Artificial Intelligence Heuristic (Informed) Search

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Artificial Intelligence Heuristic (Informed) Search Artificial Intelligence Heuristic (Informed) Search Prof. Dr. habil. Jana Koehler Dr. Sophia Saller, M. Sc. Annika Engel Deep thanks goes to Summer 2020 Prof. Jörg Hoffmann for sharing his course material © JK Agenda . Using Knowledge during Search – evaluation of search states – admissible and consistent (monotone) heuristics . Algorithms 1) Greedy (Best-First) Search 2) A* and IDA* 3) Bidirectional Search . Finding good heuristics 2 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Recommended Reading . AIMA Chapter 3: Solving Problems by Searching – 3.4 Uninformed Search Strategies, the following subchapters: • 3.4.6 Bidirectional search – 3.5 Informed (Heuristic) Search Strategies • 3.5.1 Greedy best-first search • 3.5.2 A* search: Minimizing the total estimated solution cost – 3.6 Heuristic Functions • 3.6.1 The effect of heuristic accuracy on performance • 3.6.2 Generating admissible heuristics from relaxed problems • 3.6.3 Generating admissible heuristics from subproblems: Pattern databases . Optional reading: – R. C. Holte, A. Felner, G. Sharon, N. R. Sturtevant: Bidirectional Search That Is Guaranteed to Meet in the Middle, AAAI-2016 3 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK How to Determine the next Node for Expansion? . Uninformed Search – rigid procedure, no knowledge of the cost from a node to the goal – e.g. FIFO, LIFO queues . Informed Search – "value" of expanding a node (state) used as guidance that steers the search algorithm through the search space – evaluation function f(s) assigns a number to each state 4 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK The Evaluation Function ( ) = ( ) + ( ) C(3) s 4 s1 A(2) g=5 g=2 푔 s2 h*=7 G(0) G(0) C(3) I C(3) s5 G(0) g=7 푔 B(4) s 3 E(0) h*=0 G(0) g=4 F(1) H(2) E(0) 푔 s6 s7 ( ) corresponds to the costs ( ) corresponds to the from the initial state to the + estimated costs from the current current state ℎstate to the goal state a precise value an estimated value 5 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Heuristic Functions and ∗ Let be a problem with state space . A heuristic function, short heuristic, for is a function so that, for every goal state , we have ( )Π= 0. + Θ Θ ℎ ∶ ↦ ℝ0 ∪ ∞ ℎThe perfect heuristic is the function assigning every the cost of a cheapest path from to∗ a goal state, or if no such path exists. ℎ ∈ ∞ 0, if is a goal state . = > 0, otherwise . ℎ =� for dead-end states, from which the goal is unreachable . ∗ is also called the goal distance of ℎ ∞ . The∗ value of depends only on the state , not on the path that we ℎ followed so far to construct the partial solution (and the costs of this path) ℎ 6 © JK Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search Desirable Properties of Heuristic Function ( ) 1) Efficient to compute ( = 0 as extreme case) 2) Informative ( ( ) = ( ) as extreme case) ℎ ∗ 0,ℎ ℎif is a goal state = 3) > 0, otherwise 4) ℎ is admissible� = 5) ℎ for dead-end states 6) is consistent ℎ GOOD heuristics∞ should satisfy a balanced compromise of properties (1) to ℎ(4) at least, better of all 6 Properties (5) ensures effective dead-end recognition and (6) is a prerequisite for algorithms to guarantee minimal-cost (optimal) solutions 7 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Admissiblity of ( ) Let be a problem with state space and let be a heuristic function for . We say that is admissible if, for all , we haveΠ ( ). Θ ℎ Θ ∗ ℎ ∈ The functionℎ ≤ ℎ corresponds to the real cost of the optimal path from node∗ to a goal state. ℎ The function is an optimistic estimation of the costs that actually occur. It underestimates the real costs and provides the search algorithmℎ with a lower bound on the goal distance. 8 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Consistency (Monotonicity) of h(s) Let be a problem with state space , and let be a heuristic function for . We say that is consistent if, for all transitions s in , we have Π Θ ℎ , . ′ Θ ′ ℎ → Θ Theℎ value− ℎ ≤, is the action cost of getting from to with action . We reformulate the inequality from above to: , + ( ). 