<<

The “hidden” side of the “flying-geese” catch-up model: ’s dirigiste institutional setup and a deepening financial morass

Terutomo Ozawa

Professor of Colorado State University Fort Collins, CO. 80523-1771 Phone: (970) 491-6075 Fax: (970) 491-2925 E-mail: [email protected]

July 2001

JEL classification: O14; F02; F21; O53

Keywords: Flying geese model; dirigiste regime; institutions; financial crisis

The author owes to Hugh Patrick of Columbia University for his meticulous, detailed and valuable comments, which have led to many improvements in this article—and is also appreciative of the constructive suggestions and encouragement received from an anonymous . Any remaining errors are solely of the author. This article was drafted while he was a visiting fellow at the East-West Center, Honolulu, Hawaii. An early version was presented at a seminar held at the Center. He is indebted to seminar participants, especially Dieter Ernst, theme leader, for their comments.

1 ABSTRACT

Akamatsu’s original “flying geese (FG)” growth model is often used as a frame of reference for both further conceptual elaborations and empirical explorations. So far have only the positive side and results of FG development been focused on and emphasized in connection with Asia’s phenomenal growth in the pre-crisis period. The Japanese economy, supposedly Asia’s lead goose, is in the eleventh consecutive year of stagnation. How has such a once successful lead goose come to be stricken by financial woes? This paper points out that Japan’s once miraculous FG growth was made possible because it established an effective dirigiste catch-up regime in the early postwar period but that Japan’s present financial predicament is paradoxically a path- dependent outcome of such an FG strategy. The institutional, especially financial, dimension of FG strategy needs to be taken into account to explain why such a strategy once proved effective but later culminated in a deepening financial morass. The FG model should encompass not only the industrial dimension of catch-up but also its institutional, particularly financial, dimension.

2 1. Introduction

Japan is in the eleventh year of stagnation with a prolonged financial malaise. However, Japan’s

phenomenal growth was once admired and even feared as a juggernaut. Japan and the rest of Asia grew in

tandem and basked in clustered regional prosperity, which the (1993) called the “East Asian

miracle.” One popular way of explaining such regionally agglomerated growth was the so-called “flying-geese

(FG)” model of economic development. As pointed out in Kojima (2000), however, the FG model is

incomplete in many respects, especially in its financial dimension.

Ever since the start of the 1990s Japan, supposedly Asia’s lead goose, has been mired in a self-inflicted

financial crisis ever since the bubble of 1987-1990, which is now made all the more dangerous with a “triple

deflation”—simultaneous declines in the prices of goods, property, and equity shares. On March 19, 2001, the

Bank of Japan had to adopt drastic monetary policy to flood the economy with liquidity, an unprecedented

measure designed to prevent “price destruction” in hopes of stimulating demand.

This paper argues (i) that the FG model of catch-up growth, though instrumental in depicting the essential features of latecomers’ (notably Japan’s) industrial upgrading and Asia’s export-led growth, has so far neglected its financial/institutional dimension, and (ii) that the success of Japan’s FG growth derives critically from a special set of institutional arrangements that was created in the early postwar period, and (iii) that

Japan’s present financial imbroglio is paradoxically the very vicissitudinary outcome of such an FG-specific

regime.

2. “Flying-geese” Catch-Up Strategy

As already often cited, the FG model of economic development was originally introduced by Kaname

Akamatsu in the 1930s (inter alia, Akamatsu 1935) and has been theoretically expanded and empirically tested

by his followers, as detailed in Kojima (2000) in this Journal. It is worth re-emphasizing that Akamatsu was

among the very first to recognize the economic significance of what he identified as “the alignment from

advanced nations to backward nations according to their stages of growth”: he argued that “It is impossible to 3 study the of the developing countries in modern times without considering the mutual interactions between these economies and those of the advanced countries” (Akamatsu 1962, p. 1, emphasis added). He did not, however, leave any formalized theoretical model to explain his ideas. The FG analogy came from his empirical findings of the “import->domestic production->export (M-P-E)” of sequential growth in some prewar Japanese industries (such as textiles), which he identified as the basic FG pattern. In essence, what he had in mind was an evolutionary model of sequential catch-up through teacher-learner relations among the nations along the stages of industrial upgrading. It was a model of derived economic development via emulative learning in a latecomer nation.

