Textbook, Chapter 1, Exercise 2 and 7, And

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Textbook, Chapter 1, Exercise 2 and 7, And

Econ 241 A Joshua Aizenman Problem set #1 Textbook, Chapter 1, Exercise 2 and 7, and Question # 3: Consider a two periods, small open economy. There are two goods: the home good, h, and the foreign good, m. The price of the domestic good is normalized to 1, the international relative price of the two goods is one. The consumer starts with endowment W0 of the home good in period zero. The real interest rate in terms of the home good is r (= the world real interest rate).  1  1 Consumer’s utility is (1) V  (h0 ) (m0 )   (h1 ) (m1 ) ;   1. Trade liberalization eliminates the tariff on good h at the beginning of period zero. Hence, the period-0 tariff is zero. The trade reform is not credible - it will be reversed in period one with probability . Consequently, the expected future relative price of the foreign good in the second period is

t1 Pr .  (2) T1   ; t1  1 . The tariff’s income is reimbursed to the consumer in 1 Pr . 1   a lump sum manner. A. Find the impact of the anticipated policy reversal on the patterns of consumption and saving.

B. Denote by Ct the real consumption expenditure, associated with the dual price index pt

[it has the from of Ct  (ht  Tt m) / pt ]. Characterize pt .

C. Find the expected value of C1 , C1  EC1  (E is the expectation operator). D. Consider now the case where the consumer’s preferences are modified to 1 1 1 (3) ~ 1 1 where 1 1 , and   0 . Explain the economic V  C0    C1,   C1,  EC1   interpretation of  and . E. Characterize the impact of higher  on consumer’s saving for the case outlined in part a. Econ 241 A Joshua Aizenman Problem set #2; October 8, due date: October 17. Chapter 2, question 2, and the following three questions:

1. Consider a two periods, small open economy, under free trade. There are two goods: the home good, h, and the foreign good, m. The price of the domestic good is normalized to 1, the international relative price of the two goods is one in period zero. The consumer starts

with endowment W0 of the home good in period zero. The real interest rate in terms of the home good is r (= the world real interest rate). The utility in period t is a Cobb- Douglass one  1 (1) (ht ) (mt ) The future terms of trade are random: the future relative price of the foreign good in the second period is 1/(1   ) Pr . 0.5 (2) T1   . 1/(1   ) Pr . 0.5

Denote by Ct the real consumption expenditure, associated with the dual price index pt [it has

ht  Tt m the from of Ct  1 ]. The consumer’s preferences are (Tt ) 1 1 1 (3) ~ 1 1 where 1 1 , and   0 . V  C0    C1,   C1,  EC1   Characterize the impact of greater terms of trade volatility (higher ) on consumer’s saving. Explain.

2. Consider a two period economy. The first period output is Y0  1. The second period output is random:

(1) Y1  1   ;  is the second productivity,       for 0   . Let f (  ) be the density function of productivity shocks. Collecting taxes is costly: a tax at rate t yields a net tax revenue of

(2) Ti  Yi [t  (t)]; ' 0; " 0. The tax revenue is used to purchase public goods G (like defense, etc.), and to service the outstanding debt. The demand for fiscal services is inelastic:

(3) G0  G1  G . The country may borrow internationally at a risk free real interest rate of r. Let B stand for borrowing in period zero, and assume that the initial debt is zero. The government does all the international borrowing. All agents are risk-neutral:

(4) V  C0  C1 a. Characterize the patterns of optimal taxes and borrowing for the case where the government is maximizing the expected utility of the representative agent, subject to the constraints provided by (1)-(4). b. Redo part a. for the case where the private sector does the borrowing. c. Redo part a. for the case where agents are risk averse [i.e.,

V  u(C0 )  u(C1 ); u' ; u" 0].

3. Loss aversion is the tendency of agents to be more sensitive to reductions in their consumption than to increases, relative to some reference point. It is modeled using a generalized expected utility framework that attaches bigger weights to ‘bad’ states of nature and smaller ones to ‘good’ states than in the conventional expected utility set up.

Consider a two period economy. The first period output is Y0  1. The second period output is random:

(1) Y1  1   ; There is an equal chance of the productivity shock being good or bad:   with probability 0.5 (2)    .   with probability 0.5 Consider the case where agents’ initial income is allocated across saving (S), and consumption (C). Hence, the intertemporal budget constraints are

(1) C0  1  S; C1  S(1  r)  1  

Private agents choose a level of saving to maximize the utility (V) of loss-averse agents:

MAX V (3) ; where S

(4) V  u0  0.5[(1 )u1,H (1  )u1,L ] ;

u0  u(1  S); u1,H  u(S(1  r)  1   ); u1,L  u(S(1  r)  1   ) ; and u is a neo-classical utility function [u’>0, u” < 0]. The extent of loss aversion is captured by the extra weight ( ) attached to the bad state of nature in the utility function (V ).1 Characterize the optimal saving, S. What factors determine the size of precautionary saving?