푠 ℎ ≤ ℎ 푠 ( , ) Triangle inequality: The sum of the lengths of any two sides of a triangle must be greater or equal than the length of the remaining side. ( ) ( )푠 ℎ Applying an action to the state , the heuristic value cannot decrease by more ℎ 푠 than the cost , of . goal state 9 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Consistency Admissibility Let be a problem⟹ with state space and let be a heuristic function for . If is consistent, then is admissible. Π Θ ℎ Θ ℎ ℎ To show: , , ( ) ( ), . This means that we need′ to show that a′ consistent heuristic∗ never overestimatesℎ the− ℎ costs ≤ to the goal.∀ → ⟹ ℎ ≤ ℎ ∀ ∈ Observation: The value of can at most decrease by the action costs. ( ) ( ) ℎ ℎ 0 ( ) , ( , 1) ( ) ℎ 1 , + ( ) 0 (ℎ , 2) ℎ − ℎ 푠 ≤ ( 2) 푔 . ⇔ ℎ ≤ ℎ 푠 ℎ . 10 1 2 3 © JK Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search 0 푔 푔 푔 → ⋯ → Proof: We need to show that for all . For states (dead ends) where ( ) = ∗ , this is trivial as any number is . Now let be the set of non dead ∗-end≤ states with a shortest cheapest path to a goal state of length . ℎ ∞ ≤ ∞ We will prove for all that for all by induction over . ∗ Base case: is a goal state,ℎ so≤ ℎ ( = 0). ∈By the definition of heuristic functions then ( ) = 0 and so ( ) ( ) = 0 as required. 0 ∗ ∈ Inductiveℎ Hypothesis:ℎ For≤ allℎ we have that . ∗ Inductive step: Let . Then ∈ the cheapest pathℎ from≤ ℎ to a goal state has length + 1. Let be the successor state of in this cheapest path, so . We thus know ∈ +푔 that and therefore 1) By푠 the consistency of we have: → 푠 ( , ) 푠2)∈By the Inductive Hypothesis: ′ 3) Since the cheapest pathℎ has the cheapest costs: ℎ ′ −=ℎ ∗ ≤+ ( , ) ℎ∗ ≤ ℎ∗ 푠′ Combining these three statements, we get ℎ ℎ + , + , = ( ) ′ ∗ ∗ QED 11 ≤ ℎ1) ≤ ℎ 2)푠 3) © JK (1) Greedy Best-First Search . Uses only the heuristic part of the evaluation function ( ) = ( ) ℎ . Expands the node first that is estimated as being closest to the goal . Does not consider the current path costs – "counterpart" to uniform-cost search, which uses ( ) = ( ) 12 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK GBFS Algorithm . Frontier ordered by ascending . Duplicates checked at successor generation, against both the frontier and the explored setℎ 13 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK GBFS on the Romania Travel Example h: Aerial Distances to Bucharest 14 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK 15 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Properties of GBFS . Complete – for finite state spaces and with duplicate elimination . Not optimal . Time complexity is ( ) . Space complexity is where is the maximum depth of the search space 16 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK (2) A* (Hart, Nilsson, Raphael 1968) . Greedy search only uses ( ) ℎ . Uniform-Cost search uses ( ) – finds an optimal solution if path costs grow monotonically: () ( ) ≤ 푠 . A* uses ( ) = ( ) + ( ) ℎ . A* combines both using preferably admissible and consistent heuristics . http://theory.stanford.edu/~amitp/GameProgramming/AStarComparison.html gives a good introduction 17 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK A* Algorithm Frontier ordered by ascending + , duplicates handled as in UCS (nodes replaced by duplicates with cheaper costs) 18 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristicℎ Search © JK Properties of A* . A* is complete – if a solution exists, A* will find it provided that 1) every node has a finite number of successor nodes, and 2) each action has positive and finite costs . A* is optimal – first solution found has minimum path cost if is admissible (on trees) or if is consistent (on graphs) • under an admissible heuristics on graphs, A* needsℎ to expand all nodes with ( ) (the costℎ of an optimal solution), called “re-opening” ∗ • For any path, re-opening≤ checks if it is the cheapest to a state and