<<

Labor in the Boardroom

Simon Jäger Benjamin Schoefer Jörg Heining

October 20, 2020

Abstract We estimate the wage effects of shared , or codetermination, in the form of a mandate of one third of corporate board seats going to worker representatives. We study a reform in that abruptly abolished this mandate for corporations incorporated after August 1994, while it locked the mandate for the slightly older cohorts. Our research design compares firm cohorts incorporated before the reform and after; in a robustness check we additionally draw on the analogous difference in unaffected firm types (LLCs). We find no effects of board-level codetermination on wages and the wage structure, even in firms with particularly flexible wages. The degree of rent sharing and the labor are also unaffected. We reject that disinvestment could have offset wage effects through the canonical hold-up channel, as shared governance, if anything, increases formation. JEL codes: J5, J3, G3

Corresponding author: Benjamin Schoefer. Email: [email protected]. Mailing Address: 530 Evans Hall, #3880 Department of of California, Berkeley, Berkeley, CA 94720, USA. Phone: (510) 642- 9104. Fax: (510) 642-6615. Word count (excl. Online Appendix): 21,037. [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. We thank the editor, co-editor, and four anonymous reviewers. We thank Daron Acemoglu, John Addison, Josh Angrist, David Autor, David Card, Jonathan Cohn, Robert Gibbons, Lawrence Katz, Patrick Kline, Bentley MacLeod, Jim Poterba, Fabiano Schivardi, Antoinette Schoar, Andrei Shleifer, Sebastian Siegloch, David Sraer, Jean Tirole, Margarita Tsoutsoura, and John Van Reenen for useful discussions, as well as audiences at the AEA/LERA Meetings, CEPR/LSE Annual Labour Symposium, Columbia University, Columbia Micro Macro Labor Conference, CRC Berlin Workshop on the Future of Labor, CREST, CSEF Conference on Finance, Labor, and Inequality, EIEF, INSEAD, IZA, LSE, MIT Organizational Econ Lunch, NBER Meeting, NBER Summer Institute Labor Studies, SOLE-EALE Meeting, Stanford Labor Seminar, Stanford SIEPR Workshop, Stockholm University, UC Berkeley, UCLA, UC Santa Cruz , UMass Amherst, UBC, U Mannheim, and U Montreal. For sharing their legal expertise, we thank Andreas Engert, Thomas Hoffmann, Marcus Lutter, Sebastian Sick, and Holger Spamann. Karl Aspelund, Nikhil Basavappa, Jonathan Cohen, Dominik Jurek, René Livas, Nelson Mesker, Enrique Perez, Martina Uccioli, and Dalton Zhang provided outstanding research assistance. We thank the MIT Sloan Good , Good Initiative, the UC Berkeley Institute for Research on Labor and , and the Washington Center for Equitable Growth for financial support. By focusing on wage outcomes in the administrative IAB data, this paper differs from a previous version that studied a broader set of financial outcomes in a larger and longer, multi-source Bureau van Dijk sample of firms rather than the IAB sample of firms (see Footnote 34). 1 Introduction

A fundamental question of industrial relations concerns how the institutional form of organi- zation of labor affects wage setting. With shared governance, or codetermination, workers participate in the decision-making of their employer, for example through representation on boards. By contrast, in more adversarial labor relations systems such as in the , workers are largely barred from participation in corporate decision-making. Against the backdrop of rising wage inequality and decline in the labor share, several observers and policy-makers have called for an introduction or expansion of worker board representation as a way to boost worker bargaining power.1 Whether minority board representation actually boosts worker bargaining power remains an open question. Even if it does, it may lead to agency problems, stifle investment, and thus ultimately lower wages (Jensen and Meckling, 1979). An ideal experiment to study the consequences of shared governance for wages would randomly assign the to some firms but prohibit it in others. We provide quasi-experimental evidence on the effects of this form of shared governance by studying a 1994 reform in Germany that sharply abolished worker-elected directors in certain firms, and permanently preserved the mandate in others. Before the law change, all stock corporations (Aktiengesellschaften and Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien) had to apportion at least one third of their seats to worker representatives. These worker board representatives are primarily non-managerial workers, proposed and directly elected by the non-managerial workforce. In two-tier board settings such as Germany’s, the supervisory board appoints, monitors, dismisses, and sets the compensation for the executive board. It is also directly involved in important decisions, such as large investments or outsourcing. Anecdotally, many decisions in the supervisory board are taken unanimously, with consensus between and worker representatives (Gold, 2011; Steger, 2011). In the German industrial relations system, board representation coexists with two other of worker representation. First, unions represent workers in collective bargaining negotiations, determining wage floors and hours, usually at the sector-region level. Second, works councils provide shop-floor representation and a separate form of codetermination, e.g., regarding working conditions or layoff decisions. In many cases, board representatives also serve on works councils. Our paper includes a test for interactions of board representation with these

1Several legislative proposals in the United States Senate would mandate German-style board codetermination. For example, the Reward Act and the Accountable Act would mandate 1/3 or 40%, respectively, of directors of larger corporations to be elected by the workforce. In the United Kingdom, the - commissioned Bullock Report called for worker representation on corporate boards (Report of the Committee of Inquiry on Industrial , 1977). More recently, the Labour Party proposed to mandate one-third codetermination in firms with more than 250 employees (, 09/23/2018). In an MIT Report on the "Work of the Future", Autor, Mindell, and Reynolds (2019) identify "restoring the role of workers as stakeholders, alongside owners and stockholders, in corporate decision-making" as critical to shaping the future of work. In his analysis of capital and ideology, Piketty (2020) argues for an expansion of codetermination rights.

1 two institutions. The 1994 reform abruptly abolished worker-elected directors in new stock corporations (unless firm size crossed a high threshold of 500 employees). Importantly, the cohort-based reform locked in shared governance in the incumbent firm cohorts incorporated before the reform. The sharp law change permits us to identify the effect of shared governance by comparing stock corporations incorporated just before and after the August 1994 cutoff. We implement this design by combining firm-, establishment-, and worker-level data: (i) administrative matched employee-establishment data covering the universe of security records merged with (ii) financial and production data for public and private firms based on Bureau van Dijk (BvD) data, (iii) a comprehensive data set of incorporations and exits, (iv) data on board composition for listed firms and (v) an establishment survey. Our core specifications compare stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window around the reform. Besides a series of validation and robustness checks, our main alternative specification nets out a broad class of cohort or age effects with a second difference among peer cohorts among unaffected corporation types (Gesellschaften mit beschränkter Haftung (GmbH), which we will refer to as companies (LLCs)).2 Our main finding is that mandating shared governance does not lead firms to pay measurably higher wages. We estimate small positive effects on composition-adjusted wage premia at the firm (Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis, 1999, AKM in the following), with point estimates between 0.4% and 2.3%. Confidence intervals rule out AKM pay premia effects above 4% in simple difference specifications, which corresponds to less than one-fifth of the between-firm standard deviation of AKM pay premia. Moreover, the upper bound of 4% for effects on AKM pay premia (and 8% for raw wage effects) allows us to rule out that shared governance entails the large cross-sectional wage premia associated with unions in the US (Farber et al., 2018), but not the substantially smaller wage effects of new unions in the US (DiNardo and Lee, 2004; Frandsen, 2014). Using collective bargaining in Germany as a benchmark, we can rule out some of the larger cross-sectional estimates of pay premia (Dustmann and Schönberg, 2009; Gürtzgen, 2009), but not the smaller OLS estimates of the effect of sectoral bargaining on AKM pay premia (Hirsch and Mueller, 2020). We also do not find effects on the wage structure inside the firm and measures of within-firm pay inequality. We find no evidence for increases in the labor share; if anything, we find (insignificant) decreases by about 0.03 (SE 0.03, control mean: 0.73). We provide three additional analyses to understand the absence of wage effects. First, we reject the possibility that wages did not increase on net because the bargaining power increase was offset by a tantamount decrease in the size of the firm’s pie to be shared, by, much

2German GmbHs are broadly comparable to private limited companies in the United Kingdom or LLCs in the United States. They differ from US LLCs in that they are formally corporations and in that their shares cannot be traded on a .

2 like a distortionary profit , depressing capital formation following the influential hold-up view (Jensen and Meckling, 1979; Grout, 1984). In the data, we find that firms with shared governance produce, if anything, higher output, with an extra added per worker (labor productivity) of 2 to 8%. Specifically rejecting the hold-up mechanism, shared governance leads to larger fixed capital and higher capital-labor ratios.3 Hence, the estimates reject the disinvestment predicted by the hold-up and agency cost views. We also find no evidence for reductions in revenue or employment. Second, we directly estimate and compare rent-sharing elasticities in firms with and without this form of shared governance. We document similar elasticities of wages to firm- level value added per worker, of about 0.07 in our sample. This finding indicates that worker representation does not appear to raise worker bargaining power over wages. Third, we do not find larger effects in industries where works councils are more prevalent, in high-rent industries, or in industries with low coverage of collective bargaining agreements and large revealed wage dispersion. The lack of heterogeneity in wage effects also suggests that our findings may extend beyond institutional settings similar to Germany. A priori, one-third board representation could have affected wages through various concrete channels in addition to raising worker bargaining power (Jensen and Meckling, 1979; Grout, 1984). For example, worker representatives could have pushed for the selection of labor- friendly managers (Bertrand and Schoar, 2003) or changed pay equity norms (Western and Rosenfeld, 2011). They could have affected firms’ decision to accede to or opt out of collective bargaining agreements (CBA), decisions in which supervisory boards can be involved (see Schnabel and Wagner, 1996, for a survey on CBA coverage and worker representation). The full information rights of the board members could have improved workers’ and works councils’ wage negotiation outcomes (Addison, Teixeira, and Zwick, 2010), for example as even worker board representatives who also serve on the works council report an information advantage by virtue of their board membership (see interviews with German representatives in Gold, Kluge, and Conchon, 2010).4 By facilitating cooperation, by institutionalizing communication, or through repeated interactions between labor and capital, shared governance could have helped overcome hold-up and raise productivity and, in turn, wages through rent sharing (Malcomson, 1983; Crawford, 1988; Freeman and Medoff, 1985; Freeman and Lazear, 1995). In practice, most supervisory board decisions are unanimous (Gold, 2011; Steger, 2011), leaving room for real authority even absent formal majority rights (Aghion and Tirole, 1997). We

3Our evidence against hold-up effects is consistent with (Machin and Wadhwani, 1991; Addison et al., 2007; Card, Devicienti, and Maida, 2014), even though some studies document negative investment effects of unionization (e.g., Connolly, Hirsch, and Hirschey, 1986; Hirsch, 2004). In the context of codetermination via works councils, Addison et al. (2007) finds no association with lower investment. Rapp et al. (2019) find positive effects of board representation based on a propensity score matching strategy among listed firms. 4This mechanism may be especially relevant when CBA opening clauses allow for local wage negotia- tion, or among firms not part of a CBA so that works councils are directly involved in wage setting (§87, Betriebsverfassungsgesetz).

3 discuss potential institutional explanations for the empirical absence of wage effects in the conclusion. Consistent with the absence of wage increases and of negative effects on firm performance, we find no evidence for higher or lower profitability, in contrast to some evidence for negative profit effects of firm-level unionization in adversarial settings (see, e.g., Lee and Mas, 2012). We caveat that our data do not contain payouts, as most of the stock corporations are not publicly traded. Similarly, firm owners do not appear to strategically avoid the institution by delaying incorporating or shifting corporate form, all consistent with owners reporting that one-third representation does not substantially affect choices (Albach et al., 1988). Our quasi-experimental research design complements studies comparing German firms with and without codetermination using size cutoffs on non-wage outcomes. Gorton and Schmid (2004), Kim, Maug, and Schneider (2018) and Redeker (2019) study large, publicly traded corporations at the 2,000 employee threshold, which delineates one-third and quasi- parity employee representation (in the latter group, shareholder representatives still break ties). Compared to these studies, our variation has no worker-elected directors in the control group. Our cohort-based variation also circumvents endogenous contemporaneous employment as an assignment variable, which is transitory exactly around the threshold. Instead, our variation draws on persistent regimes, sharply assigned by incorporation date. By contrast, Svejnar (1981) analyzes the effect of the introduction of parity codetermination in 1951 in the iron, steel and mining sector compared to unaffected industries, finding a 6% wage effect on sector-level average wages on the basis of industry wage tabulations; FitzRoy and Kraft (1993) study the effect of the 1976 introduction of quasi-parity representation and find small effects on labor costs per employee. Our study of board-level representation (see Scholz and Vitols, 2019, for a review) complements studies of plant-level works councils (e.g., Addison, Schnabel, and Wagner, 2001; Addison, 2009). In Section 2, we describe the institutional context and the reform. Section 3 presents our data sets. Section 4 assesses the validity of the design by measuring avoidance, exit, and entry effects. Our main findings on wage setting are reported in Section 5. Heterogeneity analyses guided by a bargaining model are presented in Section 6. Section 7 concludes.

2 Institutional Context and the 1994 Reform

We describe shared in Germany, and the 1994 abolition of board-level representation in most new stock corporations. We also review wage setting institutions.

4 2.1 Shared Corporate Governance in Germany

Corporate Governance in Germany Like many other European countries, Germany has a two-tier board system, an executive and a supervisory board, illustrated in Figure I. The executive board is the managing body and responsible for day-to-day . The supervisory board – composed of representatives for and, in many cases, workers – is responsible for the selection, monitoring, auditing, compensation structuring, and dismissal of the executive board (§§ 84, 87 and 111 AktG). The German Corporate Governance Code advises that the supervisory board be involved in all decisions of fundamental importance to the company, e.g., strategic planning and larger financial decisions. For instance, corporate frequently prescribe thresholds above which investments need to be directly approved by the supervisory board. The supervisory board is also often involved in large decisions that are directly relevant to wage setting, such as whether the company joins an employer association or not (and thereby accedes to collective bargaining agreements). Anecdotally, votes on the supervisory board are often unanimous even with worker representatives (Gold, 2011; Steger, 2011).

Shared Governance: Works Councils Two institutions allow for worker representation in employers’ decision-making: shop-floor codetermination through works councils and board-level codetermination on the supervisory board. Works councils (for recent studies, see Addison, Schnabel, and Wagner, 2001; Addison, 2009) are a shop-floor representation institution and have extensive consultation, information, and codetermination rights in areas such as work hours, occupational safety, and organizational or staffing changes, and can directly negotiate with the employer, including over . This institution goes back to the early 1900s. The role of works councils is regulated in the Establishments Constitution Act (BetrVG). In establishments with more than five employees, workers have the right to organize in a works council; multi-establishment firms that have plant-level works councils additionally coordinate via a firm-level variant. In Section 6.5, we will investigate whether codetermination through board representation interacts with the prevalence of works councils; yet, our design cannot provide estimates of the independent effect of works councils on wages.

Shared Governance: Board Representation The variation we study concerns mandates for firm-level codetermination on the supervisory board, an institution introduced in the early years of the Federal Republic of Germany (see Scholz and Vitols, 2019, for another review).5 Importantly for our study, the codetermination mandates differ by legal form

5The historical context was favorable for shared governance because, while industry leaders had collaborated with the National Socialist regime, the workers’ movement was less tainted. Shared governance was also viewed as an acceptable compromise to many firm owners in light of episodes in the United Kingdom (McGaughey, 2017).

5 and incorporation date (and also employee count). The board seats allocated to worker representatives range from zero to full parity. In 1951, the first landmark act mandated supervisory board parity in the mining, coal, and steel sectors for firms with more than 1,000 employees. In 1952, the second landmark act introduced the one-third mandate for corporations. This mandate exempted -owned firms and firms with fewer than 500 (today: 501) employees unless they are stock corporations not 100% owned by one family. In the 1960s, the union movement began pushing for further expansion of worker rep- resentation, and the social-liberal coalition passed the 1976 codetermination law (MitbestG), which mandated quasi-parity in non-mining/steel sectors for firms with more than 2,000 employees: workers elect 50% of the seats (quasi-parity), but the chairperson, who is generally a shareholder representative, can break ties. Worker board representatives are elected by the firm’s non-managerial workforce in general, secret, equal and usually direct , organized through the works council.6 Worker board representatives typically also serve on the works council. Once elected, the worker representatives are co-equal directors with the shareholder representatives. All (or, for larger firms, the majority) of the worker representatives on the supervisory board must be employees of the firm. For larger firms with larger boards, the union can nominate additional external candidates (§ 7 MitbestG, § 4 DrittelbG). Though not required by law, a large share of worker-elected directors are union members (Addison, 2009). Unions and associated also offer training programs for worker representatives on supervisory boards. As a result of these laws, in firms with 501 to 2,000 employees, workers elect one third of the seats no matter the legal form. We will find that fewer than 10% of firms cross the 500 threshold in our analysis sample. All other firms cannot have worker board representatives below this 500 threshold. Starting 1952, there was a single exception to the exemption from board representation even for the vast majority of firms below 501 employees: stock corporations were mandated to have one-third representation no matter their size, even though, we show, the vast majority of stock corporations are below this threshold. We exploit the sudden abolition of this mandate for newly incorporated stock corporations described below. Hence, the variation we study is between mandates for zero or one-third worker-elected directors among stock corporations. Figure I illustrates corporate governance with one-third (Panel (a)) or no worker participation (Panel (b)).

6In firms with more than 2,000 employees, the managerial workforce also participates in the elections and sends at least one representative (§ 15 MitbestG).

6 2.2 1994 Abolition of Shared Governance in New Stock Corporations

Since 1952, stock corporations had been required to have at least one-third worker representa- tion on the supervisory board regardless of size. A 1994 reform of the Stock Corporation Act (Aktiengesetz) and the Works Constitution Act (Betriebsverfassungsgesetz) abruptly abolished this requirement for newly incorporated stock corporations while preserving it in existing ones.7 The law was a result of a last-minute political compromise and did not affect LLCs or other features of shared governance. The goal pursued by abolishing codetermination in stock corporations was to harmonize the rules for stock corporations with those of LLCs. Figure II Panel (a) illustrates the reform-induced changes in the mandate as a function of a firm’s incorporation date. These differences in the mandate by incorporation date continue to the present.

Abolition in Stock Corporations Founded after August 10th, 1994 The reform abolished the one-third mandate only for new stock corporations: those incorporated on or after August 10, 1994. As a consequence of the reform, new stock corporations smaller than 501 employees cannot have any worker-elected board members, as the leaves no room for choice (see, e.g., Raiser, Veil, and Jacobs, 2015, § 1 Rn. 26, § 23 (5), and § 96 AktG).8 Figure I Panel (b) illustrates corporate governance in these corporations without the mandate. Upon having 501 employees, both cohorts face the same one-third mandate.9

Political Compromise: Grandfathering of Codetermination in Existing Firm Cohorts Im- portantly, the law locked in the one-third worker representation mandate in already founded stock corporations. This cohort-specific grandfathering rule arose as a last-minute political compromise in late May 1994, between the conservative-liberal governing coalition, between Christian Democrats (CDU/CSU) and Free Democrats (FDP), and the center-left opposi- tion Social Democrats (SPD), who held a majority in the upper chamber (Bundesrat). The conservative-liberal government had proposed to abolish shared governance in all stock corporations (up to 500 employees), including existing ones, to harmonize rules between stock corporations and LLCs and to deregulate and simplify the corporate and codetermination law. By contrast, the opposition had been in favor of maintaining shared governance for all stock corporations – new and old. A key rationale for the cohort-based compromise was

7See BGBl. I 1994 p. 1961. Today, the grandfathering rule with the 1994 cutoff is part of the One-Third Participation Act (Drittelbeteiligungsgesetz), which in 2004 subsumed the relevant parts of the Works Constitution Act. 8In principle, LLCs could add additional worker representatives exceeding the fractions mandated by law, although anecdotal evidence suggests that this is not common. In any case, rules for LLCs were not changed by the 1994 reform. 9For the vast majority of firms, the 500 employment cutoff is not binding. Among stock corporations incorporated after the reform, fewer than 7% of firms reach the 500 employee threshold using IAB employment data (and fewer than 1% among the LLCs).

7 that existing companies were believed to have already learned to operate under the mandate. Upon reaching the political compromise, the law was then promptly passed in both chambers in the subsequent weeks, and mandated a cutoff date of August 10, 1994, the day after the law’s promulgation.10

Rigidity of the Cohort-Based Lock-In Notably, grandfathered stock corporations incor- porated just before August 10, 1994 cannot simply escape the shared governance mandate by re-incorporating. Specifically, a change of legal form and temporally connected re- incorporation of an old stock corporation as an ostensibly new stock corporation does not invalidate the mandate for board representation of workers.11 The 1994 grandfathering rule has been challenged in legal cases brought by shareholders of older corporations on the grounds that the arbitrary nature of the cutoff date violates the constitutional principle of equality. However, the courts have upheld the clause, including the Federal Constitutional Court as recently as 2014 (BVerfG, 09.01.2014, Az. 1 BvR 2344/11).