The catch-up regime Japan set up after the Second World War, however, was rather a nationalistic dirigiste one, since the M-P-E sequence (namely import-substitution-cum-export promotion) was purposely state- assisted—and promoted as a dynamic “infant industry” development strategy. It is true that Japan’s industrial development policy was basically private-sector-assisting and “market-facilitating/creating” (Gregory 1986) or

“market-enhancing” (Aoki, Murdock, and Okuno-Fujiwara 1997). Nevertheless, it involved extensive restrictions on imports, technology transfers and inward foreign direct investment (FDI)--all for the purpose of building up national (not foreign owned) domestic industries. This role of the government was significant, particularly when Japan modernized and rebuilt -intensive heavy and chemical industries, industries that it had previously succeeded developing in the prewar years.

Emulation was the essence of Japan’s FG strategy, capitalizing on its latecomer status in learning from the

West. Akamatsu himself did not directly prescribe such strategy, but Japan’s catch-up policy was formulated and pursued in the spirit of his original insight (Korhonen 1994). Japan’s postwar policies have been well explored (inter alia, Komiya et. al. 1990; Patrick and Rosovsky 1976). Japan’s FG strategy can be re- interpreted as consisting of three critical types of industrial policy by drawing upon Akamatsu’s original triumvirate FG patterns: the M-P-E sequence, the “from crude/simple to complex/refined articles” sequence

(which is industrial upgrading) and the “alignment of nations along the different stages of development”:

(i) a policy for industrial upgrading (IU) from low value-added (low productivity) to

higher value-added (higher productivity) industries, 4 (ii) a policy for import-substitution-cum-export-promotion (IS-EP)--that is, to replace

imports with domestic output and later to promote exports,1 and

(iii) a policy to transfer comparatively disadvantaged industries or industrial

segments onto other countries (mostly nearby developing Asian countries) so as to

retain higher value-added industries at home, a process that may be identified as

recycling (CAR) and adaptive efficiency enhancement (AEE)

at home.

Obviously, the outcomes of these policies were closely and sequentially interrelated. IU policy is the ultimate goal of the FG strategy. And IU can be accomplished by both the IS-EP sequence and the CAR-AEE mechanism. Once a new comparative advantage (commensurable with Japan’s prevailing factor endowments and technological conditions at a given point in time) was created out of formerly disadvantaged industries through the IS-EP policy, Japan continued to foster other future growth industries at home—that is, to move up the ladder of IU. And once export industries (or industrial segments) began to loose competitiveness (i.e., become comparatively disadvantaged), they were transplanted via overseas investment onto other countries, especially the developing Asian countries, where the factor endowments and technological conditions were still suitable for such industries. What is more, those goods transferred and produced overseas are now imported back to home—hence, the IS-EP policy eventually turned to the sequence of “import->domestic production-

>export->overseas production via FDI

->import” by going beyond Akamatsu’s original M-P-E. In the meantime, the resources released from the contracting (now disadvantaged sector) are shifted to newly emerged competitive sectors (i.e., AEE).

What is involved is not static allocative efficiency (i.e., movement along a given product possibility frontier) but dynamic adaptive efficiency (i.e., a biased shifting-out of the product possibility frontier along the

Rybczynski path). This adaptive efficiency was pursued as an infant-industry protection strategy in a market-

1 In this trade-focused development of a specific good or industry, critical technology was acquired in an “unpackaged” manner, that is, mostly under licenses. Later on, the sequence required no initial imports of goods and shifted to that of basic technology acquisition->commercialization at home (i.e., domestic production)->export, as best seen in many of Japanese innovations such as transistor radios, pocket-size calculators, quartz watches, etc. In this later version, government role declined, while adaptive corporate R&D and played a crucial role in innovation. 5 (or industry-) creating fashion so that world-class private enterprises would emerge at home. The pro-business

(or private-sector-fostering) stance of Japan’s dirigisme cannot be overemphasized.

Consequently, the IU process itself has been state-supported but fundamentally driven, and tested, by the

logic and rigor of the market. As a latecomer economy, furthermore, Japanese IU policymakers knew what

types of industry to develop, following in America’s footsteps; Japan was able to secure readily a map (a

clear picture of existing industries in the ) and flight capabilities and instructions (technologies/

information needed to build modern industries), as it were. In the context of the Pax Americana, the United

States was indisputably the first goose, and Japan came to play the role of a second goose (intermediary) in

actively absorbing, and often improving on, modern technologies and later transferring those assimilated

technologies to the rest of Asia via CAR-AEE. It would not be amiss to argue that without America’s policy to

assist East Asia to develop industrially as a bastion against communism—and without Japan’s rapid catch-up

and industrial transformation, the “East Asian Miracle” (World Bank 1993) would not have occurred.