puts explored states back into the frontier if a cheaper path was found 19 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Properties of A* . Time Complexity is ( ) . Space Complexity is ( ), where is the maximum depth of the search space – subexponential growth requires that the error in the heuristic function grows no faster than the logarithm of the actual path cost ( ) log ( ) ∗ ∗ ℎ − ℎ ≤ ℎ 20 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK A* on the Romania Travel Example h: Aerial Distances to Bucharest 21 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Computed f-Values in the Example Frontier: A S,T,Z R,F,T,Z,O F,P,T,Z,C,O P,T,Z,B,C´,O Bucharest is inserted after Pitesti in the frontier! B´,T,Z,C´,O 22 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK f-based Contours in the Search Space . A* fans out from the start node, adding nodes in concentric bands of increasing f-costs – with good heuristics the bands stretch towards the goal state and are more narrowly focused around the optimal path 23 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Proof of Optimality of A* under Consistent Heuristics . The general idea for the proof is to encode the consistent heuristic function as action costs and establish a correspondence to uniform cost search – UCS is optimal for non-negative action costs (Dijkstra´s algorithm) . We then show that the original and the transformed problem have the same optimal solutions and isomorphic search spaces . Finally, we can prove that every optimal solution found by A* on the transformed problem, is also an optimal solution for the original problem 24 Artificial Intelligence: Heuristic Search © JK Step 1: Encoding Heuristic Values as Action Costs Definition: Let be a problem with state space = , , , , , , and let be a consistent heuristic function for . We define the -weighted state space as Π = , , , , , where: Θ • ℎ , ℎ| , ℎ, ℎ ℎ, , , Π , ℎ • ℎ: ′Θis defined by ′ , ′ , , • ℎ ≔=ℎ , + , , ∈ | , , ∈ℎ .
Recommended publications
  • Bounded Rationality Till Grüne-Yanoff* Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden
    Philosophy Compass 2/3 (2007): 534–563, 10.1111/j.1747-9991.2007.00074.x Bounded Rationality Till Grüne-Yanoff* Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden Abstract The notion of bounded rationality has recently gained considerable popularity in the behavioural and social sciences. This article surveys the different usages of the term, in particular the way ‘anomalous’ behavioural phenomena are elicited, how these phenomena are incorporated in model building, and what sort of new theories of behaviour have been developed to account for bounded rationality in choice and in deliberation. It also discusses the normative relevance of bounded rationality, in particular as a justifier of non-standard reasoning and deliberation heuristics. For each of these usages, the overview discusses the central methodological problems. Introduction The behavioural sciences, in particular economics, have for a long time relied on principles of rationality to model human behaviour. Rationality, however, is traditionally construed as a normative concept: it recommends certain actions, or even decrees how one ought to act. It may therefore not surprise that these principles of rationality are not universally obeyed in everyday choices. Observing such rationality-violating choices, increasing numbers of behavioural scientists have concluded that their models and theories stand to gain from tinkering with the underlying rationality principles themselves. This line of research is today commonly known under the name ‘bounded rationality’. In all likelihood, the term ‘bounded rationality’ first appeared in print in Models of Man (Simon 198). It had various terminological precursors, notably Edgeworth’s ‘limited intelligence’ (467) and ‘limited rationality’ (Almond; Simon, ‘Behavioral Model of Rational Choice’).1 Conceptually, Simon (‘Bounded Rationality in Social Science’) even traces the idea of bounded rationality back to Adam Smith.