Secondary and Non-Grandfathered Elements of the Reform In addition to shared gover- nance, the 1994 law changed several other rules in the Stock Corporation Act (e.g., use of profits, general shareholder meetings), all of which applied regardless of the incorporation date and hence had no grandfathering – such that they would affect both cohort groups and hence be netted out in our difference between stock old and young stock corporations. Crucially, only the shared governance setup was grandfathered in for existing corporations. Moreover, the additional features of the 1994 reform were considered secondary to the abolition of shared governance by commentators.12 In principle, such non-grandfathered features could still have effects in our research design if they affected the quantity or composition of post-1994 entrants. In Section 4, we will directly assess these potential confounders, and empirically find that the reform had no detectable effects on these margins. From that perspective, the broader

10The initially proposed bill and compromise committee recommendation are reported in Drucksache 12/6721 and 12/7848 (Deutscher Bundestag, 1994), the minutes of plenary proceedings in Plenarprotokoll 12/233 and 12/237 (Stenographischer Bericht, Deutscher Bundestag, 1994). 11See, for example, Raiser, Veil, and Jacobs (2015) § 1 Rn. 5. Re-incorporations as corporations according to European law (SE) also entail a grandfathering rule such that employee representation is preserved, even if the corporation adopts a unitary board structure (§ 21 (6) SEBG). In theory, re-incorporation as LLCs could undo the grandfathering rule (although LLCs can also opt to keep workers on the board). During our sample period, re-incorporation as an LLC requires at least 75% of shareholder votes (§ 240 (1) UmwG), although additional requirements apply in certain cases (§ 242 UmwG). We did not identify cases where stock corporations switched corporate form to an LLC to evade the grandfathering rule. Likewise, the legal practitioners we consulted deemed this scenario unlikely due to, among other reasons, switching costs. On aggregate, such evasion behavior would show up as increased exits, which we do not detect in our survival analysis in Figure III Panel (c) described in Section 4. 12For example, the Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, a newspaper of record in Germany, considered the changes irrelevant except for the codetermination reform (“Nicht nur weiße Salbe”, Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, May 27, 1994, p. 13).

8 motivation surrounding the reform to spur among stock corporations is not borne out in the data (and in any case, our research design would net out any common effects on both older and younger stock corporations).

2.3 Wage Setting in Germany

The German labor features considerable scope for firm-level wage setting, such that in principle shared governance could affect the wage setting of the treated firms compared to control firms. Sectoral bargaining, usually at the sector-state level, where unions negotiate wage floors, hours and working conditions with employer associations, leaves substantial scope for firm-specific deviations. Most importantly, covered employers can always deviate upwards (Günstigkeitsprinzip, § 4 (3) TVG). Moreover, collective bargaining coverage has decreased substantially while the prevalence of opening clauses, allowing individual firms and workers to negotiate wages lower than those in the CBA, has risen (Hassel, 1999; Brändle, Heinbach, and Maier, 2011). Hence, worker representatives on the works council (who are typically also board directors in case a firm is subject to board codetermination) are directly involved in wage negotiations among firms that are not part of a collective bargaining agreement (§87, Betriebsverfassungsgesetz) and in firms taking advantage of a CBA opening clause. Consistent with considerable scope for firm-level wage setting, there is large between-firm dispersion in wage premia even within industries (Card, Heining, and Kline, 2013). Similarly, idiosyncratic shocks to localities or firms, e.g., changes or labor supply shocks, affect wages (Fuest, Peichl, and Siegloch, 2018; Jäger and Heining, 2019). In the introduction, we have reviewed concrete channels through which board representation can affect firm-level wages. In our rent sharing analysis, we estimate the effect of firm-specific productivity on firm-level wages in the German context controlling for industry effects. We further analyze potential interdepencies between board-level codetermination and the two other forms of worker involvement in wage setting, through collective bargaining agreements and works councils.

3 Data and Sample Construction

Matched Firm-Establishment-Worker Data: Orbis-ADIAB Our main dataset is adminis- trative employer-employee data from IAB merged with Bureau van Dijk Orbis (BvD) firm-level data (Antoni et al., 2018).13 The matched employer-employee data are based on social security records and cover the universe of jobs subject to social security contributions from 1975 to 2014. In the matched

13By focusing on wage outcomes in the administrative IAB data, this paper differs from a previous version that studied a broader set of financial outcomes in a larger and longer, multi-source Bureau van Dijk sample of firms rather than the IAB sample of firms. Footnote 34 summarizes the robustness of the main results.

9 employer-employee data, we keep full-time workers aged 20-60. The data consist of day- specific spells. We drop spells with less than 1 EUR per day. In each calendar year, we keep one spell per worker, specifically the one with the highest total annual earnings. Our IAB employment measure refers to these worker-firm matches. Our wage concept is the daily wage (total earnings divided by number of days of the spell) of these full-time workers, which we deflate using the 2015 CPI. The BvD data are balance sheets and income statements based on official company registers, company reports, and information from credit rating agencies. The Orbis-ADIAB version covers 2006 through 2014. The BvD data contains the information about legal form and incorporation of the firm. We deflate all BvD nominal variables with the 2015 CPI. The matching of IAB and BvD data was conducted via establishment-level record linkage from 2006 to 2014. The match rate for stock corporations is the highest among all legal forms at 70.34% (Antoni et al., 2018).

Analysis Sample Our sample consists of stock corporations (and, as an additional control group for a difference-in-differences analysis, LLCs) incorporated from 1989 through 1999 – five years around the August 1994 reform cutoff. Our main specification will apply a bandwidth of two years around the reform, and we will explore robustness to the full set of bandwidths within the five-year window, as well as donut hole specifications. For our wage analyses, we draw on data starting the calendar year after a firm’s incorporation. We detail the two assignment variables of our design, legal form and incorporation date, as well as further sample restrictions below.

Incorporation Date We use the exact date of incorporation based on an additional data delivery from BvD. We also draw on additional BvD waves to assign each firm the earliest date reported across all BvD waves.14 The standard BvD incorporation date is the establishment date of its corporate (Feststellung der Satzung). The date relevant to the 1994 reform cutoff, however, is the entry into the Commercial Register (Handelsregister), which in the 1990s occurred sometimes up to a few months afterward. We merge on this information from the BvD Dafne data set; for the unmatched firms, we keep the original incorporation date.15 In the 1990s, the register

14We draw on the Amadeus/Orbis June 2020 version of the Wharton Research Data Services (which is a panel data set going back multiple years for each firm). Since the IAB version of the BvD data covers 2006-2014, we additionally obtain historical BvD waves by drawing on the Orbis Historical product and from the LMU-ifo Economics & Business Data Center (EBDC). 15Even in the case of divergence in the merged sample, the register date is always later than the charter BvD date, suggesting that larger deviations are due to re-incorporations. Importantly, as described in Section 2.2, old stock corporations cannot escape the mandate by re-incorporating as a new stock corporation after 1994, so such cases leave out assignment of firms into treatment and control groups intact. Hence, for any firms for which we cannot merge on the register date, the BvD date remains the relevant binding date and we correctly classify these

10 entry was delayed by around two to four months after the charter date, so we replace it if the gap is at most one year, to ensure sharpness of our local design at the policy threshold.16 In our empirical design, we address any remaining mismeasurement concerns with robustness checks in the form of donut hole specifications and varying the bandwidths around the reform date.

Legal Form We keep stock corporations (Aktiengesellschaften and Kommanditgesellschaften auf Aktien) and LLCs (Gesellschaft mit beschränkter Haftung), using the BvD legal form variable.17

Further Sample Restrictions We implement additional sample restrictions. First, we exclude firms in industries exempt from codetermination.18 We additionally drop a handful of specific firms based on a firm-by-firm review of stock corporations and a string-search algorithm of both stock corporations and LLCs.19 Second, we drop firms with in East Germany to drop entrants following of the reunification in 1990 to avoid potentially unrepresentative selection due to, e.g., of formerly state-owned firms. Third, we drop firm-years with fewer than 10 full-time employees in the IAB data.

Intent-To-Treat Interpretation Our reduced form design will yield intent-to-treat estimates as by its nature it must not condition on time-varying endogenous firm characteristics that affect codetermination rules. First, we do not condition on employment, in particular not restricting the sample to firms with fewer than 501 employees. This share is low even among stock corporations (incorporated after the reform, i.e. a control mean), fewer than 7% of firms

firms. 16We thank Thomas Hoffmann for an email correspondence regarding the typical delay between charter and Commercial Register entry among Vor-AGs and Vor-GmbHs in the 1990s. 17The Orbis-IAB data set reports only one legal form per firm. For firms for which we have legal form information pre-2006 (the year the ORBIS-IAB data starts) in our external historical BvD data described in Footnote 14, we use the earliest reported legal form. 18We use the BvD industry code and assign the firm its modal primary industry code in the case of panel variation, and replace missing primary industry information with secondary industry codes. We drop firms without any industry information. Legally, § 1 (2) DrittelbG exempts enterprises that predominantly pursue political, coalitional (labor or employer representation), religious, charitable, educational, scientific or artistic goals as well as media organizations. We drop firms with the following NACE codes: utilities (35-39), rail (490-492), media (5813, 60), education and scientific activities (72, 85, excluding driving and flying schools (8553)), and public administration (84, 99), charities (87, 88), membership organizations (94) and household activities (97, 98). 19We generate this drop list in an external BvD data set described in Footnote 14 and then merge it on the ORBIS-ADIAB data set in an anonymized process. Namely, we drop a small number of firms we identify as associated with formerly publicly owned firms (telecommunication, railway, postal services), which were privatized in the mid-1990s, public savings and , holdings, and strings associated with nonprofits ("e.V." and "gemeinn"), as well as of older firms, media companies (using string search), and utilities-related string searches. In a previous version of the paper, we further dropped state-owned firms based on BvD data outside of the ORBIS-IAB data set. Since this test only dropped one stock corporation (after having restricted the sample as described above) and since the ownership information is imperfect, we do not impose this additional restriction.

11 reach the 500 (IAB) employee threshold (and fewer than 1% among the LLCs). This small share of firms that cross the threshold are simply always-takers (in the sense of having board-level codetermination regardless of the incoporation date). We do not find evidence for changes in the probability of crossing the 501 employee threshold. Second, and relatedly, we do not condition on membership in a as individual firms may be part of a corporate group that is subject to codetermination. Only 10.7% of our stock corporation control group are part of such a corporate group and we find no evidence that older stock corporations are more likely to be part of a corporate group sufficiently large (2001 and larger) to automatically trigger codetermination for all group members. Finally, we do not condition on whether firms are fully owned by one family. Legally, fully family-owned stock corporations smaller than 500 employees are exempt from codetermination. We do not apply this test because in a previous version of the paper we estimated (constructing family ownership on the basis of owners’ last names in the BvD ownership data) that only 10% of our control stock corporations fulfill the strict criteria: in contrast to the usual definitions of family firms (at 50% of direct ownership by a family), the codetermination law requires 100% of direct and indirect family ownership. Since ownership structure and specifically concentration of large shareholders is a potentially time-varying outcome itself, we do not apply this test. Overall, our results thus have an intent-to-treat, reduced-form interpretation with a group of never-takers (fully family-owned firms) as well as always-takers (firms that grow above 500 employees or are part of a large corporate group with codetermination).

Winsorization We winsorize all continuous variables at the 1% level separately by calendar year. Before winsorizing, we set BvD variables to missing if spuriously negative (e.g., fixed assets and value added, but not, e.g., profits).

Entrants & Exits: Mannheim Enterprise Panel (MUP) We use firm panel data from the Mannheim Enterprise Panel (provided by ZEW, Mannheim, see Bersch et al., 2014) to comprehensively study incorporations and exits from 1991 onward (provided by Creditreform e.V., Germany’s largest , based on official registers). Data access is only permitted in the research data center, and we cannot merge this data with our ORBIS-ADIAB data set. We apply similar industry tests as before; we do not impose the restriction of the sample to West Germany. Since core outcome variables are not reported in the early years in which we do not have Bureau van Dijk coverage, we do not use the MUP data to study outcomes.

Worker Supervisory Board Representation: Hoppenstedt Aktienführer While our sample of BvD firms does come with some board membership information), it does not differentiate between worker and shareholder representatives. To provide one intervention check that the

12 reform shifts board composition, we draw on the Hoppenstedt Aktienführer covering all listed German firms and covering 1979 to 2015.20

IAB Establishment Panel To assess effect heterogeneity by the prevalence of works council as well as the extent to which collective bargaining agreements bind in an industry, we draw on the IAB Establishment Panel (Fischer et al., 2008). The IAB Establishment Panel is an annual survey of 16,000 establishments from all sectors and size categories. We use the waves starting 2008 for industry classifications consistent with the BvD panel, weighting establishments by employment. IAB data protection rules prohibit us from merging this survey with our ORBIS-ADIAB data set.

Summary Statistics Since all variables are potential outcome variables (as treatment is assigned at the date of incorporation), we report control means in each regression column (separately for stock corporations and LLCs incorporated after the reform).

4 No Effects on Avoidance and Firm Exit

We test for threats to identification, and answer the substantive questions whether firm owners evade shared governance by retiming incorporations or switching corporate form, and whether the institution affects firm exits.

Strategic Delay of Incorporation: McCrary Test Firms might delay incorporation date around the reform cutoff date. Our first check is a visual inspection of the incorporation fre- quency of stock corporations around the reform cutoff (Figure III Panel (a)). This analysis uses our Orbis-ADIAB analysis sample. The figure reveals no evidence of a spike in incorporations after August 10, 1994, nor of a missing mass of incorporations leading up to the reform. In the same figure, we formally implement a McCrary (2008) test of continuity of the density against the alternative of a jump in the density function at the reform cutoff date, for which we find no evidence (0.439, SE 0.628).21 Several institutional features render these two types of substitution unlikely a priori, as discussed in Section 2. The grandfathering was an unexpected political compromise, with no clear advance indication that strategic delay of incorporation would relax the firm’s mandate. In addition, the legislative process was finalized within weeks of reaching the compromise and mandated the day after the law’s promulgation as a cutoff date.

20The historical Hoppenstedt Aktienführer data have been digitized through a project by the German Research Foundation (DFG) and were retrieved from https://digi.bib.uni-mannheim.de/aktienfuehrer/. 21Appendix Figure A.1 conducts this test in the Mannheim Enterprise Panel, which contains comprehensive data on entrants (rather than survivors in the Orbis-ADIAB data) from 1991 onward.

13 Composition of New Firms by Legal Form Relatedly, more firms may substitute into the legal form of stock corporation after the reform rather than an LLC. Figure III Panel (b) plots the percentage of stock corporations against time of incorporation in a sample of both LLCs and stock corporations. The probability of incorporating as a stock corporation did not change discontinuously around the reform cutoff date. In addition, we test less locally whether the reform affected substitution in terms of legal form in our sample window. To this end, we regress an indicator for incorporation as a stock corporation on a post-reform indicator, a time trend, and the interaction of the two. We find a small, secular trend towards incorporating as a stock corporation, but we do not detect a level shift or trend change between the pre- and post-reform period (see Figure III Panel (b) and Appendix Table A.1). This finding implies that the reform overall, which in part aimed to encourage entrepreneurship in stock corporations, did not appear to have spurred a higher quantity of entrants into this legal form.22

Selection Test: Industry Composition Our design cannot test for selection by studying observables of firms because these are outcome variables potentially affected by the reform. Instead, we study one perhaps less mutable outcome determined at entry and hence indicative of selection, namely industry composition. We consider a firm’s industry (17 industry NACE Level-1 codes) as binary outcome variables. We study simple difference effects between stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window before and after the 1994 reform. We also study the double difference, comparing the difference in industry composition between stock corporations incorporated before and after the reform to that for LLCs (which were not affected by the reform and are a second control group), as well as a regression discontinuity approach; we formally describe these regression specifications below in Section 5. We report results based on the Orbis-ADIAB data for each industry in Appendix Figure A.2, with detailed regression results in Appendix Table A.2. The reform did not statistically significantly affect the industry composition of firms; the coefficients are jointly insignificant in an F-test (p  0.384, p  0.396 and p  0.828, respectively, for the three approaches). This test also rules out spurious composition effects from, e.g., business cycles or trends around the reform cutoff.23 22This finding is also consistent with a survey sampling stock corporations founded between 1994 and 1996 (Schawilye, Gaugler, and Keese, 1999). The reported top reasons for incorporating as a stock corporation rather than an LLC are: (1) image and public relations concerns (high prestige of stock corporations), (2) raising capital, (3) corporate , (4) generational change and transfer of ownership. 23We also study composition effects in the universe of entrants, using the Mannheim Enterprise Panel (MUP, see Appendix Figure A.1 Panel (b)). Here, we find no statistically significant effects for 15 of the 17 industries. The two exceptions are a small reduction in communications and a small increase in finance/ firms, and the F-test indicates significant effects (p < 0.01). These mild composition effects in the comprehensive MUP population may not show up in our Orbis-ADIAB analysis sample because of the additional sample restrictions we apply in the latter (at least ten employees, West German location, active in some year from 2006 onward, dropping industries not subject to codetermination). Alternatively, exits may have ironed out initial composition

14 Attrition: Effects on Firm Survival To rule out selective attrition – and as an outcome variable in its own right – we estimate effects on firm exit. Here, we draw on the comprehensive information on all firm incorporations in Germany from 1991 onward (from the Mannheim Enterprise Panel, while our BvD data consist of survivors’ panels from future years). Figure III Panel (c) plots the survival probability of stock corporations by incorporation date, grouped within a two-year window before the reform (“Old”) and after (“Young”). Across groups, around 50% of firms exist at age 20. Survival rates are very similar albeit slightly lower among the younger stock corporation cohorts, if anything, suggesting that shared governance raises firms’ resilience. However, first, we find that these slight differences completely disappear after age five, as illustrated in Appendix Figure A.3 Panel (a). That is, conditional on firms surviving to year five, survival functions are identical. Second, even in the early years, the survival is not differentially lower or higher for old and young stock corporations when compared to the same cohort difference within LLCs, a placebo group, which was not exposed to the 1994 reform (which only changed codetermination rules for stock corporation cohorts). We also plot these lines in Panel (c). As a complement, we report the corresponding difference-in-differences estimates on the exit probability (one minus survival probability) by firm age in Appendix Figure A.3 Panel (b). The confidence interval confidently includes zero even 20 years out (similarly for cumulative probability of exiting by , the only subcategory of exit the MUP data separate out). In any case, our analysis will always separately present simple differences between cohorts of stock corporations as well as the difference-in-differences with LLCs, and our results will be robust to either specification. In sum, we do not find evidence for differential attrition from shared governance. This result is also of substantive interest, revealing that shared governance does not appear to affect firm survival.

Validation Test: Realized Shifts in Worker Representation A potential explanation for the absence of avoidance behavior could be that the reform had no bite and, in fact, did not shift the presence of workers on corporate boards. We now verify that the reform did shift worker representation by incorporation date. Figure II Panel (b) shows the empirical share of workers on the supervisory board by incorporation date and firm size. We draw on data from the Hoppenstedt Aktienführer, which lists supervisory board members and incorporation year for the subset of listed stock corporations. We restrict the sample to stock corporations founded between 1989 and 1999 for which board composition data is reported.24 (navy-colored) and right (red) bar pairs represent corporations incorporated before or after 1994. For firms with fewer than 500 employees (in dark shades, for which the reform changed differences in our Orbis-ADIAB time, which starts in 2006. 24Specifically, we only consider firm-year observations with data on the role (chair person, worker representative, etc.) of individual supervisory board members is reported for at least one third of the supervisory board. We rely on data from the 1990s due to a structural break in reporting in 2000. We exclude firms incorporated in 1994 (as the incorporation date is annual) and East Germany. We do not impose additional sample restrictions.

15 the rules), there is a stark difference: workers hold 29.9% of the seats in stock corporations incorporated before 1994; in sharp contrast, worker representatives hold only 3.0% of the seats in stock corporations founded after 1994. The non-zero worker share is likely due to a small amount of measurement error as the employment concepts for codetermination and in the Hoppenstedt data might differ slightly. The lighter shades report analogous outcomes for very large firms, for which the mandate did not change and for which the data show no difference in worker representation – both around one third – confirming that the comparison is not driven by shifts in reporting or data quality after 1994.

Employer Attitudes Towards Board-Level Representation We close with a discussion of existing work on employers’ and managers’ views towards board-level codetermination. A body of work from the varieties of capitalism literature has argued that employers have embraced codetermination as a competitive advantage through its facilitation of cooperation (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Thelen, 1991). Historically, the original introduction of board-level representation in the Weimar Republic was heavily opposed by parts of the workers’ movement and the parties of the far left (Winkler, 1998); later, the Social Democrats and the largest unions unsuccessfully opposed the introduction of one-third codetermination in post-war Germany, the institution we study, as they viewed the institution as too favorable to the capital side (McGaughey, 2017). Regarding the more recent past, a meta-study of survey evidence and media statements has documented considerable support for board-level codetermination among individual managers and firms along with more negative views from employer associations (Paster, 2012).25 In a survey of firms incorporated before the 1994 reform and thus directly related to our sample, Albach et al. (1988) find that codetermination in the supervisory board is generally not seen as an impediment to incorporation as a stock corporation. Rather, the surveyed firms generally accept shared governance, in particular because of the information and specific knowledge about the firm that worker representatives bring to the board room, and oppose the abolition of shared governance.

5 Effects on Wages, Wage Policies, and Wage Structure

We introduce our research design studying the wage effects of shared governance with a detailed analysis of raw wages. We then report results on wages adjusted for worker demographics, on firms’ pay premia net of worker selection, and on the wage structure inside the firm. 25Paster (2012) argues that employer associations may have an incentive to strategically overstate the concerns of their dissatisfied members. For the context of works councils, Müller and Stegmaier (2020) provide evidence that employer associations may resist expansions of codetermination even though employee participation may entail, on average, positive effects on productivity or profits.

16 5.1 Raw Worker-Level Wages

Cohort Graphs by Calendar Time Figure IV Panel (a) nonparametrically plots raw worker- level log wages separately for treated and control firm cohorts against calendar time. The figure first averages worker-level wages at the firm-year level, and then at the group-year level. The comparison is between stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window before the reform and hence with a shared governance mandate ("Old Stock Corporations," plotted in navy circles with a solid line) and those in a two-year window after ("Young," plotted in red hollow circles with a dashed line). For most of the years, the two lines lie on top of each other, indicating no discernible wage differences. Before 1999 a small positive difference is visible. Around 2009, the older stock corporations see a larger real wage increase of about 5 log points and thereafter continue to evolve in parallel. This simple plot of raw data is direct nonparametric evidence that shared governance does not appear to substantially raise wages. The Orbis-ADIAB data set has the fullest coverage between 2006 and 2014, i.e. the years during which the linkage between the BvD firms and the IAB matched employer-employee data was performed year-by-year. The matched employee-establishment (IAB) component of the merged Orbis-ADIAB data set goes back earlier than the BvD Orbis outcomes, permitting us to study the firms already between their incorporation time and 2006, namely for those establishments subsequently present during the linkage period as described in Section 3. As a result, coverage declines for the earlier years with perhaps some positive selection of surviving establishments, which likely explains why the figure suggests stagnant real wages before 2006. In the figure and throughout our analysis below, we simply keep those early years. First, any such selection does not appear cohort-specific as we confirm with a placebo group below. Second, we did not find differential attrition based on comprehensive data from incorporation onward in Section 4. Third, we will show robustness of wage results to restricting the sample to 2006 and 2014 (the coverage years for BvD outcomes such as value added or fixed assets) in Section 6.