1 The loss aversion ratio is the marginal utility of a loss relative to the marginal utility of a gain. It is equal to (1   ) /(1   ) . The ratio measures the tendency of agents to be more sensitive to reductions in their utility than to increases. [See Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler (JPE, 1990)]. The ratio has a value of one in the conventional utility framework where agents assign no extra weight to bad outcomes, but it exceeds one for agents exhibiting first-order loss aversion. Empirical estimates of the loss-aversion ratio are typically in the neighborhood of 2 (corresponding to a weight of   1/ 3 ). Econ 241 A Joshua Aizenman Problem set # 3. Due Date: November 4.

1. The Classical Transfer Problem: Evaluate the welfare effects of increasing the transfer TB in a D-F-S model with non-traded goods. What factors determine the size of the welfare effect? Explain. 2. Chapter #3, question 2. 3. Consider a two period economy. Suppose  is a productivity shock that occurs only in

period one. Then GDP in period i (i = 0, 1) is

1   with probability 0.5 (1) Y0  1; Y1   . 1   with probability 0.5 Collecting taxes is costly: a tax at rate t yields a net tax revenue of

(2) Ti  Yi [t  (t)]; ' 0; " 0. The tax revenue is used to purchase public goods G (like defense, etc.), and to service the outstanding debt. The demand for fiscal services is inelastic:

(3) G0  G1  G .

All agents are risk-neutral:

The emerging market can borrow in international capital markets. It borrows B in period 0 at a contractual rate r and owes (1 r)B in period 2 [assume that the initial debt is zero]. If it faces a bad enough productivity shock in the second period, it defaults. Default is not without penalty, however. International creditors can confiscate some of the emerging market’s export revenues or other resources equal to a share  of its output. The more open the economy, the greater  is likely to be. We assume that the defaulting country’s international reserve holdings are beyond the reach of creditors.2 In period 1, the country repays its international obligations if repayment is less costly than the default penalty. The country ends up transferring S1 real resources to international creditors in the second period, where:

(3) S1  MIN(1 r)B; Y1  , 0    1

Suppose the risk-free interest rate is r f . The interest rate attached to the country’s acquired debt, r , is determined by the condition that the expected return on the debt is equal to the risk- free return:

(4) E[S1 ](1  rf )B

2 This is a realistic assumption. For example, on January 5, 2002, The Economist reported “[President Duhalde] confirmed that Argentina will formally default on its debt, an overdue admission of an inescapable reality. The government has not had access to international credit (except from the IMF) since July. It had already repatriated nearly all of its liquid foreign assets to avoid their seizure by creditors.” (The Economist, p. 29)

  

  a. Find the supply of funds facing the economy. b. Characterize the optimal borrowing and the demand for international reserves for the case

where (1 rf )  1.

Evaluate the impact of lowering  on the optimal demand for B and R. Explain. Problem set # 4. Due Date: Questions 1-2 November 19. Questions 3-4 November 26. 1. Assume a Cagan demand for currency:

(1) m  exp(0   ) . The banking system is competitive, subject to a binding reserve requirement . The real loan interest rate is zero. The nominal interest rate on reserves is zero. The demand for deposits is

(2) d  exp(0  [  id ]) , where id is the deposit nominal interest rate. a. Find the equilibrium id . b. Find the inflation tax collected for given inflation and reserve requirement. c. Find the inflation and the reserve requirement that would maximize the inflation tax. d. Suppose now that the lending interest rate is il   (1  ) ,   0 . What is the economic significance of  . How this will modify your answer to part c? Who is paying the inflation tax? Explain. 2. Find the first order condition characterizing the optimal  CB in the model discussed in section 9.5.2.1. 3. Agents in the emerging market are also risk neutral, having preferences represented by C * V *  C *  2 . The only source of macro uncertainty is the shock,  , to second period output in 1 1   * * * the emerging-market Y 2  Y ( 1   ) where  is governed by the probability density function f (  ) ,       ,   0 . All private agents are price takers. * In period 2, the borrowing country is required to repay its aggregate loan, B 1 , but because of the stochastic output it may default partially. Let S 2 denote the debt repayment to foreign creditors in period 2. In the event of default, creditors are assumed to be able to penalize the borrowing country, *  reducing its net output by Y 2 . The parameter reflects the bargaining power of foreign lenders, indicating that up to a fraction  of output can "confiscated" due to the threat of embargoes, etc. * * Consequently, the effective ceiling on net resource transfers to creditors is: S 2  m i n [ ( 1  r ) B 1 , Y 2 ] . The international credit market is risk neutral, characterized by competition among banks that are fully informed regarding the debt exposure of the country. The risk free interest rate is r*. Partial default by the emerging markets requires that banks should spend real resources  in order to verify the productivity shock and to enforce the repayment. We assume that the partial default decision is centralized, being made and enforced by the policy maker (like the Central Bank or the Treasury), * * who follows the default rule described by S 2  min[(1  r)B1 , Y2 ] . If default would occur, the debt would be serviced by the treasury, imposing the lump sum taxes need to collect * . Y2 a. Find the equilibrium financial spread [i.e. r –r*]. b. Characterize the optimal borrowing from the point of view of a small consumer (recall that each borrower is small, and price taker). c. Extra credit: Consider the case where f( ) is a uniform distribution. Characterize the optimal borrowing from the point of view of the central bank (note that the central bank is not a price taker). Describe policies that may be needed to implement the optimal borrowing. 4. Chapter 6, question #4.

Recommended publications