    [Show full text]
  • A Heuristic Study of the Process of Becoming an Integrative Psychotherapist
    'This Time it's Personal': A Heuristic Study of the Process of Becoming an Integrative Psychotherapist. A thesis submitted to the University of Manchester for the degree of Professional Doctorate in Counselling Psychology in the Faculty of Humanities 2015 Cathal O’Connor 1 2 Contents Abstract 7 Declaration 8 Copyright Statement 9 Dedication and Acknowledgements 11 Chapter 1: Introduction 12 Introduction 12 The person of the researcher: What's past is 12 prologue There is an 'I' in thesis 13 Statement of the problem 15 The structure of my research 16 What is counselling psychology? 17 Integration 18 What is psychotherapy? 20 Conclusion 21 Chapter 2: Literature Review 22 Introduction 22 Researching psychotherapy and integration 22 Personal and professional development in 24 counselling psychology training What is personal development? 25 Therapist training 27 Stages of development 34 Supervision 35 Personal development and personal therapy 37 Training in integrative psychotherapy 41 Developing an integrative theory of practice 46 Journaling for personal and professional 48 development Conclusion 57 Chapter 3: Methodology 59 Introduction 59 3 Philosophical positioning 59 Psychology and counselling psychology 60 Epistemology and the philosophy of science 60 The philosophy of scientific psychology 62 Qualitative research 63 Phenomenology 64 Research design 65 Initial engagement 69 The research question 71 Immersion 73 Incubation 76 Illumination 78 Explication 79 Creative synthesis 80 Data generation: Journaling 80 Data analysis: Thematic analysis
    [Show full text]
  • Behavioral Economics in Context Applications for Development, Inequality & Discrimination, Finance, and Environment
    Behavioral Economics In Context Applications for Development, Inequality & Discrimination, Finance, and Environment By Anastasia C. Wilson An ECI Teaching Module on Social and Environmental Issues in Economics Global Development Policy Center Boston University 53 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02155 bu.edu/gdp Economics in Context Initiative, Global Development Policy Center, Boston University, 2020. Permission is hereby granted for instructors to copy this module for instructional purposes. Suggested citation: Wilson, Anastasia C. (2020) “Behavioral Economics In Context: Applications for Development, Inequality & Discrimination, Finance, and Environment.” An ECI Teaching Module on Social and Economic Issues, Economics in Context Initiative, Global Development Policy Center, Boston University, 2020. Students may also download the module directly from: http://www.bu.edu/eci/education-materials/teaching-modules/ Comments and feedback from course use are welcomed: Economics in Context Initiative Global Development Policy Center Boston University 53 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02215 http://www.bu.edu/eci/ Email: [email protected] NOTE – terms denoted in bold face are defined in the KEY TERMS AND CONCEPTS section at the end of the module. BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................ 4 1.1 The History and Development of Behavioral Economics .......................................................... 5 1.2 Behavioral Economics Toolkit:
    [Show full text]
  • The Problems with Problem Solving: Reflections on the Rise, Current Status, and Possible Future of a Cognitive Research Paradigm1
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Purdue E-Pubs The Problems with Problem Solving: Reflections on the Rise, Current Status, and Possible Future of a Cognitive Research Paradigm1 Stellan Ohlssoni Abstract The research paradigm invented by Allen Newell and Herbert A. Simon in the late 1950s dominated the study of problem solving for more than three decades. But in the early 1990s, problem solving ceased to drive research on complex cognition. As part of this decline, Newell and Simon’s most innovative research practices – especially their method for inducing subjects’ strategies from verbal protocols - were abandoned. In this essay, I summarize Newell and Simon’s theoretical and methodological innovations and explain why their strategy identification method did not become a standard research tool. I argue that the method lacked a systematic way to aggregate data, and that Newell and Simon’s search for general problem solving strategies failed. Paradoxically, the theoretical vision that led them to search elsewhere for general principles led researchers away from stud- ’ ies of complex problem solving. Newell and Simon’s main enduring contribution is the theory that people solve problems via heuristic search through a problem space. This theory remains the centerpiece of our understanding of how people solve unfamiliar problems, but it is seriously incomplete. In the early 1970s, Newell and Simon suggested that the field should focus on the question where problem spaces and search strategies come from. I propose a breakdown of this overarching question into five specific research questions. Principled answers to those questions would expand the theory of heuristic search into a more complete theory of human problem solving.