Additional Control Group: LLCs Secular trends in wages by incorporation date but unre- lated to shared governance could mask a treatment effect. We rule out this concern by netting out incorporation time effects with a control group of unaffected legal forms (LLCs), plotted in Panel (a) in navy and hollow red triangles.26 While LLC wages are lower overall, there is no visually detectable difference in the level and evolution of log wages comparing older and younger LLCs.

26Section 4 showed that the reform did not shift the frequency of incorporations across legal forms, both on average and across different industries.

17 Cohort Graphs by Date of Incorporation Figure IV Panel (b) plots averages of firm-level log wages across all calendar years, but organized in more granular, quarter-of-incorporation cohorts and in a wider sample range of five rather than two years around the reform date. Stock corporations exhibit no clear shift in the wage level on either side of the policy discontinuity, neither locally nor for farther-away observations. The graph also reveals no differential trends, suggesting that a bandwidth choice is unlikely to affect an estimate of the wage effect, as we confirm below. The graph also includes a local linear regression line with a two-year bandwidth and a uniform kernel separately on either side of the policy discontinuity; we discuss the regression discontinuity results below. We again include LLCs as a control group. Their bins are less dispersed due to the substantially larger sample size. LLCs do not exhibit a trend or trend break around the policy discontinuity either.

Regression Evidence We now formally estimate treatment effect of shared governance. We start with a simple difference regression among stock corporations:

 + Diff · ( ) + + Yf t α γ 1 IncDate f < 0 X0f t β  f t , (1) where Yf t denotes the outcome for firm f in year t (as we stack the firm panel data) and Diff IncDate f denotes its incorporation date relative to August 10, 1994. We report results for γˆ in Table I, Panel A, Column (1) including year fixed effects and industry-year fixed effects as control variables X f t. The year or industry-year fixed effects also ensure that only observations from years in which we observe both slightly older and younger stock corporations will be used for identification of the treatment effect. Our main specification uses a two-year window around the reform. Here we find point estimates ranging between 0.025 (SE 0.039) and -0.012 (SE 0.041). The confidence intervals include zero and allow us to reject effects on mean wages larger than 0.10 or lower than -0.09. The stability of the estimates across specifications with industry-specific and common year fixed effects is consistent with the fact that the reform did not shift industry composition, as we have documented in Section 4. Figure IV Panel (c) plots γˆDiff for bandwidths ranging from 6 to 60 months, with industry- year effects. The point estimates are centered around zero for bandwidths above 12 months (and slightly larger at shorter bandwidths where confidence intervals widen); we cannot reject zero effects in any of these bandwidths. Mirroring Figure IV Panels (a) and (b), we now formalize the use of LLCs as an untreated control group in a difference-in-differences specification to net out incorporation time, cohort,

18 or age effects, which may otherwise confound our estimate of the treatment effect:27

 + DiD · ( )· + · ( ) + · + + Yf t α γ 1 IncDate f < 0 StockC f ψ 1 IncDate f < 0 δ StockC f X0f t β  f t , (2) where ψ captures incorporation time effects unrelated to shared governance and δ captures differences between stock corporations and LLCs. We report estimates of γˆDiD in Table I, Panel B, Column (1) for the two-year bandwidth. Figure IV Panel (d) plots estimates for bandwidths from 6 to 60 months. Consistent with the visual evidence in Figure IV Panels (a) and (b), the point estimates (and standard errors) of the simple difference specifications are robust to including this second control group, at 0.017 (SE 0.039) and 0.003 (SE 0.037). Our main specifications with the highest precision are the difference and the difference-in- differences ones. As a complement, we implement a regression discontinuity specification, which mirrors the difference specification in Equation (1) and additionally controls for linear trends in incorporation time:

 + RD · ( ) + · + · · ( ) + + Yf t α γ 1 IncDate f < 0 δ IncDate f δ− IncDate f 1 IncDate f < 0 X0f t β  f t , (3) where we use day-specific incorporation date as the running variable IncDate f . We report results for γˆRD in a two-year window of incorporations around the reform date in Table I, Panel C, Column (1). Figure IV Panel (b) reports a local linear specifications with a two-year bandwidth, plotting log wages against incorporation dates. Here, we find larger point estimates of 0.080 (SE 0.082) and 0.062 (SE 0.091) among stock corporations in the two-year window. The standard errors more than double in the RD specification so that the statistical power is lower. For example, the confidence interval for the specification with industry-year effects ranges from -0.114 to 0.234.28

27Of course, LLCs and stock corporations differ along a number of dimensions (including codetermination rules, see control means in our regression tables as well as the level differences depicted in Figure IV Panels (a) and (b)). The identification assumption for the difference-in-differences design is not that stock corporations and LLCs do not differ in levels, but that trends are parallel, i.e. the within-legal-form difference between slightly older versus younger firms would stay constant, were it not for the 1994 reform changing the codetermination mandate in young stock corporations (but leaving these rules unchanged for the three other groups). While we cannot test this assumption in our analysis sample (because of the reform), Appendix Table A.4 does so with placebo reforms, counterfactually assuming the 1994 reform had taken place in 1996 or 1997 instead. The robustness to varying bandwidths also supports this assumption. 28Appendix Figure A.4 Panels (a) and (b) show robustness to varying bandwidths and to donut hole specifications (where we leave out observations in a radius, indicated on the x-axis, around the reform date and extend the observations we include further away to keep a two-year window).

19 Median Wages and Censoring To gauge the role of outliers in affecting effects on the typical worker, Column (2) of Table I reports effects on median rather than mean log wages. Effects remain similar, e.g., -0.013 (SE 0.043) with industry-year effects in Panel A. In Column (3), we investigate effects on the share of censored observations at the firm, i.e. workers with earnings above the social security maximum. The control mean is 0.130. We find essentially zero effects on this outcome, between -0.004 (SE 0.020) and 0.014 (SE 0.019).

5.2 Composition Adjustment

Raw worker-level wage effects could capture or mask changes in worker composition. In Column (4) we therefore also report effects on log wages residualized by basic Mincerian controls, namely a cubic polynomial in age specific to three education groups (no training, vocational training, and university-level education). We find that the positive point estimates from raw wages drop to zero, suggesting that the wage effects captured composition effects. Moreover, precision increases. For example, in our specifications with year effects, we find estimates for γˆDiff of -0.004 (SE 0.028), for γˆDiD of -0.010 (SE 0.028), and for γˆRD of 0.012 (SE 0.059). Importantly, the larger point estimates in the RD specifications not controlling for Mincerian controls shrink close to zero when controlling for demographics.

5.3 Wage Policies: AKM Firm Effects

To further understand the effect on firms’ pay policies net of worker selection, we analyze firm pay premia in specifications with worker and firm effects as in Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999), thereby controlling for all permanent worker characteristics. We estimate the fixed effects in the full Orbis-ADIAB data set before applying our sample restrictions.29 We estimate firm level fixed effects in a rolling window of five years. We label each five-year window based on its midpoint, so that 1997 denotes the five-year window from 1995 to 1999. In our analysis sample, we assign firms their AKM effects starting three years after their incorporation i.e. when the first full five-year window is available. We report results visually in Figure V. We find that pay premia evolve similarly over time among older and younger stock corporations, and similarly for LLCs (Panel (a)). Since the levels of the AKM specifications are not comparable across years, we here normalize the AKM pay premia among older stock corporations to correspond to the average log wage in this firm group within each year (i.e. these AKM effects track the corresponding line in Figure IV Panel (a)) and adjust the premia in the other groups accordingly. Panel (b) again plots the firms by more granular quarterly cohorts, and additionally reports on implied RD effects

29To estimate AKM effects in the full sample, we follow Card, Heining, and Kline (2013) and drop marginal jobs, part-time employment, and wage observations below the 5th percentile and control for window-specific cubic polynomials in potential experience by education group.

20 (which are quantitatively small and statistically insignificant among stock corporations30) For all bandwidth plots, we find small, stable, and precisely estimated effects on pay premia centered around zero. The regression results in Column (5) of Table I mirror the visual analysis in Figure V. At a two-year bandwidth, we find point estimates between 0.004 (SE 0.016) and 0.011 (SE 0.015) in the simple difference and difference-in-differences specifications. The upper confidence interval of the former estimate hence exclude effect sizes of more than one sixth of the cross-sectional standard deviation of the AKM pay premia (which in turn is around 0.2 in our sample, similar to the (plant-based and worker-weighted) estimates in Card, Heining, and Kline, 2013, Table III Column (4)). The upper bound of 4% for effects on AKM pay premia (and 8% for raw wage effects) also rules out the large wage effects, of 10 to 20 log points, of US unions in cross-sectional worker data (Farber et al., 2018), as well as from comparing firms with and without collective bargaining coverage in Germany, of around 10% (Dustmann and Schönberg, 2009, Table 1), and for firm-level (6-10%) and sector-level (7-14%) agreements (Gürtzgen, 2009, Table 2). By contrast, we cannot rule out the considerably smaller wage effects implied by unionization events and new unions in the US (DiNardo and Lee, 2004; Frandsen, 2014), or the small effect of collective bargaining coverage on AKM firm pay premia in Germany, of around 2% (Hirsch and Mueller, 2020). We have also assessed whether worker selection as proxied by average AKM worker fixed effects is affected by shared governance and report results in Column (6) of Table I. We find no evidence for economically significant worker selection effects with tight confidence intervals including zero in all specifications.31

5.4 Wage Structure

We also analyze effects on the firm-level wage structure, as pay compression may mask wage effects (e.g., Saez, Schoefer, and Seim, 2019), and worker representation has been hypothesized to compress wages and reduce inequality inside the firm (e.g., Freeman and Medoff, 1985, p. 82-85), perhaps also through informal norms, as in the case of unions (see, e.g., Western and Rosenfeld, 2011). We report the effects on deciles of wages at the firm level for the two-year bandwidth and with industry-year effects in Figure VI and Appendix Table A.3. In the simple difference and difference-in-differences specifications, we find similar point estimates close to

30The RD effects allow us to rule out firm pay premia effects above 0.084. Again, Appendix Figure A.4 Panels (c) and (d) show robustness of the RD estimates to varying bandwidths and to donut hole specifications. 31We have also assessed direct measures of worker skill in Appendix Table A.10 and can rule out large shifts across skill groups.

21 zero across the deciles ranging between -0.026 (SE 0.061) and 0.024 (SE 0.063).32 Overall, we do not detect that shared governance leads to a compression of the pay structure.

5.5 Labor Share

We analyze whether shared governance affects the firm-level labor share, which we calculate as the wage bill share of value added, here drawing on the BvD component of the Orbis-ADIAB data for both variables.33 We report results in Column (7) of Table I and find a small negative effect of around -0.03 in most specifications relative to a control mean of 0.757. With standard errors of about the same magnitude, we can rule out labor share increases of more than 0.03 in the difference and the difference-in-differences designs. Standard errors double in the RD design with point estimates of 0.025 and -0.029. Overall, our results indicate no substantial increases in the labor share and, if anything, point towards a larger share of compensation going to capital. We will investigate the effects on capital formation, scale, rent sharing, and profitability in the next section.

6 What Explains the Absence of Wage Effects?

In this section, we further investigate the absence of wage effects and potential explanations. Drawing on a simple bargaining model, we first illustrate two potentially offsetting mechanisms through which shared governance may affect wages. On the one hand, it may increase worker bargaining power, thus increasing wages. On the other hand, the positive wage effect may be offset through hold up through which higher worker bargaining power deters capitalists’ investment and thus lowers the capital stock and wages. We then empirically shed light on both of these mechanisms. We find, if anything, that board-level codetermination raises capital formation. Next, we show that shared governance has no effects on rent sharing. We conclude with an analysis of effect heterogeneity. We find that board-level codetermination does not raise wages even when collective bargaining coverage or the prevalence of works councils is low, or when surplus is high.

6.1 Conceptual Framework

To guide our subsequent analysis and to build intuition, we present a simple model of firm-level wage setting. Even though the institution is distinct from firm-level unions as it

32Appendix Figure A.5 reports RD estimates, for which the confidence intervals again expand, with larger point estimates for the bottom two wage deciles. There, the levels of the point estimates appear positive, but recall that these estimated dropped to zero with basic composition adjustment, so our interest here is on detecting potential heterogeneity rather than interpreting the average level. 33Since value added is not filled for all firms, we replicate the IAB wage results for the set of firms with nonmissing value added (per worker) measure in Appendix Table A.6, and find very similar results.

22 is, e.g., more cooperative, a natural starting point is to view shared governance as boosting worker bargaining power, which we do in the context of a canonical union bargaining model (Brown and Ashenfelter, 1986; Abowd and Lemieux, 1993). N is the total size of the labor entity bargaining with the firm at hand. b denotes some reduced-form flow value for those not employed in the firm (unemployment insurance or wages at a reference competitive wage). L is the employment level, which we here set to be fixed at L  L¯. Here, we take output Y  F(L, K) as given, which is zero at disagreement (with zero labor). We later relax this assumption in Section 6.2.

Wage Bargaining Wages w are determined by Nash bargaining, with workers holding bargaining power φ:

W F w∗  arg max{φ log S (w) + (1 − φ) log S (w)}, (4) w where SW  L(w−b) is the workforce’s surplus: the inside value of the relationship Lw+(N−L)b minus the outside option, which is Nb. F Firm surplus is S  Y − wL¯ − c0K at the bargaining stage, where the firm’s outside option W F is repurposing or reselling capital at price c0. Total surplus is S  S + S  Y − bL − c0K. The Nash bargaining solution allocates surplus shares such that SW  φS or SF  (1 − φ)S, and therefore the Nash wage w∗ is outside option b plus share φ of surplus:

Y − bL − c K w  φ · 0 + b. (5) ∗ L

Wage Effects of Shared Governance The bargaining setup suggests three channels through which shared governance can affect wages:

Y − bL − c K  Y   c K  dw  dφ · 0 + φ · d + (1 − φ)· db − φ · d 0 , (6) ∗ L L L |{z} Rent Sharing |{z} | {z } Size of the Pie Outside Options where dx  xSG − xNo SG denotes the difference in variable x between firms with and without shared governance; Equation (6) takes a total derivative and a linear approximation, thereby assuming that the effects are small (consistent with our findings at least for wages). Equation (6) suggests three basic channels by which shared governance could have affected wage setting: rent sharing, the size of the pie, and outside options. In the next two sections, we study the terms on the right hand side to understand potential wage effects and lack thereof. First, shared governance could raise the degree of rent sharing, i.e. the share of rents such as from higher productivity or profits that workers can appropriate in the form of higher

23 wages. In the bargaining model, this would occur if shared governance were to boost the bargaining power parameter φ of workers. In Section 6.3, we analyze such effects proxied for by rent-sharing estimates. Second, shared governance could affect wages through potential effects on firm-level productivity, to the degree that firms share rents with workers, as in bargaining models. By contrast, if shared governance shrinks firm productivity, as predicted in hold-up models due to lower investment, wages may not increase on net even though workers’ bargaining power increases. We study effects on the size of the surplus pie, and specifically the capital disinvestment channel of hold-up models, in Section 6.2. Third, in bargaining models, wages also reflect outside options, shifts in which may explain the absence of wage effects. We discuss such mechanisms, as well as compensating differentials, in Section 6.4. Finally, this conceptual framework assumes scope for firm-level wage setting. We investigate whether constraints on firm-level wage flexibility may mask wage effects in a heterogeneity analysis in Section 6.5.   Y bL c0K 6.2 Do Smaller Pies and Hold-Up Effects Mask Wage Effects? d − L− One potential mechanism that could explain the absence of wages is that shared governance may reduce the size of the pie, i.e. the surplus to be shared between workers and firms. This could work through a variety of mechanisms. Most prominently, the canonical hold-up view provides a theoretical underpinning predicting this outcome through a disinvestment channel. In that model, anticipating that labor will grab a larger share of the fruits from their investments, capitalists reduce investment in these models. Several authors have argued that unions and other forms of worker representation can be thought of as rent-extracting institutions (see, e.g., Grout, 1984; Lindbeck and Snower, 1989), and that shared governance is one of such institutions (Jensen and Meckling, 1979). Alternative models of shared governance also have predictions for firm performance and hence wages in bargaining models, or more broadly any model in which firm size of productivity affects wages, such as wage posting models. An alternative bargaining model permits workers to jointly bargain over investment and wages. In Appendix Section C, we show that such a model can predict positive investment effects and break the hold-up prediction even in a closely related bargaining model, building on (Manning, 1987). Efficient bargaining too may predict positive rather than negative scale and investment effects (Crawford, 1988). Corporate governance may be affected and differential selection or of managers may lead to changes in firm scale or productivity. Alternatively, shared governance may affect productivity directly through information sharing, fostering worker voice, and facilitating training in specific skills (e.g., Freeman, 1980).

24 Firm Performance: Output and Productivity The surplus measure corresponding to our worker-level wage outcomes is per-worker surplus, so we start with value added divided by BvD-based employment (labor productivity).34 We again start by plotting raw data of this outcome, in Figure VII Panel (a), tracking cohorts of corporations over time, sorting firms into treatment and control groups along the two-year bandwidth around the reform date. Unlike the wage outcomes, this graph starts in 2006 as it builds on the BvD component of the Orbis-ADIAB data set. Labor productivity of stock corporations incorporated before 1994 and hence with shared governance (blue line with solid circles) is above their control group’s level in all years, except for two slight dips in the early years. As a placebo comparison, the figure also plots the corresponding cohort graphs for LLCs, where old and young LLCs’ labor productivity essentially lies on top of each other throughout (at a lower level). In Table II Column (1), we report the corresponding regression estimates for the treatment effect of board-level codetermination. The table follows the structure of Table I for the wage outcomes. The simple difference with year fixed effects reveals positive effects of 2.2% to 7.5%, for the simple difference between old and young stock corporations as well as with LLCs as a second control group, and with year and year-industry fixed effects. The standard errors are 11-12%, so the wide confidence intervals include zero. Figure VII Panel (b) reports robustness to varying the bandwidths for the simple difference specification, Figure A.6 Panel (b) does so for the DiD one. Since the sample drops when we study value added per worker compared to the IAB-based wage outcomes in Table I, we show that these wage results are robust to restricting the sample to the firm-year observations with non-missing value added per worker information, in Appendix Table A.6. Additionally, we report effects of placebo reforms in 1996 and 1997 on value added per worker (and on all other outcomes shown in Table II) in Appendix Table A.4. Appendix Figure A.6 shows the corresponding RD plots, with RD regression results in Appendix Table A.7 Column (1) (and similarly for the other BvD outcomes of Table II discussed below). Here, confidence intervals double, such that the large negative point estimates also accommodate positive effects of around 25%. In Column (2), we also study log value added (i.e. not divided by employment), to measure the total size of the pie and because firm scale is a marker of productivity in many models (e.g., Lucas, 1978). For this much more dispersed outcome, confidence intervals double (standard errors expand to from 0.11 to 0.23). Point estimates are zero except for the large negative simple difference with industry-year fixed effects; this specification however converges towards zero

34A previous version of this paper focused on the financial BvD outcomes, and therefore drew on a larger and longer multi-source BvD sample described in Footnote 14. The current version instead focuses on the IAB outcomes, and studies an additional, smaller, set of BvD outcomes in the smaller and shorter Orbis-ADIAB sample of BvD firms. The main results for capital and value added have remained robust to this alternative sample; the capital share and outsourcing effects are closer zero in the Orbis-ADIAB sample.

25 in the difference-in-differences specification. As less demanding measures than value added, we also present log revenue per worker and log revenue in Columns (3) and (4) of Table II, a BvD outcome filled for considerably more firms. Point estimates are positive throughout, 0.058 to 0.177 for log revenue per worker (SEs of 0.140 to 0.154) and 0.159 to 0.296 for log revenue (SEs of around 0.26). Lastly, in Columns (5) and (6), we study log employment (BvD and IAB variables respec- tively) as another measure of firm scale but also as the BvD employment measure normalizes our per-worker outcomes. The BvD variable includes those abroad; the IAB one captures employment subject to German social security and thus more relevant for codetermination thresholds (see Annuß, 2019, DrittelbG § 3, Rn. 2). We find statistically insignificant, positive effects, ranging from 0.005 to 0.092% (SEs of 0.154-0.160) for BvD employment, and 0.045-0.065 (SEs of 0.136 to 0.153) for IAB employment. The larger confidence intervals on log employment may raise the potential for worker composition to affect our estimates of wage effects of the institution. However, our strongest and most precisely estimated effects on composition- adjusted wages addressed this concern, and we moreover did not find wage effects on the within-firm wage distribution. In a dedicated analysis of worker composition reported in Appendix Table A.10, we also find no effects on the skill structure and outsourcing.35 We conclude that shared governance does not appear to reduce the size of the firm’s pie, either in total or on a per-worker basis. While effects are noisily estimated, if anything, shared governance appears to raise surplus and firm scale proxies.

Capital Formation: Testing the Hold-Up Hypothesis We now study the effect of shared governance on capital. An influential argument against shared governance is that granting workers control rights will raise their bargaining power and wages, and thereby discourage capital formation (Grout, 1984). Prominently, Jensen and Meckling (1979) lay out the disinvestment effects of codetermination as follows:

[T]he workers will begin ‘eating it up’ [the firm] by transforming the assets of the firm into consumption or personal assets. [...] It will become difficult for the firm to obtain capital in the private capital markets. [...] The result of this process will be a significant reduction in the country’s capital stock, increased unemployment, reduced labor income, and an overall reduction in output and welfare.