It should be noted that the U.S. itself was once a second goose, along with Continental European nations,

emulating Great Britain where the Industrial Revolution originated. Hence, learning-based catch-up is nothing

new. What makes Japan’s and the rest of East Asia’s experience rather distinct from any previous ones,

however, is that both the leader and follower nations have been more deliberately and more cooperatively

engaged in regional growth—the U.S. in particular has helped Asia develop by providing technology, capital

and markets, while the Asian governments have actively orchestrated export-led outer-focused industrialization.

The Asian pattern has also been more multi-layered with its constituent nations situated at different stages of

development and together forming a complementary hierarchy of interacting economies. The upshot is the

phenomenon of time-compressed and regionally clustered/agglomerated development which can be most

fittingly described as an FG growth formation.

The interface between industrial upgrading at home and CAR-AEE via multinational corporations’ (MNCs ) activities can be best described in terms of the “industrial upgrading” model of FDI (Ozawa 1993; UNCTAD

1995). This IU model is a reformulated FG theory, which emphasizes the role of cross-border direct investment as a facilitator of structural change. It depicts how Japan’s industrial structure has gone through continuous 6 metamorphic changes, a process that can be chronologically divided into four sequential stages of transformation, each of which is dominated by a particular group of comparatively advantaged industries:

Phase I. The “Heckscher-Ohlin” industries: expansion of labor-intensive

in textiles, sundries, and other light industry goods as the leading export sector

(1950 to the mid-1960s).2

Phase II. The “nondifferentiated Smithian” industries: scale-economies-based

modernization of heavy and chemical industries (prewar-built but war-torn

industries) such as steel, petrochemicals, and synthetic fibers (the late 1950s to

the early 1970s).

Phase III. The “differentiated Smithian” industries: assembly-based, subcontracting-

dependent, mass production of consumer durables, such as automobiles and

early-generation electric/electronics goods (TVs, VCRs) (the late 1960s to the

present).

Phase IV. The “Schumpeterian” industries: mechatronics-based, computer-aided flexible

(or lean) manufacturing of highly differentiated multi-variety goods, along with

R&D-driven breakthroughs such as HDTVs and other latest-generation

electronics, new materials, fine chemicals, and more advanced microchips (the

early 1980s onwards).

The transition from one phase to another has certainly not been clear-cut but has overlapped in the above chronological approximations, This stages model is basically a “leading growth sector” model a la Schumpeter

(1934), in which a sequence of growth is punctuated by stages in each of which a certain industrial sector can be identified as the main engine of structural transformation. It is in sharp contrast to the neoclassical view of growth as a smooth incremental accumulation of capital.

2 It should be noted that Japan had already gone through this phase in the late 19th century. In fact, Akamatus originally found FG patterns in the development of Japan’s labor-intensive manufacturing (such as woolen goods, and cotton yarn and cloth) and light machinery industry (spinning and weaving machines and machine tools) in the prewar period (about 1890 to 1940). 7 Japan has so far fully completed the first three phases of industrial metamorphosis and is currently in the

midst of its fourth stage. And interestingly enough, Japan’s overseas investment has exhibited similarly varied

patterns, so far four major distinct patterns in a sequential manner, each reflecting the nature of its

corresponding pattern of industrial activity at home. This stages-specific correspondence between structural

transformation and FDI is schematically illustrated in Figure 1. The revealed phases of FDI can be identified as

(i) the elementary stage of offshore production (or low-wage-seeking investment), (ii) resource-seeking and

house-cleaning investment, (iii) assembly-transplanting investment (inclusive of low-cost-labor-seeking FDI in

parts, components, accessories and low-end products), and (iv) alliance-seeking (strategically networking)

investment in production, marketing and R&D.