    [Show full text]
  • Heuristics & Biases Simplified
    University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Master of Behavioral and Decision Sciences Capstones Behavioral and Decision Sciences Program 8-9-2019 Heuristics & Biases Simplified: Easy ot Understand One-Pagers that Use Plain Language & Examples to Simplify Human Judgement and Decision-Making Concepts Brittany Gullone University of Pennsylvania Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/mbds Part of the Social and Behavioral Sciences Commons Gullone, Brittany, "Heuristics & Biases Simplified: Easy to Understand One-Pagers that Use Plain Language & Examples to Simplify Human Judgement and Decision-Making Concepts" (2019). Master of Behavioral and Decision Sciences Capstones. 7. https://repository.upenn.edu/mbds/7 The final capstone research project for the Master of Behavioral and Decision Sciences is an independent study experience. The paper is expected to: • Present a position that is unique, original and directly applies to the student's experience; • Use primary sources or apply to a primary organization/agency; • Conform to the style and format of excellent academic writing; • Analyze empirical research data that is collected by the student or that has already been collected; and • Allow the student to demonstrate the competencies gained in the master’s program. This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/mbds/7 For more information, please contact [email protected]. Heuristics & Biases Simplified: Easy ot Understand One-Pagers that Use Plain Language & Examples to Simplify Human Judgement and Decision-Making Concepts Abstract Behavioral Science is a new and quickly growing field of study that has found ways of capturing readers’ attention across a variety of industries. The popularity of this field has led to a wealth of terms, concepts, and materials that describe human behavior and decision making.
    [Show full text]
  • Revisiting Herbert Simon's “Science of Design” DJ Huppatz
    Revisiting Herbert Simon’s “Science of Design” DJ Huppatz Herbert A. Simon’s The Sciences of the Artificial has long been con- sidered a seminal text for design theorists and researchers anxious to establish both a scientific status for design and the most inclusive possible definition for a “designer,” embodied in Simon’s oft-cited “[e]veryone designs who devises courses of action aimed at chang- ing existing situations into preferred ones.”1 Similar to the earlier Design Methods movement, which defines design as a problem solving, process-oriented activity (rather than primarily concerned 1 Herbert A. Simon, The Sciences of the with the production of physical artifacts), Simon’s “science of Artificial, 3rd ed. (Cambridge, MA: MIT design” was part of his broader project of unifying the social Press, 1996): 111. Design research sciences with problem solving as the glue. This article revisits review articles typically start with Simon’s text as foundational. See, for Simon’s ideas about design both to place them in context and to example, Nigel Cross, “Editorial: Forty question their ongoing legacy for design researchers. Much contem- Years of Design Research,” Design porary design research, in its pursuit of academic respectability, Studies 28, no. 1 (January 2007): 1–4; remains aligned to Simon’s broader project, particularly in its and Nigan Bayazit, “Investigating definition of design as “scientific” problem solving. However, the Design: A Review of Forty Years of Design Research,” Design Issues 20, repression of judgment, intuition, experience, and social interaction no. 1 (Winter 2004): 16–29. in Simon’s “logic of design” has had, and continues to have, pro- 2 See Hunter Crowther-Heyck, Herbert A.