Formally, the firm invests anticipating wage rule (5), in which share φ of the marginal product

35In Appendix Table A.10, we find negative point estimates throughout for the share of low-skilled workers without vocational training. We further study effects on the share of workers in outsourceable occupations (, cleaning, security and logistics) and similarly find no evidence for firms reducing employment in these categories. We also report positive, insignificant effects on the BvD-based value-added/revenue ratio as an inverse measure of outsourcing.

26 of capital goes to wages, acting like a distortionary profit tax (as in Grout, 1984).36 The BvD data report capital stocks but not capital expenditures (“investment”). We start with fixed assets, which comprise tangible assets, such as buildings and equipment, and intangible assets, such as or trademarks. The point estimates for log fixed assets, reported in Column (7) of Table II, are large and positive, around 0.431 to 0.546, and relatively stable across specifications, with large standard errors of 0.317-0.352, such that confidence intervals include zero. Again, we plot the raw data by group and year in Figure VII Panel (c) along with the bandwidth graphs in Panel (d), which visualizes the striking positive and parallel lines. Together with the more granular quarter-by-incorporation RD graph in Appendix Figure A.6 (along with the DiD bandwidth graphs), the raw data also suggest that it is unlikely that specific calendar years or specific firms drive these effects, or mask negative effects on capital. We further study tangible fixed assets in Column (8), documenting large positive but again insignificant effects ranging from 0.270 to 0.490 (SEs of 0.196-0.224). Since these scale outcomes are potentially skewed, we additionally normalize them by BvD employment, as with value added. That is, we estimate effects on the capital-labor ratio. Figure VII Panels (e) and (f) present these results (with the RD figure and the DiD bandwidth plot reported in Appendix Figure A.6). Effects on log fixed assets per worker, reported in Column (9) of Table II, are of similar magnitude ranging between 0.443 and 0.587, but are now more precisely estimated with standard errors dropping to 0.250-0.273; as a result, the positive effects are statistically significant at the 5% (10%) level for the specifications with industry-year effects (year effects). Column (10) reports effects on log tangible assets per worker, for which normalizing by employment leaves point estimates similar but reduces standard errors as well. These non-negative capital effects imply that either shared governance does not depress capital formation through hold-up. Or, the hold-up mechanism is overturned by counteracting forces that crowd in investment. Our analysis of effects on rent sharing will allow us to shed further light on the former mechanism. As we drop some firms for this analysis using BvD outcomes (relative to our analysis of wages), Appendix Table A.5 shows that the wage results from Table I are robust to restricting

36Consider a simplified two-stage setting, in which capital K is purchased in stage 1 at price c, becomes productive in stage 2, then fully depreciates. There is no discounting between periods. The firm chooses K maximizing expected profits, π w, L¯ , K  F K, L¯ wL¯ cK, by equalizing the marginal cost of purchasing it, c, ( ) ( ) − − h φ i ¯  + ¯ ∂w∗  + ¯  + with its marginal benefit (output net of wage effects): FK L, K∗ c L ∂K c φ FK L, K∗ c0 c c c0 1 φ . ( ) ( ( )− ) ( − ) − Capital investment involves two considerations. First, the marginal unit of capital raises output by FK, but comes at cost c. Second – the core of the hold-up mechanism – workers grab share φ of surplus in stage 2. At that stage, capital has value c c. Underinvestment (Fk > c) emerges as long as wage bargaining power φ > 0 and capital is 0 ≤ at least partially sunk (c0 < c). As a result, shared governance may exacerbate hold-up, and reduce investment to dK∗  1 1 the extent that it boosts worker bargaining power φ in wage negotiations: dφ ¯ c c0 2 < 0. This FKK L,K∗ ( − ) 1 φ induced reduction in the capital/labor ratio would also lower per-worker surplus. Appendix( ) Section( − ) C shows that these predictions extend to the case with endogenous labor.

27 the sample to firm-year observations with non-missing fixed asset information. Again, Appendix Table A.4 reports results from placebo reforms in 1996 and 1997. We also ballpark that the large implied capital effects can be considered consistent with the moderate value added effects in a Cobb-Douglas constant-returns production framework.37

Assessment of Hold-Up Theory Shared governance does not appear to induce firms to become smaller or less productive. The data specifically reject the prominent disinvestment prediction of the hold-up and agency cost views of shared governance (see, e.g., Jensen and Meckling, 1979). A priori, such disinvestment could have rationalized the absence of wage increases or even led to wage reductions. Instead, the findings on firm performance align more with richer perspectives on industrial relations and capital-labor interactions. For example, worker representatives may have longer- term perspectives than shareholders or executives. Or, shared governance may facilitate cooperation and long-term between owners, managers and the workforce, perhaps by institutionalizing communication channels and repeated interactions. These views are consistent with anecdotal evidence for worker representatives’ self-described objectives to boost firm scale and investment, for example:

[S]hared governance per se opposes -term shareholder interests. The focus [of shared governance] is on the long-term safeguarding of the company through investments and innovations with participation of the employees [...].38

Berthold Huber, Worker Supervisory Board Representative, Siemens

Similarly, surveys of plant-level agreements have found that workers often push for guarantees of investments in existing plants when negotiating (Rehder, 2003). Alternatively, the institution may lead to agency conflicts inside the firm such as facilitating managers’ empire building, with resources being locked into fixed capital at the expense

37Consistent with the increase in capital intensity, we also documented a negative but insignificant decline in the labor income share in Table I Column (7), although, for example with Cobb-Douglas the capital income shared can remain constant even if capital intensity increases such as in response to factor price shifts. Regarding the labor productivity effects, the capital share in our sample is 0.272 on average (one minus control mean of labor share in Table I Column (7)), which in a Cobb-Douglas constant-returns production function represents the elasticity of value added per worker to the capital-labor ratio (holding efficiency constant). Hence, a 50% increase in fixed assets times a capital share of 0.272 would lead to a 13.6% predicted increase of value added per worker, close to the two higher point estimates among the four specifications in Table II Column (1), and within the confidence interval of all estimates. The magnitude of the capital point estimates also falls within the range of estimated firm-level investment responses to other corporate governance variation. In the context of Compustat firms, Bertrand and Schoar (2003) find that manager style effects on firm-level investment (to capital ratio) differ by 20 log points between the 25th and 75th percentile of managers. Pan, Wang, and Weisbach (2016) find a 29% (6.9/24) effect on investment over the course of a new CEO’s tenure comparing the first three years to the later years. In the context of smaller, Danish firms, Bennedsen et al. (2007) find an effect of death-driven successions of CEOs by family members rather than outside directors reduces assets by 0.30 (SE 0.24) in family firms. 38Source: Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, November 15, 2004, Nr. 267, p. 13, translation by authors.

28 of – so that capitalists may not voluntarily adopt codetermination (Jensen and Meckling, 1979). We study profitability effects below.

6.3 Does Shared Governance Boost Rent Sharing? dφ

We directly assess the degree to which workers’ bargaining power in wage setting may have shifted in shared-governance firms. We do so by studying firm-level rent sharing elasticities and find no shifts induced by shared governance. The motivation for the analysis is that in bargaining settings, workers can capture firm-specific shifts in surplus, to a degree that is guided by worker bargaining power φ:

∂w ∗  φ. (7) ∂S/L

The rent sharing estimation therefore permits us to directly test whether shared governance shifts worker bargaining power in wage setting (as in Jäger et al., 2020, who also include a meta analysis of the implied parameters). In practice, we estimate standard rent sharing elasticities ∂w Y L Y L ∗ /  / that use variation in surplus arising from value added per worker, i.e. ∂Y L w φ w . We / have found no effects on wages or the labor share, so we can plausibly go from the elasticity to the bargaining interpretation.

Shared Governance and Rent Sharing In Figure VIII, we plot the relationship between wages to value-added per worker. Specifically, we use our AKM firm fixed effects as a measure of composition-adjusted wage policies of firms on the y-axis, and firms’ sample average of log value added per worker on the x-axis. Our sample is firms incorporated within two years around the reform. The slope between these two variables traces out the rent-sharing elasticity. This slope is 0.067 (SE 0.018) for young shareholder corporations not subject to the mandate.39 Comparing these firms with their slightly older peers subject to the mandate, we detect no difference in rent sharing induced by shared governance. The simple difference estimate is 0.010 (SE 0.026). We find a difference-in-differences estimate of 0.007 (SE 0.022) using LLCs as a second control group, ruling out increases in the rent-sharing elasticity of more than 0.05.40 Consequently, we find no evidence for workers capturing a larger part of output when they have board representation – a result consistent with and perhaps underlying the absence of

39In Appendix Figure A.7, we plot the data for the pooled analysis sample. We estimate an elasticity of 0.084 (SE 0.004). While no previous worker-and-firm-level rent-sharing estimates for Germany have been reported (for lack of matched firm and worker data), the elasticity is similar to those documented in other countries (Card et al., 2018; Jäger et al., 2020) and to estimates in the German context based on establishment-level survey data (Gürtzgen, 2009; Hirsch and Mueller, 2020). 40The DiD estimate is the coefficient on the interaction between log value added per worker and an indicator for stock corporations incorporated before August 10, 1994. The model also includes base effects for cohort and legal form, each interacted with value added.

29 hold-up patterns in capital formation.

Reconciling Wage and Value Added Effects Finally, we assess whether the wage and value added effects can be rationalized with rent-sharing elasticities. The largest effect on value added per worker in Table II is 0.075. Together with the rent-sharing elasticity of 0.067 reported in Figure VIII among young stock corporations, the largest value added per worker point estimate implies a wage increase of 0.075 × 0.067 ≈ 0.005. By contrast, even when using the upper confidence interval of the value added per worker effects of around 0.3, the predicted wage effect purely from the potential increase in surplus would be 0.3 × 0.067 ≈ 0.020. These predicted effects are strikingly similar to the point estimates for the effect on firm pay premia in Column (5) of Table I range between 0.004 to 0.023, with tight confidence intervals especially for the difference and difference-in-differences specifications (SEs of around 0.015). That is, workers may benefit from the larger capital stock and larger pie through the standard rent-sharing channel, which, by itself and absent increases in rent sharing, however, would imply small wage gains. Our rent-sharing estimates revealed no large effects on this aspect of wage setting.

Profitability We find no evidence of profit effects (see Appendix Table A.8), which is consistent with the absence of measurable effects on wages, rent sharing and labor shares. This finding is also consistent with an absence of strategic delay or rushed entrance of firms before the cutoff documented in Section 4, which would have been predicted if shared governance were very costly or profitable (e.g., Jensen and Meckling, 1979).

6.4 Non-Wage Amenities, Compensating Differentials, and Outside Op- tions: Effects on Tenure and Separations

Shared governance may raise the amenity value of staying at the firm and such an increase may be offset in lower wages through compensating differentials (Kim, Maug, and Schneider, 2018). If shared governance led to higher worker rents, even if those manifested themselves in non-monetary form rather than wages, we would see an increase in workers’ willingness to stay in the firm and hence an increase in average tenure, even if wages were not or even negatively affected. Lastly, in principle, shared governance may affect wage-relevant outside options (as in Jäger et al., 2020) , though we find it difficult to formulate plausible scenarios, such as shifts in training in general human capital or unemployment durations. We test these alternative mechanisms by studying tenure and separations in Appendix Table A.10 Columns (6) through (8), studying log tenure, level of tenure in years, and the annual separation rate, among the full-time workers that make up our wage analysis sample. Effects on tenure are statistically insignificant but positive in most specifications. In the simple

30 difference specifications, point estimates suggest 0.071 and 0.077 increases in log tenure (SEs of around 0.05) and 0.235 and 0.332 years of additional tenure (SEs of 0.279 and 0.301) with year and industry-year effects respectively. In the DiD specifications (which would also account for potential mechanical effects from lower censoring of tenure in older firms), effects fall towards zero and slightly negative (with similar SEs). We find essentially zero effects on the annual separation rate (-0.001 to -0.009 with SEs of around 0.0006 to 0.016, with control means of 0.095). Therefore, the results do not suggest that shared governance raises quality aspects valued by workers. Additionally, studying is also another validation revealed- preference check of the absence of wage premia. Finally, our results on turnover also do not provide support for the voice-exit hypothesis, by which information sharing and exercise of worker voice could have reduced turnover (Hirschman, 1970; Freeman, 1980).

6.5 Heterogeneity Analysis: Wage Flexibility, Collective Bargaining, High- Rent Industries, and Works Councils

We close our empirical analysis by shedding further light on the mechanisms underlying our key finding of no detectable wage effects of board representation, and by providing an attempt to gauge external validity of our findings. We do so in a series of heterogeneity analyses across different pockets of the labor market. To this end, we calculate characteristics at the three digit industry level, for example, collective bargaining agreement (CBA) coverage, and then analyze treatment effects depending on whether the firm is in an industry cell above or below the median (allowing for all relevant base and interaction effects). For the CBA and works council variables, our analysis draws on the IAB Establishment Panel (a representative survey of establishments) from 2008 onwards (when the NACE Rev. 2 codes permit a direct mapping to the BvD NACE code). We report results in Figure IX, including means of the sorting (heterogeneity) variables separately for the above and below median samples of stock corporations in a two-year bandwidth around the reform. In Figure IX, we report heterogeneous effects on AKM firm fixed effects (pay premia) in the difference and difference-in-differences specifications; Appendix Figure A.8 Panel (a) does so for firm-level mean log wages (for all three specifications), and Panel (b) reports on the additional RD specification for firm AKM effects (again with wider SEs). Appendix Table A.11 reports the full regression results.

Collective Bargaining Coverage and Observed Wage Differentiation A potential reason why wage effects are close to zero may be that CBAs may leave little room for decentralized wage setting at the firm level. Centralized wage setting may curb rent extraction and thus reduce hold-up problems (Freeman and Lazear, 1995; Acemoglu, 2001). In the German context,

31 CBA coverage has been associated with lower responsiveness of establishment-level wages to the presence of works councils and to establishment-level value added, as well as with lower dispersion of establishment wage fixed effects Hübler and Jirjahn (2003); Gürtzgen (2009); Hirsch and Mueller (2020). First, we sort firms into their industries by (industry- or firm-specific) CBA coverage using the IAB Establishment Panel. There is substantial heterogeneity in CBA coverage, namely the mean CBA coverage is 42.5% among below-median firms and 79.7% among above-median firms. This wide dispersion and the existence of pockets with low coverage reflect a trend towards decentralization since the 1990s (Hassel, 1999; Brändle, Heinbach, and Maier, 2011; Card, Heining, and Kline, 2013; Dustmann et al., 2014; Kügler, Schönberg, and Schreiner, 2018). We find no evidence that higher CBA coverage masks effects on AKM firm fixed effects (nor for mean log wages reported in Appendix Figure A.8 Panel (a)). Low-coverage cells exhibit close to zero point estimates of 0.003 (SE 0.022) and -0.002 (SE 0.018) for the simple difference and difference-in-differences analyses. We also do not find heterogeneity in wage effects when grouping firms into industries by the fraction of firms with “binding” CBA coverage (having a CBA and not paying above-CBA wages). The baseline levels above and below the median are very low at 0.254 and 0.108, respectively, again reflecting substantial scope for localized wage setting. Lastly, we do not find larger wage effects when zooming into (3-digit) industries with larger dispersion (SD) of the AKM firm pay premia as another proxy for scope for firm-level wage setting.

Prevalence of Works Councils We also study whether the prevalence of establishment-level works councils may attenuate wage effects of board-level codetermination by, e.g., duplicating some codetermination channels. As an alternative hypothesis, observers of industrial relations in Germany have argued for a complementarity between establishment- and board-level codetermination (as board representatives can also serve as works councilors, see, e.g., Streeck, 1984; Paster, 2012). We find substantial baseline variation in the prevalence of works councils with an average prevalence of 57.2% and 83.5%, respectively, in cells above and below the median. Our results leave some room for larger effects on AKM pay premia in industries with higher works council prevalence, at 0.028 (SE 0.023) and 0.040 (SE 0.023), with the mirror image of negative but insignificant effects for cells below the median. The point estimates for wage effects, reported in Appendix Figure A.8 Panel (a), are even larger at 0.097 (SE 0.060) and 0.116 (SE 0.057). Overall, the weight of the evidence suggests, if anything, a complementarity between works councils and board-level codetermination in terms of wage effects.

Proxies for Surplus Finally, we assess heterogeneity in the effect by the level of surplus per worker. At an extreme, in industries with low or no rents, increases in worker bargaining

32 power may not be consequential because wages are determined by outside options rather than reflecting the surplus from the employment relationship. We consider three surplus proxies at the industry level: log value added per worker, average AKM pay premium, and average tenure (revealed-preference measure of surplus). Figure IX reveals no significant heterogeneity in the wage effects across these surplus proxies. This finding further suggests that worker representation on corporate boards do not appear to shift worker bargaining power, consistent with our direct evidence on rent sharing elasticities in Section 6.3.

7 Conclusion

Worker representation on company boards does not appear to affect wage setting in detectable ways such as by raising bargaining power. We have studied a cohort- and legal-form- based reform in Germany that abolished this form of shared governance in some firms but permanently preserved it in others. Our main results are that, first, worker representation on boards does not appear to affect wage setting, as measured by average wages, firms’ wage policies, the wage structure within firms, or the degree of rent sharing. Second, the data reject the prominent disinvestment prediction of the hold-up and agency cost views of shared governance (see, e.g., Jensen and Meckling, 1979), which could have in principle rationalized the absence of wage effects. Third, we do not find negative profitability effects, although we caution that our data do not contain dividend payouts or firm valuations. Fourth, heterogeneity analyses rule out that sectoral collective bargaining, the presence of works councils or low surplus masked potential wage effects.41 Hence, our findings may extend beyond institutional settings similar to Germany’s. In fact, Harju, Jäger, and Schoefer (2020) confirm our main findings of zero wage effects and nonnegative, if anything positive, effects on investment studying board representation in the Finnish context studying the 1991 introduction of this institution in firms with 150 employees or more. We close by reflecting on aspects of the institution we study itself. First, owner representa- tives always retain the majority of board seats in the German codetermination system (and in other countries with codetermined boards). Even theories that do grant minority factions some real authority (Aghion and Tirole, 1997) would do so only in matters unimportant to capital – a domain that plausibly excludes wage setting. Second, in the dual board structure, the supervisory boards do not have direct influence on wage setting, although we reviewed a number of plausible channels in the introduction.42 Third, unlike the role of unions in an

41While we did not find that board representation affected wage setting and found if anything larger incremental effects in cells with more works councils, our study does not speak to the potential independent wage effects of plant-level works councils, the other facet of shared governance. 42The evidence is consistent with limited influence of gender quotas for board seats on the gender wage gap as in Bertrand et al. (2018); Maida and Weber (2019). Yet, these studies affected the composition of capital representatives along a demographic dimension. Other settings with unitary board structures as the dominant

33 adversarial system, de jure the fiduciary duty of worker representatives on the board lies with the corporation and hence may be more aligned with the capital owners. In fact, it has been argued that worker board representatives are typically moderate actors and that minority board representation itself may have contributed to overall more cooperative labor relations in Germany (Thelen, 1991).

Simon Jäger Benjamin Schoefer Massachusetts Institute of University of California, Berkeley NBER

Jörg Heining Institute for Employment Research (IAB)

governance form, such as in Finland, permit worker representation also on and in bodies.

34 8 Bibliography

Abowd, John, Francis Kramarz, and David Margolis. 1999. “High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms.” Econometrica 67 (2):251–333.

Abowd, John A and Thomas Lemieux. 1993. “The Effects of Product Market on Collective Bargaining Agreements: The Case of Foreign Competition in Canada.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (4):983–1014.

Acemoglu, Daron. 2001. “Good Jobs versus Bad Jobs.” Journal of labor Economics 19 (1):1–21.

Addison, John. 2009. The Economics of Codetermination: Lessons from the German Experience. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.

Addison, John, Thorsten Schank, Claus Schnabel, and Joachim Wagner. 2007. “Do Works Councils Inhibit Investment?” ILR Review 60 (2):187–203.

Addison, John, Claus Schnabel, and Joachim Wagner. 2001. “Works Councils in Germany: their Effects on Establishment Performance.” Oxford Economic Papers 53 (4):659–694.

Addison, John, Paulino Teixeira, and Thomas Zwick. 2010. “German Works Councils and the Anatomy of Wages.” ILR Review 63 (2):247–270.

Aghion, Philippe and Jean Tirole. 1997. “Formal and Real Authority in Organizations.” Journal of Political Economy 105 (1):1–29.

Albach, Horst, Christiane Corte, Rolf Friedewald, Marcus Lutter, and Wolf Richter. 1988. Deregulierung des Aktienrechts: das Drei-Stufen-Modell: ein Entwurf zur Modifizierung des Aktienrechts im Hinblick auf personalistische Gesellschaftsstrukturen und einen erleichterten Börsenzugang. Verlag -, Gütersloh.

Annuß, Georg. 2019. Münchener Kommentar zum Aktiengesetz, vol. 2. C. H. Beck, 5 ed.

Antoni, Manfred, Katharina Koller, Marie-Christine Laible, and Florian Zimmermann. 2018. “Orbis-ADIAB: From Record Linkage Key to Research Dataset.” FDZ-Methodenreport 04/2018 (en). Editors Rainer Schnell, Manfred Antoni .

Autor, David, David Mindell, and Elisabeth Reynolds. 2019. “The Work of the Future: Shaping Technology and Institutions.”

Bennedsen, Morten, Kasper Meisner Nielsen, Francisco Perez-Gonzalez, and Daniel Wolfenzon. 2007. “Inside the Family Firm: The Role of Families in Succession Decisions and Performance.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (2):647–691.