As Japan metamorphosed structurally, its comparatively disadvantaged industries have been recycled abroad,

particularly to other Asian economies--hence, the notion of “market or industrial recycling” (Ozawa 1993) or

“comparative advantage recycling” (Berri and Ozawa 1997). The causal mechanisms between structural change

and FDI are also theorized elsewhere (Kojima 2000; Kojima and Ozawa, 1984, 1985; Ozawa 1997, 2000a) and

have recently begun to be empirically examined (inter alia, UNCTAD 1995; Dowling and Cheang 2000). (see

Figure 1.)

Seen in this light, Japan’s industrial rise has been almost flawless. Thanks to the FG strategy of catch-up

(i.e., learn industrial knowledge as much and as quickly as possible through emulation), its technological level and productive capability are now overall on a par with the United States and the EU. It has a huge reservoir of private wealth, and is a formidable competitor in the . There is nothing wrong with its

“fundamentals.” But its economy is in a financial shambles. What went wrong?

3. Japan’s Institutional Matrix for FG Catch-Up

What is missing from the smoothly evolving picture of Japan’s industrial upgrading and growth as depicted in the above FG model is its much neglected institutional dimension, including the financial setup. Each economy has its own set of institutions for economic activities, and its overall economic performance is largely determined (enhanced or retarded) by such an institutional arrangement (North 1990). Such a set can also be 8 called “an institutional matrix that defines the incentive structure of society” against the backdrop of “the belief

system” that “reality” to the institutions (North 1999, p. 9). Japan set up a catch-up regime suitable

for its own prevailing socio-economic conditions in the early postwar period by combining formal rules with

traditional norms and mores.

Japan’s FG catch-up regime was actually effective mostly during the high-growth era of heavy and

chemical industrialization up until the mid-1970s--that is, during the so-called “Golden Age of Capitalism.” It

was based on, and supported by, four key elements: (i) state-augmented bank-based finance (the “main bank

system” and the “stakeholder model” of ), (ii) Keiretsu formation, (iii) the politically

protected “pork-barrel” sector, and (iv) the principle of “job primacy over efficiency” as an implicit social

contract. Each of these elements has already been well explored in many studies, but their interactions and

evolutionary developments in the context of Japan’s FG strategy and present financial quagmire have not been

examined. As will be detailed below, these elements have eventually evolved and converged in a sequential

and path-dependent fashion to cause some critical institutional misalignments (incongruities) which culminated

in the recent and current economic crises as the vicissitudinary outcomes of Japan’s once phenomenal growth under the FG catch-up strategy. The institutional misalignments have been caused by the combined forces of the fast-changing market conditions that Japan’s FG catch-up regime itself created and the rigidification of such a regime a la Olson (1982) which was set up in the early postwar period. All the path-dependent evolutionary developments that have transpired are sketched out in Figure 2.

3.1 . State-augmented bank-based finance and repressed capital markets

As is typically the case with any developing countries, Japan once resorted to and maximized the use of bank-based finance for FG catch-up instead of capital-market-based finance. In this scheme, Japan also used

“central-bank-based finance” (the Bank of Japan created funds internally) rather than “CA-deficit-based finance” (i.e., borrowings from overseas) (Ozawa 1999, 2001). These two, but especially the latter, are the crucial financial aspects of catch-up growth which the FG model has so far not taken into account, but which can shed light on the puzzle of a successful FG process suddenly ending up in a crisis. 9 At the start of postwar growth the stock market initially was a relatively important source of funds for

corporate investment in Japan. Soon, however, bank loans were deliberately promoted for corporate finance as

the essential financial strategy of overall FG development, and equity finance quickly became secondary to

bank loans. In order to control credit expansion, moreover, the government prohibited corporations from

issuing bonds. A bond-issuing privilege was granted only to those financial institutions (mainly, three long-

term credit banks) and utilities that were specifically designed to finance public purpose long-term projects

(Patrick 1994a). Consequently, there was early on no choice on the part of corporations but to borrow from

banks.

Dependence on bank loans thus became the critical mechanism through which a policy of financial

repression was implemented by keeping interest rates low, controlling market (via entry

regulations), and channeling capital to policy-targeted sectors and projects. Under close supervision and control

of the Bank of Japan, which was virtually a policy arm of the Ministry of Finance, the six major keiretsu banks

(Mitsui, Mitsubishi, Sumitomo, Fuji, Sanwa, and DKB) played the role of “main banks” for their respective

groups in investing in heavy and chemical industries the capital injected by the central bank (Aoki 1994; Aoki

and Patrick 1994: Teranishi 1994). In those days, the strength of the main bank system was “its strong information collecting, related monitoring capabilities, and management consulting, ” reducing uncertainty and increasing commercial information, although it was also accompanied by weaknesses such as preferential access to information among participants, secretive and opaque relationship banking and limited public disclosure (Patrick 1994b, p. 359).