    [Show full text]
  • Incremental Heuristic Search in AI
    AI Magazine Volume 25 Number 2 (2004) (© AAAI) Articles Incremental Heuristic Search in AI Sven Koenig, Maxim Likhachev, Yaxin Liu, and David Furcy ■ Incremental search reuses information from previ- changes of their models of the world, for ex- ous searches to find solutions to a series of similar ample, because the actual situation turns out search problems potentially faster than is possible to be slightly different from the one initially by solving each search problem from scratch. This assumed or because the situation changes over is important because many AI systems have to adapt their plans continuously to changes in (their time. In these cases, the original plan might no knowledge of) the world. In this article, we give an longer apply or might no longer be good, and overview of incremental search, focusing on LIFE- one thus needs to replan for the new situation LONG PLANNING A*, and outline some of its possible (desJardins et al. 1999). Similarly, one needs to applications in AI. solve a series of similar search problems if one wants to perform a series of what-if analyses or if the costs of planning operators, their precon- ditions, or their effects change over time be- cause they are learned or refined. Overview In these situations, most search algorithms t is often important that searches be fast. AI replan from scratch, that is, solve the new has developed several ways of speeding up search problem independently of the old ones. Isearches by trading off the search time and However, this approach can be inefficient in the cost of the resulting path, which includes large domains with frequent changes and, using inadmissible heuristics (Pohl 1973, 1970) thus, limit the responsiveness of AI systems or and search with limited look ahead (Korf 1990; the number of what-if analyses that they can Ishida and Korf 1991; Koenig 2001), which is perform.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of Values As Heuristics on Social Cognition
    DePaul University Via Sapientiae College of Science and Health Theses and Dissertations College of Science and Health Summer 8-20-2017 The Impact of Values as Heuristics on Social Cognition Lauren James [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://via.library.depaul.edu/csh_etd Part of the Psychology Commons Recommended Citation James, Lauren, "The Impact of Values as Heuristics on Social Cognition" (2017). College of Science and Health Theses and Dissertations. 229. https://via.library.depaul.edu/csh_etd/229 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Science and Health at Via Sapientiae. It has been accepted for inclusion in College of Science and Health Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of Via Sapientiae. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Running head: THE IMPACT OF VALUES AS HEURISTICS ON SOCIAL COGNITION 1 The Impact of Values as Heuristics on Social Cognition Lauren James DePaul University THE IMPACT OF VALUES AS HEURISTICS ON SOCIAL COGNITION 2 Abstract Stereotypes, and other forms of heuristics, are used in our everyday lives to assist our brains absorb information. An argument is made here to show that values can act as a form of heuristics and affect implicit attitudes. Drawing on research regarding implicit attitudes, heuristics, and values, we believe that values, such as equality, can act as a heuristic and consequently alter implicit attitudes on race. In this experiment, participants were primed with equality, intuition, or a stereotype inhibition prompt and ran through the affect misattribution procedure (AMP). Contrary to the hypothesized expectation, the results showed that participants in the equality condition rated pictographs preceding African-American faces as less pleasant compared to Caucasian faces.
    [Show full text]
  • The Behavioral Economics Guide 2015
    THE BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS GUIDE 2015 Edited by Alain Samson Introduction by Dan Ariely The Behavioral Economics Guide 2015 Author information: Alain Samson (Editor) Dan Ariely (Introduction) Phil Barden, Gerhard Fehr, Timothy Gohmann, Moritz Jäger, Alain Kamm, Roger Miles, Seamus O'Farrell , Henry Stott (Contributing authors) Cover design and layout adapted from Tilly Patsalis and Elina Halonen. Copyright © by the authors All Rights Reserved Requests for permission to reproduce materials from this work should be sent to [email protected] or directly to contributing authors. Suggested citation: Samson, A. (Ed.)(2015). The Behavioral Economics Guide 2015 (with an introduction by Dan Ariely). Retrieved from http://www.behavioraleconomics.com. Suggested citation for individual sections/authors: [Author(s)] (2015). [Chapter/Section Title]. In A. Samson (Ed.), The Behavioral Economics Guide 2015 (with an introduction by Dan Ariely)(pp. nn-nn). Retrieved from http://www.behavioraleconomics.com. With Contributions By: With Further Support By: Contents I N T R O D U C T I O N BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS: AN EXERCISE IN DESIGN AND HUMILITY (DAN ARIELY) ......................................... V P A R T 1 - E D I T O R I A L BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE: THEORY AND PRACTICE (ALAIN SAMSON) .................................................................... 1 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS IN 2015 ..................................................................................................................... 1 BE BITS AND PIECES ...................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Cognitive Influences on Decision Making
    PBS402A STUDENT READING – 6,797 words / 27 minutes COGNITIVE TENDENCIES and INFLUENCES IN DECISION MAKING Human decision making is complex. It might not always seem to be because people make judgments and decisions all throughout the day, every day. Most of those are automatic or reactive, rather than reflective and that generally works out quite well for us. Consider the ease with which many people drive complicated machines every day. Through training and repetition veteran drivers have internalized and can automatically execute a series of complex analyses, inferences, and quick effective judgments that novices can find mentally all-consuming. Automatic reactions are also seen in bike riders who often pedal along paying more attention to the beauty of their surroundings than on shifting gears or maintaining their balance. Other decisions cannot be made so easily and demand that we slow down to deliberate. Even then, we can make decisions very quickly and efficiently and at times will shortchange the amount of effort truly required to make the optimal decision. Since so many of our judgments, including many good ones, are quick and reactive, not deliberative or reflective, we can fall into overreliance on our subconscious mental processes without even realizing what we are missing. In some circumstances reactive judgments can lead to unnecessary risks and mistaken biases. Anyone reading this has surely experienced regret over a decision. Is it possible that you made a reactive judgment when you should have been deliberative? Or that you were deliberative, but still managed to mislead yourself in some way? For any of us to maximize our personal potential for developing and applying critical thinking skills to real life decision making, we first must understand how human problem-solving and decision-making generally function.