Bersch, Johannes, Sandra Gottschalk, Bettina Müller, and Michaela Niefert. 2014. “The Mannheim Enterprise Panel (MUP) and Firm Statistics for Germany.” ZEW-Centre for European Economic Research Discussion Paper (14-104).

Bertrand, Marianne, Sandra Black, Sissel Jensen, and Adriana Lleras-Muney. 2018. “Breaking the Glass Ceiling? The Effect of Board Quotas on Female Labour Market Outcomes in Norway.” The Review of Economic Studies 86 (1):191–239.

35 Bertrand, Marianne and Antoinette Schoar. 2003. “Managing With Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4):1169–1208.

Brändle, Tobias, Wolf Dieter Heinbach, and Michael Maier. 2011. “Tarifliche Öffnung in Deutschland: Ausmaß, Determinanten, Auswirkungen.” Zeitschrift für Arbeitsmarktforschung 44 (1):163–172.

Brown, James and Orley Ashenfelter. 1986. “Testing the Efficiency of Employment Contracts.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (3, Part 2):S40–S87.

Card, David, Ana Rute Cardoso, Jörg Heining, and Patrick Kline. 2018. “Firms and Labor Market Inequality: Evidence and Some Theory.” Journal of Labor Economics 36 (S1):S13–S70.

Card, David, Francesco Devicienti, and Agata Maida. 2014. “Rent-Sharing, Holdup, and Wages: Evidence from Matched Panel Data.” Review of Economic Studies 81 (1):84–111.

Card, David, Jörg Heining, and Patrick Kline. 2013. “ Heterogeneity and the Rise of West German Wage Inequality.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (3):967–1015.

Connolly, Robert, Barry Hirsch, and Mark Hirschey. 1986. “Union Rent Seeking, Intangible Capital, and Market Value of the Firm.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 68 (4):567–577.

Crawford, Vincent. 1988. “Long-Term Relationships Governed by Short-Term Contracts.” The American Economic Review 78 (3):485–499.

DiNardo, John and David Lee. 2004. “Economic Impacts of New Unionization on Private Sector Employers: 1984–2001.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (4):1383–1441.

Dustmann, Christian, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener. 2014. “From Sick Man of to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (1):167–88.

Dustmann, Christian and Uta Schönberg. 2009. “Training and Union Wages.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 91 (2):363–376.

Farber, Henry, Daniel Herbst, Ilyana Kuziemko, and Suresh Naidu. 2018. “Unions and Inequality over the Twentieth Century: New Evidence from Survey Data.” NBER Working Paper .

Fischer, Gabriele, Florian Janik, Dana Müller, Alexandra Schmucker et al. 2008. “The IAB Establishment Panel–from Sample to Survey to Projection.” FDZ Methodenreport 1:2008.

FitzRoy, Felix R and Kornelius Kraft. 1993. “Economic Effects of Codetermination.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95 (3):365–375.

Frandsen, Brigham R. 2014. “The Surprising Impacts of Unionization: Evidence from Matched Employer-employee Data.” Brigham Young University Working Paper .

Freeman, Richard. 1980. “The Exit-Voice Tradeoff in the Labor Market: Unionism, Job Tenure, Quits, and Separations.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 94 (4):643–673.

36 Freeman, Richard and Edward Lazear. 1995. “An Economic Analysis of Works Councils.” In Works Councils: Consultation, Representation, Cooperation in Industrial Relations, edited by Joel Rogers and Wolfgang Streeck. NBER Comparative Labor Markets Series.

Freeman, Richard and James Medoff. 1985. “What Do Unions Do?” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 38 (2):244–263.

Fuest, Clemens, Andreas Peichl, and Sebastian Siegloch. 2018. “Do Higher Corporate Reduce Wages? Micro Evidence from Germany.” American Economic Review 108 (2):393–418.

Gold, Michael. 2011. “‘Taken on Board’: An of the Influence of Employee Board- Level Representatives on Company Decision-Making across Europe.” European Journal of Industrial Relations 17 (1):41–56.

Gold, Michael, Norbert Kluge, and Aline Conchon. 2010. ’In the Union and on the Board’: Experiences of Board-level Employee Representatives Across Europe. European Union Institute (ETUI).

Gorton, Gary and Frank Schmid. 2004. “Capital, Labor, and the Firm: A Study of German Codetermination.” Journal of the European Economic Association 2 (5):863–905.

Grout, Paul. 1984. “Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach.” Econometrica 52 (2):449–460.

Gürtzgen, Nicole. 2009. “Rent-Sharing and Collective Bargaining Coverage: Evidence from Linked Employer–Employee Data.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 111 (2):323–349.

Hall, Peter and David Soskice. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. .

Harju, Jakko, Simon Jäger, and Benjamin Schoefer. 2020. “Shared Governance and Worker Voice: Evidence from Finland.” Working Paper .

Hassel, Anke. 1999. “The Erosion of the German System of Industrial Relations.” British Journal of Industrial Relations 37 (3):483–505.

Hirsch, Barry. 2004. “What Do Unions Do for Economic Performance?” Journal of Labor Research 25 (3):415–455.

Hirsch, Boris and Steffen Mueller. 2020. “Firm Wage Premia, Industrial Relations, and Rent Sharing in Germany.” ILR Review 73 (5):1119–1146.

Hirschman, Albert. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States, vol. 25. Press.

Hübler, Olaf and Uwe Jirjahn. 2003. “Works Councils and Collective Bargaining in Germany: the Impact on Productivity and Wages.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 50 (4):471–491.

Jäger, Simon and Jörg Heining. 2019. “How Substitutable Are Workers? Evidence from Worker Deaths.” Working Paper .

37 Jäger, Simon, Benjamin Schoefer, Samuel Young, and Josef Zweimüller. 2020. “Wages and the Value of Nonemployment.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135 (4):1905–1963.

Jensen, Michael and William Meckling. 1979. “Rights and Production Functions: An Applica- tion to Labor-Managed Firms and Codetermination.” Journal of Business 52 (4):469–506.

Kim, Han, Ernst Maug, and Christoph Schneider. 2018. “Labor Representation in Governance as an Insurance Mechanism.” Review of Finance 22 (4):1251–1289.

Kügler, Alice, Uta Schönberg, and Ragnhild Schreiner. 2018. “Productivity Growth, Wage Growth and Unions.” In Price and Wage-Setting in Advanced Economies, vol. 2018. ECB, 215–247.

Lee, David and Alexandre Mas. 2012. “Long-Run Impacts of Unions on Firms: New Evidence From Financial Markets, 1961-1999.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (1):333–378.

Lindbeck, Assar and Dennis Snower. 1989. The Insider-Outsider Theory of Employment and Unemployment. MIT Press.

Lucas, Robert. 1978. “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms.” The Bell Journal of Economics 9 (2):508–523.

Machin, Stephen and Sushil Wadhwani. 1991. “The Effects of Unions on Investment and Innovation: Evidence from WIRS.” The Economic Journal 101 (405):324–330.

Maida, Agata and Andrea Weber. 2019. “Female and Gender Gap within Firms: Evidence from an Italian Board Reform.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP13476 .

Malcomson, James. 1983. “Trade Unions and Economic Efficiency.” The Economic Journal 93:51–65.

Manning, Alan. 1987. “An Integration of Models in a Sequential Bargaining Framework.” The Economic Journal 97 (385):121–139.

McCrary, Justin. 2008. “Manipulation of the Running Variable in the Regression Discontinuity Design: A Density Test.” Journal of Econometrics 142 (2):698–714.

McGaughey, Ewan. 2017. “The Codetermination Bargains: The History of German Corporate and .” Columbia Journal of European Law 23 (1):135–176.

Müller, Steffen and Jens Stegmaier. 2020. “Why Is There Resistance to Works Councils in Germany? An Economic Perspective.” Economic and Industrial Democracy 41 (3):540–561.

Pan, Yihui, Tracy Yue Wang, and Michael Weisbach. 2016. “CEO Investment Cycles.” The Review of Financial Studies 29 (11):2955–2999.

Paster, Thomas. 2012. “Do German Employers Support Board-level Codetermination? The Paradox of Individual Support and Collective Opposition.” Socio-Economic Review 10 (3):471– 495.

Piketty, Thomas. 2020. Capital and Ideology. Harvard University Press.

38 Raiser, Thomas, Rüdiger Veil, and Matthias Jacobs. 2015. Mitbestimmungsgesetz und Drittel- beteiligungsgesetz. Walter de Gruyter GmbH & Co KG.

Rapp, Marc Steffen, Michael Wolff, Jan Hennig, and Iuliia Udoieva. 2019. “Mitbestimmung im Aufsichtsrat und ihre Wirkung auf die Unterenhmensführung: Eine empirische Analyse vor dem Hintergrund der Finanz-und Wirtschaftskrise.” Study Nr. 424, Hans-Böckler-Stiftung .

Redeker, Nils. 2019. “The Politics of Stashing Wealth: The Demise of Labor Power and the Global Rise of Corporate Savings.” Center for Comparative and International Studies (CIS) .

Rehder, Britta. 2003. Betriebliche Bündnisse für Arbeit in Deutschland: Mitbestimmung und Flächentarif im Wandel. Campus Verlag.

Saez, Emmanuel, Benjamin Schoefer, and David Seim. 2019. “Payroll Taxes, Firm Behavior, and Rent Sharing: Evidence from a Young Workers’ Tax Cut in .” American Economic Review 109 (5):1717–63.

Schawilye, Ramona, Eduard Gaugler, and Detlef Keese. 1999. “Das Gesetz für kleine Aktienge- sellschaften und zur Deregulierung des Aktienrechts.” In Die kleine AG in der betrieblichen Praxis. Springer, 1–10.

Schnabel, Claus and Joachim Wagner. 1996. “Ausmaß und Bestimmungsgründe der Mit- gliedschaft in Arbeitgeberverbänden: eine empirische Untersuchung mit Firmendaten.” Industrielle Beziehungen/The German Journal of Industrial Relations 3 (4):293–306.

Scholz, Robert and Sigurt Vitols. 2019. “Board-Level Codetermination: A Driving Force for Corporate Social Responsibility in German Companies?” European Journal of Industrial Relations 25 (3):233–246.

Steger, Thomas. 2011. “Context, Enactment and Contribution of Employee Voice in the Boardroom: Evidence From Large German Companies.” International Journal of Business Governance and Ethics 6 (2):111–134.

Streeck, Wolfgang. 1984. “Co-Determination: The Fourth Decade.” In International Perspectives of Organizational Democracy. John Wiley & Sons.

Svejnar, Jan. 1981. “Relative Wage Effects of Unions, Dictatorship and Codetermination: Econometric Evidence From Germany.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 63:188–197.

Thelen, Kathleen Ann. 1991. Union of Parts: Labor Politics in Postwar Germany. Cornell University Press.

Western, Bruce and Jake Rosenfeld. 2011. “Unions, Norms, and the Rise in US Wage Inequality.” American Sociological Review 76 (4):513–537.

Winkler, Heinrich August. 1998. Weimar 1918-1933: Die Geschichte der ersten deutschen Demokratie. CH Beck.

39 Tables

Table I: Effect of Shared Governance on Wages

Log Wage, Log Wage, % Above SocSec Log Wage, AKM Firm AKM Worker Labor Mean p50 Maximum Mincer Resid. Fixed Effect Fixed Effect Share (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.025 0.037 0.014 -0.004 0.011 0.009 -0.029 (0.039) (0.043) (0.019) (0.028) (0.015) (0.021) (0.034)

Industry-Year FE -0.012 -0.013 -0.004 -0.025 0.004 -0.021 -0.034 (0.041) (0.043) (0.020) (0.030) (0.016) (0.018) (0.035)

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE 0.017 0.028 0.014 -0.010 0.010 0.006 -0.035 (0.039) (0.043) (0.019) (0.028) (0.015) (0.021) (0.035)

Industry-Year FE 0.003 0.003 0.004 -0.018 0.010 -0.016 -0.033 (0.037) (0.040) (0.017) (0.028) (0.015) (0.018) (0.033)

Panel C: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.080 0.049 0.007 0.012 0.023 -0.010 -0.029 (0.082) (0.089) (0.039) (0.059) (0.031) (0.042) (0.069)

Industry-Year FE 0.062 0.045 0.013 -0.010 0.010 0.006 0.025 (0.091) (0.096) (0.045) (0.069) (0.034) (0.042) (0.067)

Control Mean: Stock Cs 4.576 4.672 0.130 0.087 -0.008 0.120 0.728 N, Stock Cs 229 229 229 229 226 226 151 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 2,667 2,667 920

Control Mean: LLCs 4.366 4.434 0.049 -0.064 -0.057 -0.032 0.757 N, LLCs 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,047 12,047 3,694 N, Firm-Years LLCs 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 116,932 116,932 18,008

Note: The table reports the effect of shared governance on wages. Panel A reports the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in simple difference specifications (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window ˆ before vs. after the August 10, 1994 cutoff date. Panel B reports difference-in-differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as a controlˆ group. Panel C reports estimates γRD from the RD specifications in Equation (3). We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixedˆ effects. All outcomes, with the exception of the share variable in Column (3), are winsorized at the 1% level by year. The control means refer to observations of firms incorporated on or after August 10, 1994. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

40 Table II: Effect of Shared Governance on Labor Productivity and Capital Intensity

Log VA Log Value Log Revenue Log Log Emp Log Emp Log Log Log Fixed A. Log Tang. A. per Emp Added per Emp. Revenue (BvD) (IAB) Fixed A. Tang. A. per Emp per Emp. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.075 0.022 0.058 0.159 0.070 0.045 0.500 0.323 0.478∗ 0.273 (0.118) (0.221) (0.154) (0.264) (0.158) (0.144) (0.322) (0.283) (0.260) (0.209)

Industry-Year FE 0.022 -0.233 0.137 0.212 0.005 0.056 0.546 0.490 0.587∗∗ 0.486∗∗ (0.114) (0.229) (0.140) (0.266) (0.158) (0.153) (0.352) (0.299) (0.273) (0.224)

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE 0.074 0.015 0.055 0.152 0.050 0.065 0.431 0.270 0.443∗ 0.253 (0.119) (0.224) (0.154) (0.265) (0.160) (0.144) (0.323) (0.284) (0.261) (0.211)

Industry-Year FE 0.055 -0.033 0.177 0.296 0.092 0.046 0.514 0.394 0.492∗∗ 0.338∗ (0.113) (0.226) (0.141) (0.260) (0.154) (0.136) (0.317) (0.264) (0.250) (0.196) 41 Control Mean: Stock Cs 11.367 16.062 12.262 16.526 4.174 3.880 13.966 12.962 9.962 8.935 N, Stock Cs 146 152 171 178 212 229 217 217 212 211 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 894 923 892 982 1,367 3,179 1,548 1,535 1,359 1,350

Control Mean: LLCs 11.074 15.215 11.976 15.264 3.318 3.255 12.424 12.132 9.243 8.935 N, LLCs 3,524 3,715 8,776 9,242 11,096 12,639 11,491 11,407 11,000 10,916 N, Firm-Years LLCs 16,783 18,110 35,983 43,434 57,006 146,289 72,988 72,177 56,265 55,724

Note: The table reports the effect of shared governance on measures of productivity and capital intensity. Panel A reports the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in simple difference specifications (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window before vs. after the August 10, 1994 cutoff date. Panelˆ B reports difference-in-differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as a control group. ˆ Appendix Table A.7 reports estimates γRD from the RD specifications in Equation (3), but features substantially wider confidence intervals. We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-yearˆ fixed effects. All outcomes are winsorized at the 1% level by year. The control means refer to observations of firms incorporated on or after August 10, 1994. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Figures

Figure I: Corporate Governance and Worker Representation on Supervisory Board

(a) One-Third Worker Representation (b) No Worker Representation

Shareholders Shareholders

Elect Elect

Supervisory Board Supervisory Board Major Major Decisions Decisions Elect

Appoint Appoint Control Control Report Report Dismiss Dismiss Executive Board Executive Board

Workforce Workforce

Note: The figure illustrates the supervisory board composition and in German corporations with and without worker-elected supervisory board directors. Panel (a) illustrates the stylized corporate governance structure with one-third worker representation (here depicted as the blue, solid supervisory board members). Panel (b) shows the stylized corporate governance structure with no worker representation. Our paper studies variation in whether workers elect a third of the supervisory board members.

42 Figure II: Overview of Reform and Research Design

(a) Worker Representation by Legal Form and Incorporation Date

(b) Empirical Share of Worker Board Seats in Listed Stock Corporations

≤ 500 Employees 50 >500 Employees

40

30

20

10 Worker Share on Board

0 Incorporation before 1994 Incorporation after 1994 (Old Stock Corporations) (Young Stock Corporations)

Note: Panel (a) illustrates board codetermination rules as a function of incorporation date and legal form among firms with at most 500 employees. Stock corporations incorporated before August 10, 1994 face a mandate to have one-third worker representatives on the supervisory board. Stock corporations incorporated on or after August 10, 1994 have no worker representatives on the supervisory board. LLCs, which we use as control group in the DiD specifications, have no worker representation on the board. Regardless of incorporation date and legal form, firms with 501 to 2,000 workers have one-third representation, firms with more than 2,000 employees have quasi-parity representation. See Section 2.1 for more information. Panel (b) shows the empirical share of worker seats in listed stock corporations founded between 1989 and 1999 based on the Hoppenstedt Aktienführer, by size and incorporation date. It excludes firms founded in 1994 as incorporation is at the yearly level in the Hoppenstedt data.

43 Figure III: Validation of Design: Incorporation, Selection, and Survival

(a) Frequency of Incorporation and McCrary Test (b) Selection Into Stock Corporation Status

12 5

10 4

8 3 6 2 4

1 2 Number of Stock Corporations

0 Disc. Estimate: 0.439 (SE 0.628) Proportion Stock Corporations (ppt) 0 -24 -12 0 12 24 -24 -12 0 12 24 Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Months) Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Months)

(c) Survival Probability by Group

1 Old Stock Corporations (Shared Governance) Young Stock Corporations (No Shared Goverance) Old LLCs .8 Young LLCs

.6 Share of Cohort Surviving .4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Years Since Incorporation

Note: Panel (a) plots the frequency of the incorporation of stock corporations around the August 10, 1994 cutoff date, after which the shared governance mandate was relaxed. It reports the result of the McCrary (2008) test for a jump in the density at the threshold. Panel (b) visualizes the selection into stock corporation status as the share of a sample of all incorporations (stock corporations and LLCs) by incorporation date. Appendix Table A.1 reports corresponding regression results. Panels (a) and (b) are based on the Orbis-ADIAB data; we plot versions of Panels (a) and (b) in Appendix Figure A.1 using the Mannheim Enterprise Panel (MUP) data. Panel (c) is based on MUP data and shows survival probabilities of firms incorporated within a two-year window of August 10, 1994 separately for firms incorporated before or after the cutoff date, and for stock corporations and LLCs.

44 Figure IV: Effects on Mean Log Wages

(a) Over Time, by Group (b) By Incorporation Date and Legal Form

5 5 Old Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) Young Stock Corps (Shared Gov.)

RD: 0.062 (SE 0.091) 4.8 4.8

4.6 4.6

4.4 4.4

Old LLCs Young LLCs 4.2 4.2 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 -20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12 16 20 Year Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Quarters)

(c) Differences (Old - Young Stock Corps), (d) DiD (w/ LLCs as Additional Control Group), By Bandwidth Around Reform Date By Bandwidth Around Reform Date

.4 .4

Diff: -0.012 (SE 0.041) DiD: 0.003 (SE 0.037) .2 .2

0 0

-.2 -.2 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994) Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

Note: The figure displays the effects of shared governance on firm-level mean worker-level log wages. Panel (a) presents the time series of old (incorporated up to two years before the cutoff) and young (incorporated up to two years after the cutoff) firms, of stock corporations and LLCs, averaged by firm group and year. Panel (b) is a binned scatter plot by quarter of incorporation date around the reform cutoff with a five-year bandwidth. It also plots results of a local linear regression with a uniform kernel and a two-year bandwidth, using day-specific incorporation date as the running variable. Panels (c) and (d) plot the coefficients varying the bandwidths for, respectively, the simple difference, and difference-in-differences specifications with industry-year fixed effects and standard errors clustered at the firm level. Appendix Figure A.4 reports bandwidth and donut hole coefficient plots for the RD estimates. We report the corresponding main estimates, denoted in Panels (b), (c) and (d) (highlighted with a blue square and blue 95% confidence interval in the later two panels), in Table I Column (1).

45 Figure V: Effects on AKM Pay Premia

(a) Over Time, By Group (b) By Incorporation Date and Legal Form

4.75 .1 Old Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) Young Stock Corps (Shared Gov.)

RD: 0.010 (SE 0.034) .05 4.65

0

4.55 -.05

4.45 -.1 Old LLCs Young LLCs 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 -20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12 16 20 Year Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Quarters)

(c) Differences (Old - Young Stock Corps), (d) DiD (w/ LLCs as Additional Control Group), By Bandwidth Around Reform Date By Bandwidth Around Reform Date

.2 .2

.1 .1 DiD: 0.010 (SE 0.015) Diff: 0.004 (SE 0.016)

0 0

-.1 -.1 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994) Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

Note: The figure displays the effects of shared governance on AKM firm effects. Panel (a) presents the time series of old (incorporated up to two years before the cutoff) and young (incorporated up to two years after the cutoff) firms, of stock corporations and LLCs, averaged by firm group and year. Panel (b) is a binned scatter plot by quarter of incorporation date around the reform cutoff with a five-year bandwidth. It also plots results of a local linear regression with a uniform kernel and a two-year bandwidth, using day-specific incorporation date as the running variable. Each calendar year indicates the mid-point of a five-year estimation window of the AKM effects. (Since the levels of the AKM specifications are not comparable across years, we normalize the AKM pay premia among older stock corporations to correspond to the average log wage in this firm group within each year and adjust the premia in the other groups accordingly.) Panels (c) and (d) plot the coefficients and 95% confidence intervals varying the bandwidths for, respectively, the simple difference, and difference-in-differences specifications with industry-year fixed effects and standard errors clustered at the firm level. Appendix Figure A.4 reports bandwidth and donut hole coefficient plots for the RD estimates. We report the corresponding main estimates, denoted in Panels (b), (c) and (d) (highlighted with a blue square and blue 95% confidence interval in the later two panels), in Table I Column (5).

