improve the design and implementation of economic sanctions. To forge a path toward more effective economic sanctions, the initiative has a focus that goes beyond a purely national security perspective on sanctions to bridge the gap with the broader business perspective. he recent comments by US Secretary of State Rex Tillerson— “[W]e will continue to hold Russia accountable to its Minsk commitments. The United States sanctions will remain until Moscow reverses the actions that triggered our sanctions.”1— Tunderscore the enduring significance of economic sanctions as a vital foreign policy tool. Whether faced with aggressive military actions by one country against another, interference by one country in another country’s elections, intolerable human rights violations, or the illegal testing of nuclear weapons, economic sanctions are among the first foreign policy options discussed as a response. The United States, for instance, has twenty-six active sanctions programs against
    [Show full text]