    [Show full text]
  • Heuristic Decision-Making for Human-Aware Navigation in Domestic Environments Alexandra Kirsch
    Heuristic Decision-Making for Human-aware Navigation in Domestic Environments Alexandra Kirsch To cite this version: Alexandra Kirsch. Heuristic Decision-Making for Human-aware Navigation in Domestic Environments. 2nd Global Conference on Artificial Intelligence (GCAI), 2016, Berlin, Germany. hal-01693667 HAL Id: hal-01693667 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01693667 Submitted on 26 Jan 2018 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. This space is reserved for the EPiC Series header, do not use it Heuristic Decision-Making for Human-aware Navigation in Domestic Environments Alexandra Kirsch1 Eberhard Karls Universit¨atT¨ubingenT¨ubingen,Germany [email protected] Abstract Robot navigation in domestic environments is still a challenge. This paper introduces a cognitively inspired decision-making method and an instantiation of it for (local) robot navigation in spatially constrained environments. We compare the method to two existing local planners with respect to efficiency, safety and legibility. 1 Motivation Domestic robots are one of the major application scenarios for future robots. A prerequisite is the basic skill of efficiently and safely navigating in apartments in a manner that is understand- able and predictable for the human inhabitants.
    [Show full text]
  • Heuristics, Concepts, and Cognitive Architecture: Toward Understanding How the Mind Works
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Scholarship@Western Western University Scholarship@Western Electronic Thesis and Dissertation Repository 4-20-2011 12:00 AM Heuristics, Concepts, and Cognitive Architecture: Toward Understanding How The Mind Works Sheldon J. Chow The University of Western Ontario Supervisor Dr. Christopher Viger The University of Western Ontario Graduate Program in Philosophy A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the equirr ements for the degree in Doctor of Philosophy © Sheldon J. Chow 2011 Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.lib.uwo.ca/etd Part of the Philosophy of Mind Commons Recommended Citation Chow, Sheldon J., "Heuristics, Concepts, and Cognitive Architecture: Toward Understanding How The Mind Works" (2011). Electronic Thesis and Dissertation Repository. 128. https://ir.lib.uwo.ca/etd/128 This Dissertation/Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarship@Western. It has been accepted for inclusion in Electronic Thesis and Dissertation Repository by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Western. For more information, please contact [email protected]. HEURISTICS, CONCEPTS, AND COGNITIVE ARCHITECTURE: TOWARD UNDERSTANDING HOW THE MIND WORKS (Spine title: Heuristics, Concepts, and Cognitive Architecture) (Thesis format: Monograph) by Sheldon Chow Graduate Program in Philosophy A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy The School of Graduate and Postdoctoral Studies The University of Western Ontario London, Ontario, Canada c Sheldon Joseph Chow 2011 THE UNIVERSITY OF WESTERN ONTARIO School of Graduate and Postdoctoral Studies CERTIFICATE OF EXAMINATION Examiners: Supervisor: ..................... Dr. John Nicholas ....................
    [Show full text]