46 Figure VI: Effects on the Wage Distribution

.2 Difference DiD

.1

0

-.1

-.2 p10 p20 p30 p40 p50 p60 p70 p80 p90 Within-Firm Wage Percentile

Note: The figure displays the effect of shared governance on the within-firm wage distribution. Specifically we study as outcome variables the deciles of the within-firm log wage distribution in a given year. Blue squares denote the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in Equation (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window before and after the Augustˆ 10, 1994 cutoff date. Grey hollow circles denote difference-in- differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as a control group.ˆ We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixed effects. The vertical lines denote 95% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at the firm level. Appendix Table A.3 reports the full regression results; Appendix Figure A.5 reports the estimates from the RD specifications.

47 Figure VII: Effects on Labor Productivity and Capital Intensity

(a) Log Value Added per Worker (b) Differences (Old - Young Stock Corps)

12 4.5

3.5

11.5 2.5

1.5 11 .5 Diff: 0.022 (SE 0.114)

10.5 -.5 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Year Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

(c) Log Fixed Assets (d) Differences (Old - Young Stock Corps)

15.5 4.5

3.5 14.5

2.5 Diff: 0.546 (SE 0.352) 13.5 1.5

12.5 .5

11.5 -.5 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Year Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

(e) Log Fixed Assets per Worker (f) Differences (Old - Young Stock Corps)

11.5 4.5

3.5

10.5 2.5 Diff: 0.587 (SE 0.273) 1.5 9.5 .5

8.5 -.5 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Year Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

Note: The figure displays the effects of shared governance on firm-level labor productivity and capital. The left column presents the time series of old (incorporated up to two years before the cutoff) and young (incorporated up to two years after the cutoff) firms, of stock corporations and LLCs, averaged by firm group and year. The right column plots coefficients and 95% confidence intervals varying the bandwidth for simple difference specifications with industry-year effects and standard errors clustered at the firm level. We report the corresponding main estimates, denoted in Panels (b), (d), and (f) by the highlighted blue square and blue 95% confidence interval, in Table II Columns (1), (7), and (9). For each outcome, Appendix Figure A.6 reports additional results, namely scatter plots by quarter of incorporation along with RD estimates, and bandwidth plots of DiD specifications with industry-year fixed effects. 48 Figure VIII: Rent Sharing in Stock Corporations with and without Shared Governance: Firms’ Pay Premia (AKM Firm Fixed Effects) and Value Added per Worker

.2 Old Stock Corp's (Shared Gov.) Young Stock Corp's (No Shared Gov.)

.1

0

-.1 Slope of Control Group (Young Stock Corps): 0.067 (SE 0.018) Simple Difference Effect (Old - Young Stock Corps): 0.010 (SE 0.026) Residualized Firm Pay Premia -.2 DiD Effect (w/ LLCs as Additional Control Group): 0.007 (SE 0.022) -2 -1 0 1 2 Residualized Firm-Level Mean of Log Value Added per Worker

Note: This figure presents a binned scatter plot of firm’s average pay premia (AKM firm fixed effects) plotted against average log value added per worker in the 2006-14 sample of the Orbis-ADIAB data. The AKM firm fixed effects are estimated in a five-year rolling window and then averaged by firm. Both variables are residualized by industry (2-digit NACE) fixed effects. The figure draws on our analysis sample of stock corporations incorporated two years around the reform date. It separately plots the observations for older firms, i.e. with shared governance, in solid navy circles and a solid estimated linear regression line, and for younger firms, i.e. without shared governance, in hollow red circles and a dashed regression line. We report the slope of young stock corporations (the control group) in the bottom right along with standard errors. We also report the estimates of the slope from the simple difference and difference-in-differences specifications (with LLCs as a second control group) in the lower right-hand corner. Appendix Figure A.7 displays the pooled rent sharing elasticity including both stock corporations and LLCs.

49 Figure IX: Heterogeneity Analysis: Wage Effect (AKM Pay Premia) of Shared Governance in Subsamples of Firms

Mean of Sorting Variable:

Below: 0.425 CBA Coverage Above: 0.796

Binding 0.108 CBA Coverage 0.254

AKM Pay 0.135 Premia SD 0.161

Industry AKM 0.059 0.150

Works Council 0.572 0.835 Below Median: Diff Log Value Added 10.916 DiD per Worker 11.365 Above Median: Tenure 3.014 Diff 6.562 DiD

-.15 -.1 -.05 0 .05 .1 .15

Note: The figure reports heterogeneity in the effect of shared governance on the AKM firm fixed effect. We report the results for the effect on log mean wages in Appendix Figure A.8. We split the firm sample at the median according the 3-digit NACE industry average of the variables reported on the left-hand side. Solid (hollow) symbols denote the estimate of the sample with values below (above) the median. We highlight the simple difference specification in blue, and report DiD specification in gray symbols. We also print the means of the sorting (heterogeneity) variables on the left column, as shown in the figure. The means are calculated for stock corporations in a two-year bandwidth around the reform. To illustrate, we find a small negative point estimate for the effect on pay premia among firms in industries with below-median works council prevalence, and a small positive point estimate among those with above-median prevalence. The CBA and works council variables are based on the IAB Establishment Panel from 2008 onward; the remaining variables based on the Orbis-ADIAB data. All specifications include 2-digit NACE industry-year fixed effects. The horizontal lines indicate 95% confidence intervals, with standard errors clustered at the firm level. See Section 6.5 for more information; Appendix Table A.11 reports the detailed regression results.

50 Online Appendix of: Labor in the Boardroom Simon Jäger, Benjamin Schoefer and Jörg Heining

51 Contents

List of Tables

A.1 Differential Trends for Incorporation of Stock Corporations ...... 53 A.2 1994 Reform and Industry Composition of Stock Corporations ...... 54 A.3 Effects on the Wage Distribution ...... 55 A.4 Placebo: Effect of Shared Governance on Wages (Placebo Reforms in 1996 and 1997) ...... 56 A.5 Effect of Shared Governance on Wages (Non-Missing Fixed Assets) ...... 57 A.6 Effect of Shared Governance on Wages (Non-Missing Value Added per Worker) 58 A.7 Placebo: Effect of Shared Governance on Labor Productivity and Capital Intensity (RD and Placebo Reforms in 1996 and 1997) ...... 59 A.8 Effect of Shared Governance on Profitability ...... 60 A.9 Placebo: Effect of Shared Governance on Profitability (Placebo Reforms in 1996 and 1997) ...... 61 A.10 Effect of Shared Governance on Skill Structure, Outsourcing, and Tenure (Matched Employer-Employee Data) ...... 62 A.11 Heterogeneity of Shared Governance Effects on Wages ...... 63

List of Figures

A.1 Frequency of Incorporation and Selection: MUP Data ...... 65 A.2 Balance of Industry Composition ...... 66 A.3 Firm Survival and Bankruptcy by Incorporation Date and Corporation Type . . 67 A.4 Robustness of RD Estimates of Effects on Mean Log Wage and AKM Pay Premia: Varying the Bandwidth, and Donut Holes ...... 68 A.5 Additional RD Specifications: Effects on the Wage Distribution ...... 69 A.6 Effects on Labor Productivity and Capital Intensity ...... 70 A.7 Pooled Rent Sharing: Firms’ Pay Premia (AKM Firm Fixed Effects) and Value Added per Worker ...... 71 A.8 Additional Results for Heterogeneity Analysis: Wage Effect of Shared Gover- nance in Subsamples of Firms ...... 72

52 A Additional Tables

Table A.1: Differential Trends for Incorporation of Stock Corporations

1(Inc. as Stock Corp.) (1) (2)

Incorporation Date 0.352 0.269 (0.325) (0.323)

1(Pre-Reform) 0.005 -0.040 (0.470) (0.465)

Inc. Date × 1(Pre-Reform) 0.046 0.139 (0.403) (0.398)

Industry FE X N, Stock Cs 231 230

N, LLCs 12,643 12,640

Note: This table reports estimates of whether the reform had an effect on firms’ decision to incorporate as a stock corporation (AG). We test for differential trends before and after the reform by interacting an indicator for whether the firm incorporated pre-reform with a continuous time trend variable (denominated in years) for incorporation date relative to August 10, 1994. Estimates are in percentage points. The sample is restricted to stock corporations ( and limited liability companies (LLCs) with 10 or more employees incorporated within two years of the reform date of August 10, 1994. Column (1) reports the basic specification and Column (2) includes industry fixed effects. The observations are firms rather than firm-years. Standard errors clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Figure III Panel (b) plots the underlying data.

53 Table A.2: 1994 Reform and Industry Composition of Stock Corporations

NACE Industry Classification DiD Diff RD NACE Industry Classification DiD Diff RD

B: Mining and quarrying 0.012 0.011 K: Financial and insurance activities -0.034 -0.038 -0.036 (0.011)(0.011) × (0.029)(0.029)(0.060) Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.0000 0.0000 Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.071 0.071 0.071 Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.002 n/a Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.008 n/a n/a

C: Manufacturing -0.011 -0.009 0.136 L: Real estate activities 0.017 0.015 (0.047)(0.047)(0.100) (0.017)(0.017) × Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.142 0.142 0.142 Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.007 0.007 Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.213 n/a n/a Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.023 n/a

F: Construction -0.022 -0.031 -0.018 M: Professional, scientific, and technical activities 0.060 0.063 -0.109 (0.021)(0.020)(0.048) (0.055)(0.055)(0.113) Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.043 0.043 0.043 Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.170 0.170 0.170 Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.151 n/a n/a Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.057 n/a n/a

G: Wholesale and trade; repair of motor vehicles-0.092∗ -0.069 -0.014 N: Administrative and support service activities -0.023 -0.030 -0.025 (0.048)(0.048)(0.099) (0.034)(0.034)(0.069) Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.191 0.191 0.191 Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.085 0.085 0.085 Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.242 n/a n/a Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.075 n/a n/a

H: Transportation and storage 0.019 0.023 0.045 R: Arts, entertainment, and recreation 0.007 0.004 (0.025)(0.025)(0.046) (0.013)(0.013) × Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.021 0.021 0.021 Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.007 0.007 Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.052 n/a n/a Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.011 n/a

J: Information and communication 0.057 0.053 -0.031 S: Other services activities -0.004 -0.007 (0.056)(0.056)(0.109) (0.007)(0.007) × Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.191 0.191 0.191 Control Mean: Post-Reform Stock Cs 0.007 0.007 Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.056 n/a n/a Control Mean: Post-Reform LLCs 0.017 n/a

N, Firms 12,874 231 231 N, Stock Cs. 231 231 231 N, LLCs 12,643 n/a n/a Joint P-Value 0.384 0.396 0.828

Note: This table reports estimates of the effect of shared governance on the industry composition of stock corporations. Formally, we use indicators for each NACE Rev. 2 Classification 1 industry code as outcomes for DiD specifications as in equation (2). Some industries are excluded due to insufficient observations among stock corporations. Column “DiD” reports the basic specification from equation (2), column “Diff” reports the basic specification from (1) and column “RD” reports results from basic specification of (3). The RD design has missing entries indicated by as those cells had zero observations in those industries among young stock corporations. We visually report all× estimates in Panel (c) of Figure. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

54 Table A.3: Effects on the Wage Distribution

Outcome Mean Log Wage Percentile p10 p20 p30 p40 p50 p60 p70 p80 p90 Panel A: Actual Reform (1994)

Difference 0.006 -0.026 -0.019 -0.012 -0.013 -0.014 -0.010 -0.003 -0.004 Industry-Year FE (0.074) (0.061) (0.052) (0.046) (0.043) (0.041) (0.039) (0.035) (0.029)

DiD 0.024 -0.001 -0.004 0.001 0.003 0.004 0.006 0.009 0.004 Industry-Year FE (0.063) (0.053) (0.047) (0.042) (0.040) (0.039) (0.037) (0.033) (0.028)

RD 0.199 0.095 0.045 0.049 0.045 0.050 0.052 0.039 0.021 Industry-Year FE (0.151) (0.128) (0.109) (0.100) (0.096) (0.095) (0.090) (0.083) (0.072) Control Mean: Stock Cs 3.953 4.284 4.456 4.574 4.672 4.758 4.845 4.941 5.051 N, Stock Cs 229 229 229 229 229 229 229 229 229 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 3,179 Control Mean: LLCs 3.823 4.097 4.248 4.351 4.434 4.509 4.586 4.675 4.802 N, LLCs 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 12,639 N, Firm-Years LLCs 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 146,289 Panel B: Placebo Reform 1996

Difference -0.016 0.018 0.011 -0.001 -0.009 -0.022 -0.033 -0.030 -0.025 Industry-Year FE (0.062) (0.054) (0.049) (0.046) (0.044) (0.041) (0.037) (0.033) (0.026)

DiD -0.047 -0.001 -0.001 -0.010 -0.019 -0.027 -0.037 -0.033 -0.031 Industry-Year FE (0.057) (0.050) (0.045) (0.042) (0.040) (0.038) (0.036) (0.033) (0.027)

RD 0.113 0.077 0.064 0.071 0.047 0.024 0.018 0.024 0.021 Industry-Year FE (0.126) (0.110) (0.099) (0.093) (0.087) (0.081) (0.075) (0.066) (0.051) Control Mean: Stock Cs 3.968 4.267 4.448 4.584 4.695 4.792 4.889 4.980 5.083 N, Stock Cs 327 327 327 327 327 327 327 327 327 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 Control Mean: LLCs 3.808 4.083 4.235 4.340 4.424 4.500 4.579 4.669 4.795 N, LLCs 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 N, Firm-Years LLCs 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 Panel C: Placebo Reform 1997

Difference 0.062 0.061 0.040 0.036 0.044 0.047 0.046 0.041 0.033 Industry-Year FE (0.056) (0.049) (0.044) (0.040) (0.037) (0.034) (0.031) (0.027) (0.022)

DiD 0.042 0.046 0.026 0.017 0.019 0.019 0.015 0.007 0.001 Industry-Year FE (0.051) (0.045) (0.040) (0.037) (0.035) (0.033) (0.031) (0.028) (0.023)

RD 0.002 -0.013 -0.068 -0.073 -0.054 -0.048 -0.046 -0.052 -0.041 Industry-Year FE (0.113) (0.099) (0.091) (0.083) (0.077) (0.072) (0.064) (0.055) (0.044) Control Mean: Stock Cs 3.922 4.242 4.431 4.567 4.674 4.769 4.864 4.958 5.062 N, Stock Cs 456 456 456 456 456 456 456 456 456 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 Control Mean: LLCs 3.791 4.068 4.220 4.324 4.407 4.484 4.562 4.652 4.778 N, LLCs 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 N, Firm-Years LLCs 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565

Note: The table reports the effect of shared governance on the within-firm wage distribution, using as outcome variables the deciles of the intra-firm log wage distribution in a given year. The first row reports the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in simple difference specifications (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window before vs. after the Augustˆ 10, 1994 cutoff date. The second row reports difference-in-differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as ˆ a control group. The third row reports RD specifications, i.e. estimates of γRD in Equation (3). We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixed effects. All outcomes are winsorized at the 1% level byˆ year. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

55 Table A.4: Placebo: Effect of Shared Governance on Wages (Placebo Reforms in 1996 and 1997)

Log Wage, Log Wage, % Above SocSec Log Wage, AKM Firm AKM Worker Labor Mean p50 Maximum Mincer Resid. Fixed Effect Fixed Effect Share (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Panel A: Placebo Reform 1996 Panel A.a: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.020 -0.022 -0.026 -0.013 -0.019 -0.019 0.014 (0.036) (0.040) (0.016) (0.025) (0.013) (0.018) (0.031) Industry-Year FE -0.011 -0.009 -0.026 -0.009 -0.020 -0.006 0.007 (0.038) (0.044) (0.019) (0.028) (0.013) (0.019) (0.035) Panel A.b: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE -0.029 -0.033 -0.024 -0.022 -0.021 -0.022 0.023 (0.037) (0.040) (0.017) (0.025) (0.013) (0.018) (0.031) Industry-Year FE -0.025 -0.019 -0.018 -0.019 -0.023∗ -0.005 0.011 (0.036) (0.040) (0.016) (0.026) (0.013) (0.017) (0.032) Panel A.c: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.041 0.034 -0.0005 0.036 0.017 0.004 -0.009 (0.076) (0.083) (0.034) (0.056) (0.026) (0.037) (0.060) Industry-Year FE 0.052 0.047 0.005 0.033 0.016 0.013 0.027 (0.078) (0.087) (0.039) (0.058) (0.026) (0.038) (0.061) Control Mean: Stock Cs 4.595 4.695 0.157 0.104 0.009 0.144 0.713 N, Stock Cs 327 327 327 327 319 319 187 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 4,001 4,001 4,001 4,001 3,227 3,227 1,094 Control Mean: LLCs 4.356 4.424 0.051 -0.070 -0.061 -0.030 0.765 N, LLCs 13,574 13,574 13,574 13,574 12,878 12,878 3,935 N, Firm-Years LLCs 143,087 143,087 143,087 143,087 111,707 111,707 18,679 Panel B: Placebo Reform 1997 Panel B.a: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.036 0.032 0.0005 0.013 0.010 0.0004 0.030 (0.033) (0.036) (0.015) (0.023) (0.011) (0.016) (0.027) Industry-Year FE 0.043 0.044 0.003 0.019 0.013 0.012 0.031 (0.034) (0.037) (0.016) (0.024) (0.012) (0.015) (0.030) Panel B.b: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE 0.011 0.004 -0.002 -0.008 0.0006 -0.010 0.037 (0.033) (0.036) (0.015) (0.023) (0.012) (0.016) (0.027) Industry-Year FE 0.018 0.019 0.003 -0.007 0.002 0.005 0.046∗ (0.032) (0.035) (0.014) (0.023) (0.011) (0.015) (0.028) Panel B.c: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.036 -0.058 -0.006 -0.046 -0.007 -0.046 0.037 (0.069) (0.076) (0.031) (0.043) (0.023) (0.032) (0.049) Industry-Year FE -0.042 -0.054 -0.011 -0.047 -0.003 -0.025 0.015 (0.070) (0.077) (0.032) (0.045) (0.024) (0.030) (0.055) Control Mean: Stock Cs 4.571 4.674 0.151 0.100 -0.002 0.137 0.708 N, Stock Cs 456 456 456 456 444 444 242 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 5,184 5,184 5,184 5,184 4,068 4,068 1,393 Control Mean: LLCs 4.340 4.407 0.050 -0.079 -0.067 -0.035 0.767 N, LLCs 14,770 14,770 14,770 14,770 13,951 13,951 4,267 N, Firm-Years LLCs 148,565 148,565 148,565 148,565 113,990 113,990 19,944

Note: The table reports placebo specifications for the effect of shared governance on wages. Panel A reports results for a counterfactual reform on August 10, 1996, Panel B for a placebo reform on August 10, 1997. Panel A.a and B.a reports the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in simple difference specifications (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window beforeˆ vs. after the August 10, 1994 cutoff date. Panels A.b and B.b report difference-in-differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal ˆ form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as a control group. Panels A.c and B.c report estimates γRD from the RD specifications in Equation (3). We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixedˆ effects. All outcomes are winsorized at the 1% level by year. The control means refer to observations of firms incorporated on or after August 10, 1994. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. We report main estimates in Table I.

56 Table A.5: Effect of Shared Governance on Wages (Non-Missing Fixed Assets)

Log Wage,Log Wage,% Above SocSec Log Wage, AKM Firm AKM Worker Labor Mean p50 Maximum Mincer Resid.Fixed Effect Fixed Effect Share (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.025 0.041 0.018 -0.004 0.013 0.014 -0.029 (0.046) (0.048) (0.020) (0.031) (0.016) (0.024) (0.034)

Industry-Year FE -0.018 -0.013 -0.002 -0.026 0.001 -0.013 -0.034 (0.045) (0.047) (0.021) (0.034) (0.016) (0.022) (0.035)

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE 0.019 0.037 0.018 -0.008 0.013 0.013 -0.035 (0.046) (0.048) (0.020) (0.032) (0.016) (0.024) (0.035)

Industry-Year FE 0.005 0.010 0.009 -0.016 0.015 -0.010 -0.033 (0.042) (0.044) (0.018) (0.031) (0.016) (0.020) (0.033)

Panel C: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.069 0.032 0.014 0.000 0.015 -0.010 -0.029 (0.098) (0.102) (0.043) (0.069) (0.034) (0.049) (0.069)

Industry-Year FE 0.056 0.038 0.021 -0.019 0.001 0.006 0.025 (0.101) (0.104) (0.050) (0.074) (0.037) (0.047) (0.067)

Control Mean: Stock Cs 4.567 4.665 0.131 0.100 -0.007 0.123 0.728 N, Stock Cs 217 217 217 217 212 212 151 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 1,548 1,548 1,548 1,548 1,275 1,275 920

Control Mean: LLCs 4.342 4.414 0.049 -0.053 -0.057 -0.032 0.756 N, LLCs 11,491 11,491 11,491 11,491 11,011 11,011 3,675 N, Firm-Years LLCs 72,988 72,988 72,988 72,988 58,278 58,278 17,855

Note: This table replicates Table I for non-missing firm-year BvD observations of fixed assets.

