Supply and Demand and Equilibrium
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
1
Supply and Demand and Equilibrium
Introduction to Microeconomic Supply and Demand
This on-line Chapter introduces the concepts of Supply and Demand to students who have not had an introductory micro-economics course. Many economists argue that many questions in economics (why is air which is essential to life “free” while diamond rings which have no necessary role to play in human life expensive?) can be answered with the three words, “supply and demand.” In fact, there is a joke (attributed to the British philosopher Thomas Carlyle) that you could teach a parrot to say “supply and demand” and it would immediately become an economist! So what are these concepts of “supply and demand?” Economists use supply and demand analysis to explain the price of products, the wages and salaries of employees, and the interest rate on money loans. In chapters 3, 4 and 6, this book uses the tools of supply and demand analysis to illuminate the differences between the Classical approaches to macro-economics and the Keynesian critiques of those proposals. Students who have already had a Principles of Microeconomics course will find this chapter has nothing new in it but they might find it a useful review before tackling chapters 3, 4 and 6. The limitations and criticisms of supply and demand analysis are discussed toward the end of the chapter.
The major points in this chapter are: • Defining and explaining the basics of supply and demand analysis. • Understand the context in which the supply and demand model is developed. • Explaining progressive criticisms of supply and demand analysis.
The Market System and Individual Markets
It is important to begin by distinguishing a particular market from the whole market system (often just called “the market”). Historically, a market was an area, usually near the center of a village or town, where buyers and sellers would meet and exchange goods. Later, any place where a merchant regularly sold commodities was referred to as a market. Today, the word “market” sometimes refers to a grocery store, but it is more generally used as an abstract concept among economists. In this text, market refers to a process rather than a location–a process through which buyers and sellers exchange money for goods and services. We speak of the stock market, the labor market, or the automobile market when we are specifically referring to the buying and selling of stocks, labor services, or automobiles. We speak of the market or the market system when we mean monetary exchange and price determination in general. It is obvious that any modern market system that successfully facilitates exchange must contain complex systems of customs and traditions, laws and agencies of law enforcement, as well as the infrastructure in which and through which exchange takes place. A market is a two-sided phenomenon, with both buyers and sellers. In the modern capitalist economy, buyers have money they wish to exchange for goods and services. At the same time, sellers have goods and services they wish to exchange for money. “Goods” are things like toothbrushes or television sets. “Services” are things like haircuts or music lessons. The market treats the two categories in exactly the same way. Therefore, in 2 what follows here, we shall use “goods,” but keep in mind that the argument is just the same for services. The amount of a good that buyers want to buy and have the money to purchase at any given price is called the “demand” for that good. Similarly, the amount of the good that sellers are willing and able to sell at any given price is called the “supply” of the good. Note that demand is not simply related to need or desire. A penniless child longingly gazing through the window of a candy store adds nothing to the market demand for candy. Similarly, in the Great Depression of the 1930s, millions of people went hungry while tons of wheat and thousands of cattle and sheep were destroyed and wasted because of the lack of any market demand for these products. The problem, of course, was that, like the child at the candy store, the unemployed millions, had no money to exchange for the food they needed. Thus, demand involves the combination of wants plus cash. Similarly, supply requires not just the willingness to sell a product but that actual possession of the product.
Supply, Demand, and Prices
Restated more formally, the definitions of demand and supply are as follows. Demand for a good is the quantity of that good buyers would be willing and able to purchase during a given period, at various price levels, holding all other things constant. We can think of it as a series of “if…., then…” statements: “If the price if $X, then I will buy Y quantity,” in the mind of the consumer before he/she actually arrives at the point where he/she can actually buy it. Obviously, demand must be expressed in terms of a given period if it is to have any meaning. The number of automobiles people wish to purchase is certainly very different over the course of a week than over a year. Moreover, a given price must be specified. Clearly, the number of automobiles people would like to buy will be very different if the price is $500 than if it is $50,000. The lower the price, the more of them people will be able to and want to buy. It is also very important to understand that these alternative price-quantity combinations are internal to the consumer–they exist before the consumer sees the product and knows the possible price. The definition of supply is very similar to that of demand. Supply of a good is the quantity of the good sellers would like to sell during a given period, at various prices, holding all other things constant. In most circumstances, firms are willing to increase the quantity they produce if the market price increases. Again, supply can be described as a series of “if…., then…” statements: “If the price is $A, then I will offer for sale B quantity,” in the mind of the seller before he/she knows how many buyers there are for the product. When demand and supply are combined, they describe the market for a particular product. Students should note that as defined above, demand and supply are independent of each other. Beginning with these definitions, it becomes possible to define a demand schedule and a supply schedule. A “demand schedule” relates various prices of that good with the amounts of that good people would like to buy at each of the various prices. This schedule of demand by buyers takes as given the incomes and preferences of the buyers–as well as the prices of related goods like substitutes. If people in a particular state or region of the United States were polled in order to determine the number of automobiles, such as Ford Explorers, they would like to buy at various prices, the results might be similar to those given in Table SD1. <