57 Table A.6: Effect of Shared Governance on Wages (Non-Missing Value Added per Worker)

Log Wage, Log Wage, % Above SocSec Log Wage, AKM Firm AKM Worker Labor Mean p50 Maximum Mincer Resid. Fixed Effect Fixed Effect Share (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.002 0.023 0.012 -0.023 0.003 0.004 -0.032 (0.055) (0.060) (0.026) (0.036) (0.020) (0.028) (0.035)

Industry-Year FE -0.042 -0.032 -0.018 -0.035 0.001 -0.034 -0.040 (0.056) (0.058) (0.027) (0.039) (0.020) (0.028) (0.035)

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE 0.008 0.034 0.016 -0.013 0.009 0.005 -0.039 (0.056) (0.060) (0.026) (0.037) (0.020) (0.029) (0.035)

Industry-Year FE -0.009 0.003 -0.000 -0.018 0.012 -0.016 -0.037 (0.049) (0.053) (0.023) (0.036) (0.019) (0.024) (0.033)

Panel C: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.102 0.051 -0.010 0.063 0.013 -0.012 -0.035 (0.122) (0.131) (0.056) (0.084) (0.045) (0.058) (0.069)

Industry-Year FE 0.094 0.074 -0.004 0.050 0.023 -0.003 0.014 (0.123) (0.134) (0.064) (0.086) (0.046) (0.058) (0.067)

Control Mean: Stock Cs 4.628 4.716 0.158 0.143 0.022 0.134 0.729 N, Stock Cs 146 146 146 146 144 144 146 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 894 894 894 894 740 740 892

Control Mean: LLCs 4.505 4.558 0.094 0.075 -0.003 0.019 0.754 N, LLCs 3,524 3,524 3,524 3,524 3,395 3,395 3,508 N, Firm-Years LLCs 16,783 16,783 16,783 16,783 14,211 14,211 16,707

Note: This table replicates Table I for non-missing firm-year BvD observations of value added per worker.

58 Table A.7: Placebo: Effect of Shared Governance on Labor Productivity and Capital Intensity (RD and Placebo Reforms in 1996 and 1997)

Log VA Log Value Log Revenue Log Log Emp Log Emp Log Log Log Fixed A. Log Tang. A. per Emp Added per Emp. Revenue (BvD) (IAB) Fixed A. Tang. A. per Emp per Emp. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) Panel A: Actual Reform (1994) Panel A.a: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.186 -0.109 0.094 0.515 0.345 0.124 0.928 0.528 0.534 0.208 (0.223) (0.453) (0.284) (0.536) (0.356) (0.335) (0.681) (0.578) (0.551) (0.409) Industry-Year FE -0.257 -0.447 0.014 0.288 0.144 -0.101 0.935 0.496 0.772 0.368 (0.241) (0.438) (0.337) (0.623) (0.363) (0.336) (0.766) (0.607) (0.547) (0.437) Control Mean: Stock Cs 11.367 16.062 12.262 16.526 4.174 3.880 13.966 12.962 9.962 8.935 N, Stock Cs 146 152 171 178 212 229 217 217 212 211 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 894 923 892 982 1,367 3,179 1,548 1,535 1,359 1,350 Panel B: Placebo Reform 1996 Panel B.a: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.038 0.084 0.082 0.318 0.220 0.199 0.042 0.278 -0.216 0.055 (0.097) (0.192) (0.130) (0.224) (0.143) (0.132) (0.254) (0.229) (0.203) (0.173) Industry-Year FE -0.102 0.0009 0.003 0.177 0.154 0.147 -0.082 0.070 -0.234 -0.071 (0.104) (0.225) (0.142) (0.248) (0.154) (0.144) (0.279) (0.226) (0.221) (0.167) Panel B.b: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE -0.026 0.118 0.073 0.285 0.186 0.210 -0.053 0.172 -0.258 0.005 (0.098) (0.196) (0.130) (0.225) (0.145) (0.133) (0.256) (0.230) (0.205) (0.175) Industry-Year FE -0.042 0.114 -0.025 0.224 0.183 0.215 -0.098 0.113 -0.297 -0.067 (0.098) (0.199) (0.120) (0.221) (0.142) (0.131) (0.252) (0.212) (0.202) (0.162) Panel B.c: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.059 0.073 0.321 0.658 0.106 0.150 0.216 0.140 0.075 0.085 (0.195) (0.365) (0.267) (0.443) (0.296) (0.273) (0.537) (0.470) (0.413) (0.331) Industry-Year FE -0.026 -0.067 0.220 0.473 0.013 0.039 -0.048 0.024 -0.143 0.023 (0.190) (0.359) (0.288) (0.487) (0.321) (0.300) (0.550) (0.448) (0.413) (0.302) Control Mean: Stock Cs 11.407 15.969 12.180 16.205 3.951 3.680 13.924 12.684 10.176 8.879 N, Stock Cs 184 187 251 258 305 327 312 312 304 303 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 1,061 1,101 1,264 1,406 1,861 4,001 2,148 2,132 1,851 1,842 Control Mean: LLCs 11.086 15.246 11.969 15.230 3.283 3.266 12.330 12.026 9.200 8.885 N, LLCs 3,748 3,951 9,377 9,930 11,922 13,574 12,432 12,331 11,802 11,717 N, Firm-Years LLCs 17,341 18,786 37,961 46,015 60,059 143,087 77,233 76,362 59,142 58,567 Panel C: Placebo Reform 1997 Panel C.a: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.120 0.035 0.055 0.349∗ 0.328∗∗∗ 0.236∗∗ 0.349 0.500∗∗ -0.015 0.134 (0.087) (0.169) (0.112) (0.196) (0.124) (0.112) (0.227) (0.202) (0.179) (0.149) Industry-Year FE -0.197∗∗ 0.083 -0.018 0.341 0.381∗∗∗ 0.283∗∗ 0.368 0.405∗∗ -0.052 0.020 (0.093) (0.193) (0.114) (0.213) (0.132) (0.118) (0.239) (0.198) (0.182) (0.139) Panel C.b: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE -0.132 -0.042 0.024 0.248 0.246∗ 0.204∗ 0.261 0.382∗ -0.029 0.096 (0.089) (0.174) (0.114) (0.198) (0.126) (0.113) (0.228) (0.204) (0.181) (0.152) Industry-Year FE -0.165∗ -0.057 -0.053 0.193 0.232∗ 0.194∗ 0.161 0.268 -0.124 -0.015 (0.088) (0.176) (0.107) (0.195) (0.126) (0.112) (0.228) (0.194) (0.178) (0.142) Panel C.c: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.142 0.284 -0.269 -0.152 0.273 0.156 -0.072 0.301 -0.391 0.040 (0.177) (0.325) (0.194) (0.377) (0.249) (0.231) (0.443) (0.390) (0.343) (0.285) Industry-Year FE -0.106 0.521 -0.340 -0.122 0.330 0.195 -0.122 0.207 -0.429 0.005 (0.183) (0.329) (0.211) (0.376) (0.246) (0.229) (0.454) (0.364) (0.352) (0.269) Control Mean: Stock Cs 11.481 15.973 12.164 16.102 3.831 3.617 13.761 12.509 10.119 8.830 N, Stock Cs 237 242 354 364 425 456 437 435 423 421 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 1,358 1,402 1,772 1,949 2,523 5,184 2,923 2,903 2,516 2,500 Control Mean: LLCs 11.061 15.176 11.950 15.173 3.244 3.262 12.305 11.991 9.199 8.874 N, LLCs 4,074 4,285 10,213 10,802 13,016 14,770 13,588 13,468 12,894 12,791 N, Firm-Years LLCs 18,537 20,054 41,311 50,049 65,240 148,565 83,976 82,990 64,291 63,634

Note: This table replicates Table II for RD specifications (Panel A) and placebo reforms (Panel B and Panel C).

59 Table A.8: Effect of Shared Governance on Profitability

EBITDA EBIT Net Income EBITDA EBIT Net Income /Revenue /Revenue /Revenue /Total A. /Total A. /Total A. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.004 -0.070 0.018 0.013 -0.009 -0.006 (0.015) (0.045) (0.031) (0.020) (0.020) (0.013)

Industry-Year FE -0.011 -0.071 -0.012 0.003 -0.011 -0.010 (0.020) (0.049) (0.037) (0.023) (0.025) (0.015)

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE 0.007 -0.068 0.015 0.016 -0.008 -0.007 (0.015) (0.045) (0.031) (0.021) (0.021) (0.013)

Industry-Year FE -0.004 -0.056 -0.000 0.006 -0.011 -0.009 (0.015) (0.042) (0.029) (0.021) (0.021) (0.013)

Panel C: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.007 0.084 -0.049 -0.072 -0.037 -0.033 (0.027) (0.081) (0.056) (0.049) (0.048) (0.029)

Industry-Year FE -0.006 0.111 -0.092 -0.105∗ -0.064 -0.042 (0.043) (0.104) (0.085) (0.059) (0.057) (0.035)

Control Mean: Stock Cs 0.098 0.013 0.056 0.162 0.086 0.057 N, Stock Cs 124 131 131 145 152 152 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 562 715 699 772 945 929

Control Mean: LLCs 0.083 0.037 0.024 0.177 0.104 0.057 N, LLCs 2,938 3,060 3,029 3,597 3,726 3,697 N, Firm-Years LLCs 11,160 12,417 11,898 16,527 18,228 17,704

Note: The table reports the effect of shared governance on measures of profitability. Panel A reports the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in simple difference specifications (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year window beforeˆ vs. after the August 10, 1994 cutoff date. Panel B reports difference-in-differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as ˆ a control group. Panel C reports estimates γRD from the RD specifications in Equation (3). We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixedˆ effects. All outcomes are winsorized at the 1% level by year. The control means refer to observations of firms incorporated on or after August 10, 1994. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Appendix Table A.9 reports effects of placebo reforms.

60 Table A.9: Placebo: Effect of Shared Governance on Profitability (Placebo Reforms in 1996 and 1997)

EBITDA EBIT Net Income EBITDA EBIT Net Income /Revenue /Revenue /Revenue /Total A. /Total A. /Total A. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Panel A: Placebo Reform 1996 Panel A.a: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.018 0.036 -0.017 0.014 0.015 0.009 (0.015) (0.030) (0.023) (0.018) (0.017) (0.012) Industry-Year FE -0.021 0.016 -0.022 0.007 -0.004 -0.0008 (0.016) (0.037) (0.027) (0.024) (0.022) (0.016) Panel A.b: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE -0.013 0.035 -0.015 0.020 0.013 0.010 (0.015) (0.030) (0.023) (0.019) (0.018) (0.012) Industry-Year FE -0.002 0.038 -0.011 0.039∗∗ 0.026 0.017 (0.015) (0.030) (0.021) (0.020) (0.018) (0.013) Panel A.c: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.002 0.111 -0.037 -0.000026 0.015 0.015 (0.031) (0.069) (0.051) (0.034) (0.029) (0.022) Industry-Year FE 0.006 0.132∗∗ -0.067 -0.006 -0.003 -0.004 (0.026) (0.065) (0.048) (0.048) (0.039) (0.025) Control Mean: Stock Cs 0.116 -0.025 0.070 0.148 0.066 0.044 N, Stock Cs 162 169 169 179 187 187 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 722 902 885 929 1,131 1,114 Control Mean: LLCs 0.088 0.033 0.024 0.183 0.096 0.054 N, LLCs 3,210 3,361 3,318 3,817 3,961 3,923 N, Firm-Years LLCs 12,197 13,680 13,047 17,017 18,898 18,271 Panel B: Placebo Reform 1997 Panel B.a: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.020 0.033 -0.019 -0.032∗∗ -0.009 -0.006 (0.012) (0.031) (0.023) (0.014) (0.014) (0.012) Industry-Year FE -0.039∗∗∗ 0.023 -0.013 -0.032∗ -0.011 -0.001 (0.014) (0.039) (0.027) (0.019) (0.018) (0.014) Panel B.b: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE -0.018 0.035 -0.019 -0.035∗∗ -0.012 -0.011 (0.013) (0.031) (0.023) (0.015) (0.014) (0.012) Industry-Year FE -0.018 0.040 -0.015 -0.027∗ -0.007 -0.006 (0.013) (0.032) (0.023) (0.015) (0.015) (0.012) Panel B.c: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.039 -0.091∗ -0.025 -0.014 -0.025 -0.020 (0.025) (0.053) (0.043) (0.029) (0.027) (0.022) Industry-Year FE -0.058∗∗ -0.069 -0.007 -0.041 -0.036 -0.010 (0.029) (0.060) (0.045) (0.039) (0.033) (0.022) Control Mean: Stock Cs 0.114 -0.051 0.067 0.161 0.061 0.043 N, Stock Cs 210 226 225 226 243 242 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 925 1,230 1,215 1,137 1,463 1,449 Control Mean: LLCs 0.087 0.033 0.023 0.179 0.093 0.051 N, LLCs 3,488 3,654 3,610 4,130 4,295 4,255 N, Firm-Years LLCs 13,113 14,740 14,090 18,087 20,183 19,543

Note: This table replicates Table A.8 for the placebo reforms.

61 Table A.10: Effect of Shared Governance on Skill Structure, Outsourcing, and Tenure (Matched Employer- Employee Data)

Low- Med- High- Outsourceable Value Added Log Tenure Separation Skilled % Skilled % Skilled % (FSCL) % /Revenue Tenure (Years) Rate (Annual) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE -0.019 0.001 0.017 -0.009 0.101 0.071 0.235 -0.003 (0.031) (0.024) (0.038) (0.015) (0.079) (0.052) (0.279) (0.006)

Industry-Year FE 0.006 0.010 -0.017 0.012 0.008 0.077 0.332 -0.001 (0.031) (0.027) (0.039) (0.009) (0.081) (0.054) (0.301) (0.007)

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

Year FE -0.037 0.009 0.028 -0.016 0.091 -0.027 -0.206 0.002 (0.032) (0.024) (0.038) (0.016) (0.079) (0.051) (0.282) (0.006)

Industry-Year FE 0.005 0.006 -0.011 -0.000 0.003 0.009 -0.032 -0.002 (0.030) (0.024) (0.033) (0.016) (0.063) (0.049) (0.268) (0.006)

Panel C: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

Year FE 0.004 0.043 -0.046 -0.001 -0.186 0.125 0.529 -0.009 (0.062) (0.048) (0.073) (0.028) (0.139) (0.111) (0.594) (0.014)

Industry-Year FE -0.025 0.013 0.012 0.004 -0.225 0.067 0.288 -0.006 (0.067) (0.059) (0.083) (0.026) (0.145) (0.109) (0.554) (0.016)

Control Mean: Stock Cs 0.293 0.296 0.411 0.059 0.463 -4.457 4.865 0.095 N, Stock Cs 226 226 226 229 131 229 229 229 N, Firm-Years Stock Cs 2,947 2,947 2,947 3,179 694 3,179 3,179 3,179

Control Mean: LLCs 0.493 0.301 0.205 0.148 0.345 -4.330 5.522 0.105 N, LLCs 11,865 11,865 11,865 12,639 3,049 12,639 12,639 12,639 N, Firm-Years LLCs 124,016 124,016 124,016 146,289 12,316 146,289 146,289 146,289

Note: The table reports the effect of shared governance on employer-reported education measures in the IAB data (namely (i) low-skilled workers with no vocational training, (ii) medium-skilled workers with a finished school degree and a vocational qualification, and (iii) high-skilled workers with a university degree), outsourcing (the share of workers in outsourceable low-skilled occupations (i.e. food, security, cleaning and logistics, following Goldschmidt and Schmieder, 2017), and the BvD-based value-added/revenue ratio as an inverse measure of outsourcing), and tenure and annual separation rates. Panel A reports the effect of shared governance, γDiff, in simple difference specifications (1) comparing stock corporations incorporated in a two-year windowˆ before vs. after the August 10, 1994 cutoff date. Panel B reports difference-in-differences results, γDiD in Equation (2), additionally drawing on LLCs (a legal form unaffected by the 1994 reform) as a controlˆ group. Panel C reports estimates γRD from the RD specifications in Equation (3). We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixedˆ effects. All outcomes are winsorized at the 1% level by year. The control means refer to observations of firms incorporated on or after August 10, 1994. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

62 Table A.11: Heterogeneity of Shared Governance Effects on Wages

Outcome Control Means Mean Log Wage AKM Firm Fixed Effect Cut Below Median Above Median Below Median Above Median Below Median Above Median Panel A: Difference Design (Stock Corporations)

CBA Coverage 0.425 0.796 -0.041 (0.056) 0.031 (0.063) 0.003 (0.022) 0.004 (0.025 ) Binding CBA Coverage 0.108 0.254 -0.019 (0.057) -0.020 (0.058) 0.012 (0.020) -0.011 (0.024 ) AKM Pay Premia SD 0.135 0.161 0.011 (0.053) -0.069 (0.064) 0.005 (0.018) -0.015 (0.029 ) Industry AKM 0.059 0.150 -0.079 (0.058) 0.005 (0.055) -0.024 (0.023) 0.010 (0.020 ) Works Council 0.572 0.835 -0.095 (0.059) 0.097 (0.060) -0.017 (0.024) 0.028 (0.023 ) Log Value Added per Worker 10.916 11.365 -0.017 (0.063) -0.027 (0.056) -0.002 (0.025) 0.004 (0.020 ) Tenure 3.014 6.562 -0.051 (0.047) 0.005 (0.045) 0.010 (0.019) -0.010 (0.020 )

Panel B: Difference-in-Differences Design (Stock Corporations + LLC Control Group)

CBA Coverage 0.425 0.796 -0.050 (0.046) 0.088 (0.065) -0.002 (0.018) 0.028 (0.027 ) Binding CBA Coverage 0.108 0.254 -0.009 (0.048) 0.018 (0.061) 0.004 (0.019) 0.017 (0.024 ) AKM Pay Premia SD 0.135 0.161 0.037 (0.046) -0.052 (0.064) 0.017 (0.018) -0.003 (0.028 ) Industry AKM 0.059 0.150 -0.114 (0.068) 0.045 (0.044) -0.041 (0.028) 0.028 (0.017 ) Works Council 0.572 0.835 -0.099 (0.048) 0.116 (0.057) -0.018 (0.019) 0.040 (0.023 ) 63 Log Value Added per Worker 10.916 11.365 -0.041 (0.072) 0.005 (0.043) -0.015 (0.032) 0.015 (0.017 ) Tenure 3.014 6.562 -0.029 (0.043) 0.053 (0.040) 0.010 (0.016) 0.008 (0.020 )

Panel C: Regression Discontinuity Design (Stock Corporations)

CBA Coverage 0.425 0.796 0.099 (0.128) 0.058 (0.135) 0.045 (0.041) -0.020 (0.057 ) Binding CBA Coverage 0.108 0.254 0.117 (0.141) 0.030 (0.110) 0.031 (0.048) -0.009 (0.047 ) AKM Pay Premia SD 0.135 0.161 0.181 (0.127) -0.176 (0.136) 0.066 (0.043) -0.095 (0.057 ) Industry AKM 0.059 0.150 -0.160 (0.128) 0.187 (0.121) -0.083 (0.053) 0.055 (0.041 ) Works Council 0.572 0.835 0.151 (0.136) 0.020 (0.120) 0.040 (0.046) -0.010 (0.050 ) Log Value Added per Worker 10.916 11.365 -0.044 (0.133) 0.152 (0.126) -0.039 (0.055) 0.049 (0.039 ) Tenure 3.014 6.562 0.080 (0.103) 0.028 (0.101) 0.033 (0.040) -0.028 (0.043 )

Note: The table reports heterogeneity in the effect of shared governance on wage measures. The rows are labeled by the heterogeneity categories, which are calculated as averages at the three-digit industry (NACE) level (with CBA coverage and works council prevalence calculated based on the IAB Establishment Panel). For example, CBA coverage splits firms into two categories depending on whether their industry has above or below-median collective bargaining coverage. The reported coefficients correspond to the effect of shared governance in firms above or below the median for the relevant heterogeneity category. The underlying regression model (with interacted base effects) is a simple difference specification as in Equation (1) in Panel A, a difference-in-difference specification as in Equation (2) in Panel B, and an RD specification as in Equation (3) in Panel C. Across panels, the means of the sorting (heterogeneity) variables are calculated among stock corporations in a two-year bandwidth around the reform.. All specifications include 2-digit NACE industry-year effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. Stars denote statistical significance: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. We plot our main graphical results in Figure VI. B Additional Figures

64 Figure A.1: Frequency of Incorporation and Selection: MUP Data

(a) Frequency of Incorporation

20

18

16

14

12

10

8

6

4 Number of Stock Corporations 2

0 Disc. Estimate: 0.261 (SE 0.439) -24 -12 0 12 24 Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Months)

(b) Balance of Industry Composition

.1

.05

0

-.05

-.1 MUP DiD

Mining Wholesale Real Estate Construction Manufacturing Transportation Other Services Communications Finance/Insurance Arts/Entertainment Professional/Scientific Administration/Support

Note: This figure reports results analogous to Figure III Panel (a) and Appendix Figure A.2 based on data from the Mannheim Enterprise Panel (MUP), which is available from 1991 onward. This figure does not contain the MUP version of Figure III Panel (b) or all specifications of Appendix Figure A.2 due to data access restrictions. See figure notes for Figure III and Appendix Figure A.2 for additional information. For our analysis with the Mannheim Enterprise Panel, we drop observations of firms with the following NACE codes: 3500-3899 (utilities), 4900-4929 (railroads), 8400-8499 (public administration), 9400-9499 (membership organizations), 9700-9899 (household activities), and 9900-9999 (extraterritorial entities).

65 Figure A.2: Balance of Industry Composition

.4

.2

0

-.2

-.4

Mining Wholesale Real Estate Construction Manufacturing Transportation Other Services Communications Finance/Insurance Arts/Entertainment Professional/Scientific Administration/Support

Difference DiD RD

Note: The analysis presented in the figure tests for industry selection. This figure plots the simple difference (γDiff), difference-in-differences ˆ (γDiD) and regression discontinuity (γRD) coefficients with 95% confidence intervals corresponding to, respectively, Equations (1), (2), and (3)ˆ with an indicator for industry typeˆ (NACE Rev. 2 Classification 1) as the outcome variable. Some industries are excluded due to insufficient observations among stock corporations.F-tests of joint significance show no statistically significant compositional changes in any of the three specifications with p-values of p  0.384, p  0.396 and p  0.828, respectively. Due to insufficient observations, some industries are dropped in the RD design (denoted by a gray ). Appendix Table A.2 reports the corresponding regression results in detail. This figure is based on the Orbis-ADIAB data; we plot another× version of this figure in Appendix Figure A.1 using the Mannheim Enterprise Panel (MUP) data.

66 Figure A.3: Firm Survival and Bankruptcy by Incorporation Date and Corporation Type

(a) Survival Probability by Group

1

.8

.6

.4

Share of Cohort Surviving .2 Old Stock Corporations (Shared Governance) Young Stock Corporations (No Shared Goverance) Old LLCs Young LLCs 0 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Years Since Incorporation

(b) Difference-in-Differences Estimates on Cumulative Exit and Bankruptcy

.2

.1

0

-.1 Cumulative Effect (DiD Estimate)

Any Exit Bankruptcy -.2 1 5 10 15 20 Years After Incorporation

Note: The figure is based on the Mannheim Enterprise Panel. Panel (a) replicates Figure III Panel (c) in showing the survival probability for firms incorporated within a two-year window of August 10, 1994. separately for firms incorporated before or after the cutoff date and for stock corporations and LLCs. Unlike Figure III Panel (c), this panel plots survival rates conditional on the firm being five years and older, to highlight the elimination of visible differences starting then. Panel (b) shows difference-in-differences point estimates and 95% confidence intervals for cumulative bankruptcy probabilities and for cumulative firm exit probabilities at various years after incorporation, showing that differences are small and statistically insignificant.

67 Figure A.4: Robustness of RD Estimates of Effects on Mean Log Wage and AKM Pay Premia: Varying the Bandwidth, and Donut Holes

(b) Mean Log Wage: Donut Hole Estimate, (a) Mean Log Wage: Bandwidth Excluding Months Around Reform Date

.4 .4

.2 .2

0 0

-.2 -.2

-.4 RD: 0.062 (SE 0.091) -.4

-.6 -.6 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 0 5 10 15 20 25 Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994) Months excluded around August 10, 1994

(d) AKM Pay Premia: Donut Hole Estimate, (c) AKM Pay Premia: Bandwidth Excluding Months Around Reform Date

.3 .3

.2 .2

.1 .1

0 0

-.1 -.1 RD: 0.010 (SE 0.034) -.2 -.2

-.3 -.3 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 0 5 10 15 20 25 Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994) Months excluded around August 10, 1994

Note: The figure displays the effects of shared governance on firm-level mean worker-level log wages and AKM firm effects, using the regression discontinuity specification. Panels (a) and (c) plot the coefficients varying the bandwidths for, respectively, mean worker-level log wages and AKM firm effects with industry-year fixed effects and standard errors clustered at the firm level. Panel (b) and (d) reports estimates for a donut hole specification with a two-year bandwidth, industry-year fixed effects, and standard errors clustered at the firm level. Here we drop observations in a radius, indicated on the x-axis, around the reform cutoff and extend the overall two-year bandwidth correspondingly. We report the corresponding main estimates, denoted in Panels (a) and (c) by the highlighted blue square and blue 95% confidence interval, in Table I Columns (1) and (5). The underlying raw data is depicted in Panel (b) of Figure IV (mean log wage) and Figure V (AKM pay premia).

68 Figure A.5: Additional RD Specifications: Effects on the Wage Distribution

.5 RD Difference (From Main Text) DiD (From Main Text)

.4

.3

.2

.1

0

-.1

-.2 p10 p20 p30 p40 p50 p60 p70 p80 p90 Within-Firm Wage Percentile

Note: The figure displays the effect of shared governance on the within-firm wage distribution using the regression discontinuity specification. Specifically we study as outcome variables the deciles of the within-firm log wage distribution in a given year. We use 2-digit NACE designations to create industry-year fixed effects. The vertical lines denote 95% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at the firm level. Appendix Table A.3 reports the full regression results.

69 Figure A.6: Effects on Labor Productivity and Capital Intensity

(a) Log Value Added per Worker (b) Log Value Added per worker , DiD

12.5 2.5

Old Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) Young Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) 2 12 1.5

11.5 1 DiD: 0.055 (SE 0.113) .5 11 0

10.5 Old LLCs Young LLCs -.5 -20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12 16 20 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Quarters) Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

(c) Log Fixed Assets (d) Log Fixed Asset, DiD

17 4.5

Old Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) Young Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) 16 3.5

15 2.5 DiD: 0.514 (SE 0.317)

14 1.5

13 .5

12 Old LLCs Young LLCs -.5

-20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12 16 20 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Quarters) Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

(e) Log Fixed Assets per Worker (f) Log Fixed Assets per Worker, DiD

13 Old Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) Young Stock Corps (Shared Gov.) 2.5

2 DiD: 0.492 (SE 0.250) 12 1.5

11 1

.5 10 0

9 Old LLCs Young LLCs -.5

-20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12 16 20 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Incorporation Date Relative To August 10, 1994 (Quarters) Bandwidth (Months around August 10, 1994)

Note: The figure displays the effects of shared governance on firm-level labor productivity and capital. The left column presents binned scatter plots by quarter of incorporation date around the reform cutoff with a five-year bandwidth. It also plots results of a local linear regression with a uniform kernel and a two-year bandwidth, using day-specific incorporation date as the running variable. The right column plots coefficients and 95% confidence intervals (with SEs clustered at the firm level) from difference-in-differences specifications with industry-year effects with varying bandwidths, reported on the x-axis. We report the corresponding main estimates, denoted by the highlighted blue square and blue 95% confidence intervals in Panels (b), (d) and (f), in Table II Columns (1), (7), and (9). We report our main graphical results in Figure VII. 70 Figure A.7: Pooled Rent Sharing: Firms’ Pay Premia (AKM Firm Fixed Effects) and Value Added per Worker

.2

.1

0

-.1

Residualized Firm Pay Premia Slope: 0.084 (SE 0.004) -.2 -2 -1 0 1 2 Residualized Firm-Level Mean of Log Value Added per Worker

Note: This figure presents a binned scatter plots of firm’s average pay premia (AKM firm fixed effects) plotted against average log value added per worker, in the 2006-14 sample of the Orbis-ADIAB data. The AKM firm fixed effects are estimated in a five-year rolling window and then averaged by firm. Both variables are residualized by industry (2-digit NACE) fixed effects. The figure also includes the estimated linear regression line, the slope of which we report in the bottom right along with standard errors. The sample consists of all firm-year observations in our analysis sample (LLCs and stock corporations) incorporated in a two-year bandwidth around the reform.

71 Figure A.8: Additional Results for Heterogeneity Analysis: Wage Effect of Shared Governance in Subsamples of Firms

(a) Mean Log Wages

Mean of Sorting Variable:

Below: 0.425 CBA Coverage Above: 0.796

Binding 0.108 CBA Coverage 0.254

AKM Pay 0.135 Premia SD 0.161

Industry AKM 0.059 0.150 Below Median: Works Council 0.572 Diff 0.835 DiD RD Log Value Added 10.916 per Worker 11.365 Above Median: Diff Tenure 3.014 DiD 6.562 RD

-.5 -.3 -.1 .1 .3 .5

(b) AKM Pay Premia

Mean of Sorting Variable:

Below: 0.425 CBA Coverage Above: 0.796

Binding 0.108 CBA Coverage 0.254

AKM Pay 0.135 Premia SD 0.161

Industry AKM 0.059 0.150 Below Median: Works Council 0.572 Diff (From Main Text) 0.835 DiD (From Main Text) RD Log Value Added 10.916 per Worker 11.365 Above Median: Diff (From Main Text) Tenure 3.014 DiD (From Main Text) 6.562 RD

-.5 -.3 -.1 .1 .3 .5

Note: The figure reports heterogeneity in the effect of shared governance on mean log wages (Panel (a)) and the AKM firm fixed effects (Panel (b)), highlighting the regression discontinuity specification in the latter as it was not reported in Figure IX. We split the firm sample at the median according the 3-digit NACE industry average of the variables reported on the left-hand side. Solid (hollow) symbols denote the estimate of the sample with values below (above) the median. We also print the means of the sorting (heterogeneity) variables on the left column, as shown in the figure. The means are calculated for stock corporations in a two-year bandwidth around the reform.

72 C Theoretical Appendix: Hold-Up, Shared Governance, and Investment

We now show that a simple but plausible extension that models worker participation as occurring also in bargaining over inputs, besides bargaining over wages, can overturn the underinvestment result of (Grout, 1984). Specifically, we separate the decisions in a model of sequential bargaining: rather than a unilateral firm decision, in stage 1 the firm and the workers now jointly determine the capital stock by bargaining. As in (Manning, 1987), on whom our application to shared governance draws, we permit the wage and investment bargaining to feature different worker bargaining power parameters, with ι applying to bargaining over investment:

W F max{ι log S (w∗, L¯ , K) + (1 − ι) log S (w∗, L¯ , K)}, (A.1) K 1 1 where stage-1 investment choices are again made anticipating wage rule (5), the structure of which remains unchanged in stage 2. The worker and firm surpluses entering first-stage W  ¯ − ¯ F  ( ¯) − ¯ − bargaining are S1 Lw∗ bL, while S1 F K, L w∗L cK. The previous case of the firm unilaterally setting capital is nested if ι  0, when underinvestment emerged whenever φ > 0 and c0 < c. In that case, modeling shared governance as an increase in φ distorted investment further downward. Indeed, the specific institution of codetermination gives workers a vote alongside capitalists in a series of corporate decisions, including those over strategically important investment decisions, and in the appointment and holding accountable of managers. Shared governance may therefore alternatively be viewed as an increase in ι. To foreshadow why this channel will lead to higher rather than lower investment, note that here workers care about the capital choice K solely because of its effect on wages. First consider the extreme case where workers have full bargaining power over inputs, i.e. ι  1. The optimization problem (A.1) now { W ( ¯ )} maximizes worker surplus, maxK log S1 w∗, L, K , with the following first order condition:

∂w L¯ ∗  0 (A.2) ∂K ⇔ φFK(K∗, L¯) − φc0  0 (A.3)

⇔ FK(K∗, L¯)  c0 ≤ c. (A.4)

Workers’ capital choice off the benefit – its marginal product – of which share φ goes to the worker, with the marginal cost – resale value c0 – because each unit of capital boosts the

firm’s outside option in form of c0K in wage setting. Workers ignore direct capital costs c. The two extreme cases of ι  0 and ι  1 make clear that increasing worker bargaining power in

73 capital choice ι overturns the Grout (1984) underinvestment result (FK > c) to overinvestment if

c0 < c (then FK  c0 < c).

The general bargained capital level K∗ under ι ∈ [0, 1] is given by: " # (ι − φ)(F(K∗, L¯) − bL¯ − c0K∗) + ι(c0 − c)K∗ F (K , L¯)  c − (c − c ) × . (A.5) K ∗ 0 ( − )( ( ¯) − ¯ − ) + ( − ) 1 φ F K∗, L bL c0K∗ ι c0 c K∗

Here, K∗ depends on ι as follows:

dK −(c − c )(F − bL¯ − c K + (c − F )K ) ∗  0 0 ∗ 0 K ∗ (A.6) ( − )[ ( − ¯ − ) + ( − )2] − ( − )[ − + ] dι 1 φ FKK F bL c0K∗ FK c0 c c0 FK c0 ιFKK K∗

This expression (which we formally evaluate in Appendix C.1) is positive, so K∗ is increasing

in ι, as long as φ > 0 and c0 < c.43 If given a chance, workers will bargain to raise capital investment, as they will benefit in stage-2 wage bargaining from the higher production. Hence, increasing worker bargaining power in operational decisions such as capital choices may mitigate hold-up and lead to efficient investment, and even overinvestment.

In sum, this extended model of labor-capital interaction serves as a proof of concept that a given institution boosting workers’ control rights need not crowd out, and can in fact crowd in, investment.

C.1 Comparative Statics of Investment to Bargaining Power Parameters φ and ι

We here formally derive the of the comparative static of capital stock choice K∗ to worker bargaining power parameters φ (in wage setting) and ι (in input choice).

Capital Choice In period 1, the objective function in the bargaining is:

max{ι log S1W (φ, L¯ , K) + (1 − ι) log S1F(φ, L¯ , K)}, (A.7) K

where the surpluses of the parties depend on period 2 Nash bargaining: 1W 2 1F 2 S (φ, L¯ , K)  φS (K, L¯) and S (φ, L¯ , K)  (1 − φ)S (K, L¯) + (c0 − c)K, with 2 S (K, L¯)  F(K, L¯) − bL¯ − c0K. 44

43If φ  0 (i.e the workforce has no power in setting the wage), then w∗  b does not depend on K. For ι  1, any K∗ is a solution, while for ι < 1, efficiency emerges (FK  c). 2W 2 2F 44Period 2 Nash bargaining allocates surplus so that S w∗, L¯ , K  φS K, L¯ and S w∗, L¯ , K  1 φ S2 K, L¯ . Period 1 and period 2 surpluses are related as follows:( S1W ) S2W and( S)1F  S2F +( c c K). ( − ) ( ) ( 0 − )

74 The optimality condition for K is:

S1W S1F ι K + (1 − ι) K  0. (A.8) S1W S1F

Where the subscript K indicates the partial derivative of the function with respect to K. The second-order condition, a we will use for the comparative statics below and the value of which we define as B, is: ! ! S1W S1W − S1W S1W S1F S1F − S1FS1F ι KK K K + (1 − ι) KK K K < 0. (A.9) S1W S1W S1FS1F | {z } B ≡

The Effect of Worker Bargaining Power in Wage-Setting, φ , on K ∗ To characterize the effect of K∗ on φ totally differentiate first-order condition (A.8) with respect to K∗ and φ in the

neighborhood of K∗:

 S1W S1W − S1W S1W S1F S1F − S1W S1F   Kφ K φ Kφ K φ  B × dK∗ + ι © ª + (1 − ι) © ª dφ  0. (A.10)  ­ S1W S1W ® ­ S1FS1F ®    « ¬ « ¬ | {z } A ≡

And therefore, dK A ∗  . (A.11) dφ −B

− dK∗ By SOC (A.9), B > 0. We will now evaluate A and hence the sign of dφ . Note that

1W 2 1F 2 S  φS S  (1 − φ)S + (c0 − c)K (A.12) 1W  2 1F  − 2 Sφ S Sφ S (A.13) 1W  2 1F  ( − ) 2 + ( − ) SK φSK SK 1 φ SK c0 c (A.14) 1W  1W  2 1W  1F  − 2 SKφ SφK SK SKφ SφK SK. (A.15)

Therefore

1W 1W − 1W 1W  2 2 − 2 2  SKφ S SK Sφ SK φS φSKS 0 (A.16)

S1F S1W K  − ι K (the first parenthesis in A = 0). Recall also that from FOC (A.8), S1F 1 ι S1W . Note also that −

75 1F  − 1W 1F  − 1W Sφ Sφ and SKφ SKφ . Therefore, A becomes:

 S1W S1W − S1W S1W S1F S1F − S1FS1F   Kφ K φ Kφ K φ  A  ι © ª + (1 − ι) © ª (A.17)  ­ S1W S1W ® ­ S1FS1F ®    « ¬ « ¬ 1F 1F 1F SKφ S Sφ  (1 − ι) © − K ª (A.18) ­ S1F S1F S1F ® « ¬ 1W 1W 1W S 1W S S Kφ ι S φ  −(1 − ι) © + K ª (A.19) S1F ­S1W 1 − ι S1W S1W ® « ! ¬ S1W 1 S2  −(1 − ι) K (A.20) S1F 1 − ι S1W " # S2 (1 − ι)φS2  − K (A.21) ( − ) 2 + ( − ) ( − ) 2 1 φ S c0 c K 1 ι φS < 0, (A.22)

provided that ι < 1, φ > 0, S2 > 0. Since A < 0 and −B > 0, we have now shown that

dK ∗ < 0 (A.23) dφ

for any level of ι < 1, provided that φ > 0 and S2 > 0.

The Effect of Worker Bargaining Power in Investment, ι, on K∗ We totally differentiate

FOC (A.8) with respect to K∗ and ι:

" 1W 1F # SK SK B × dK∗ + − dι  0. (A.24) S1W S1F | {z } C ≡ so,

dK C ∗  . (A.25) dι −B

76 Again by SOC (A.9), −B > 0. We will now evaluate the sign of C, which determines the sign S1F S1W dK∗ K  − ι K of dι . Recall that from FOC (A.8), S1F 1 ι S1W . Therefore, C becomes: − " # S1W S1F C  K − K (A.26) S1W S1F

" W W # S1 ι S1  K + K (A.27) S1W 1 − ι S1W W 1 S1  K (A.28) 1 − ι S1W 1 φS2  K (A.29) 1 − ι φS2 > 0. (A.30)

Since C > 0 and −B > 0,

dK ∗ > 0 (A.31) dι for any level of 1 > φ > 0. If φ  0, i.e workers have no power in setting the wage, then w∗ is equal to b and does not depend on K. Therefore, for ι  1 any K is a solution, while for ι < 1  dK∗  we have efficiency (FK c) and K∗ does not depend on ι ( dι 0).

C.2 Endogenous Labor

Here, we relax the assumption of exogenous labor and assume instead that labor L is chosen contemporaneously to K with the same bargaining parameter ι. If labor and capital are

complements (FLK > 0), the effects of changes in φ or ι on labor have the same signs as the respective effects on capital (and opposite for FLK < 0). Importantly, the model can therefore rationalize positive or neutral effects of increases in ι on labor. The stage 1 objective function in Nash bargaining is now

max{ι log S1W (φ, K, L) + (1 − ι) log S1F(φ, K, L)}, (A.32) K,L where stage-2 surplus is anticipated to be Nash bargained as above. Note that L only enters the surplus of the respective parties through aggregate period-2 surplus: 1W 2 1F 2 S (φ, K, L)  φS (K, L) and S (φ, K, L)  (1 − φ)S (K, L) + (c0 − c)K, where 2 S (K, L)  F(K, L) − bL − c0K. Hence, both parties will agree on choosing the optimal level of

77 L regardless of bargaining powers, given by:

S1W S1F  φ (1 − φ) ι L + (1 − ι) L  0 ⇔ S2 ι + (1 − ι) S1W S1F L U V

⇔ 2  SL 0 ⇔ FK  b.(A.33)L∗ does not depend on φ or ι directly but only through K; for any change in

K, L∗ adjusts such that FL(K, L)  b and hence:

dL F ∗  − LK . (A.34) dK FLL

dK∗ dK∗ Moreover, the results (A.23) on dφ < 0 and (A.31) on dι > 0 continue to hold in the case with endogenous L. The formulae (A.11) and (A.25) still hold, with B now being a function of the Hessian of the objective function which we can again sign by appealing to the second order condition.45 As a result, employment effects inherit the qualitative properties of the capital effects in this extended setting as long as FLK > 0. Going forward, we therefore consider the general setting with endogenous labor. Therefore, the results derived for capital effects with fixed labor ∂K  A ∂K  C above correspond to the partial effects ∂φ B and ∂ι B in the model with endogenous − − labor (with the seemingly fixed labor level set to the originally optimal one). However, the total capital effects dK  A and dK  C (while having the same sign as in the fixed-labor dφ B˜ dι B˜ setting) also reflect endogenous− adjustment− in labor (with B˜ defined in Footnote 45).

K The Effect of Worker Bargaining Power on L We further show that the capital-labor ratio will increase with ι as long as the capital-labor complementarity is not too large. These predictions will be qualitatively consistent with our empirical evidence. Related models with an insider/outsider perspective, in which worker representatives might advocate to keep employee numbers low in order to increase the capital-labor ratio and to reap ensuing rents as in Lindbeck and Snower (1989); Johnson (1990), would predict a decline in employment – in contrast to our findings. We now derive the additional comparative statics of profit and the capital labor ratio, and do so in the aforementioned extended model with endogenous labor. Denote the bargained

45 To see this, take the total derivative of the FOCs (A.8) – now with endogenous labor – and (C.2) with respect to L, K and the parameter of interest. Use the latter to replace dL as a function of dK in the former. This yields (A.10) and (A.24), with B being replaced by

  1   ∂2Ω − ∂2Ω ∂2Ω ∂2Ω ∂2Ω B˜  ∂L2 ∂K2 ∂L2 − ∂K∂L ∂L∂K where Ω K, L; φ, ι  ι log S1W φ, K, L + 1 ι log S1F φ, K, L is the objective function of the bargaining. Note that B˜ < (0 by SOC.) ( ) ( − ) ( )

78  K ∈ { } capital-labor ratio by R L . The effect of a parameter ψ φ, ι on R is:

dR 1 dK K dL  − (A.35) dψ L dψ L2 dψ 1  K F  dK  1 + LK , (A.36) L L FLL dψ where the second equality uses (A.34). The capital-labor ratio will move in the same direction d K ( L )  ( dK∗ ) − L as capital, sign dψ sign dψ , if and only if FLK < K FLL , that is if the complementarity between K and L is not too large for the labor response (to the capital increase) to outpace the capital response.

79 D Online Appendix References

Goldschmidt, Deborah and Johannes Schmieder. 2017. “The Rise of Domestic Outsourcing and the Evolution of the German Wage Structure.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (3):1165–1217.

Grout, Paul. 1984. “Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach.” Econometrica 52 (2):449–460.

Johnson, George. 1990. “Work Rules, Featherbedding, and Pareto-Optimal Union-Management Bargaining.” Journal of Labor Economics 8 (1, Part 2):S237–S259.

Lindbeck, Assar and Dennis Snower. 1989. The Insider-Outsider Theory of Employment and Unemployment. MIT Press.

Manning, Alan. 1987. “An Integration of Trade Union Models in a Sequential Bargaining Framework.” The Economic Journal 97 (385):121–139.

80