Furthermore, bank-created money (both the central bank’s credit and the banking industry’s multiple- expansion of deposits and loans) and did not lead to any serious inflation, since (i) the funds were carefully

invested in supply-increasing industrial projects, (ii) the monetary spigot was turned off as soon as Japan

encountered a balance-of-payments deficit, a deficit caused by such an expansionary monetary policy (Wallich

and Wallich, 1976), (iii) during Japan’s high growth period (from the early 1950 to the early 1970s) domestic

increased dramatically, which were channeled into business investment (instead of consumer credit,

whose facilities were still repressed ) and (iv) the government maintained a balanced budget, hence the absence 10 of open market operations (to monetize national debts) (Patrick 1994b). That central-bank-augmented credit

creation for growth was a classic case of development finance in the early-stage of industrial capitalism as

envisaged and theorized by Schumpeter (1934), who even called the banks as “the headquarters of the capitalist

system.”3

Capital markets were given a supplementary role, and the bond market in particular was even discouraged to develop until the mid-1980s; corporate issues and the development of a secondary market were severely discouraged (Patrick, 1994a). That state-augmented banking system naturally produced a “moral hazard” effect, since high-risk investments were encouraged and the central bank always stood ready to bail out any keiretsu bank at the first sign of financial difficulty; they were strategically too significant to fail. Small and

even inefficient banks were equally protected under the scheme popularly referred to as a “convoy system, “ in

which strong banks were obliged to guard weak ones. The result was that banks’ operations became extremely

asset-expansive as they eagerly extended loans—especially in the context of inter-keiretsu oligopolistic rivalry

as the keiretsu competed vigorously with each other in setting up a similar set of industries, a phenomenon that

came to be called the “one-set” principle (Miyazaki 1980).

Banks—and their keiretsu customers—were thus all the more willing to take risks because they could count

on government help. Moral hazard was actually needed as an inducement to promote large-scale investments in

capital-intensive, scale-driven industries, since these industries imposed high financial risks on the private

sector. Without government support and the keiretsu formation, individual enterprises alone might have been

reluctant to plunge into new large-scale ventures during Japan’s heavy and chemical industrialization (from the

mid-1950s to the early 1970s). A rise in national output capacity (aggregate supply) had to be induced to match

the liquidity (aggregate demand) pumped into the economy by the central-bank-augmented credit creation in

order to prevent inflation (as emphasized by Schumpeter). This type of moral hazard, then, can be identified as

the socially justifiable type (Ozawa 1999), since it induced socially desirable investments in the modern sector,

thereby facilitating a swift industrial transformation. Indeed, this was the financial side story of Japan’s FG

3 It should be noted that Schumpeter recognized the role of securities (equity shares and bonds) in finance but that he considered them basically by-products or derivatives of the very process of development that would be brought about by bank loans in the first place 11 strategy which resulted in unusually rapid growth during the “nondifferentiated Smithian” stage of heavy and chemical industrial modernization.

Ironically, the very success of dirigiste bank-based capitalism, however, came to undermine the privileged position of banks. It was a self-destructive system. Thanks to the low-cost capital made available under such a system, big corporations, mostly in the keiretsu, grew quickly and accumulated internal reserves, along with a sharp rise in debt-equity ratios--for example, from 0.78 in 1961 to 5.67 in 1964 (Arisawa 1967). Both retained earnings and banks loans were needed to finance the development of capital-intensive heavy and chemical industries. The accumulation of internal funds was made possible because corporate investment was quite profitable during the high growth period and, moreover, because companies did not need to pay out much dividends (post- payments) and paid mainly a fixed amount of interest (pre-tax payments) without regards to profitability. Once Japan’s economic growth slowed down after the first oil crisis of 1974, the expansion of internal reserves began to serve as an emancipator from dependence on banks. In other words, the main bank system itself was responsible for making the banks’ clients less and less dependent on loans—hence less susceptible to monitoring and more autonomous in investment decisions (Ozawa 2000b).

Moreover, as Japan entered the subsequent “differentiated Smithian” phase of assembly-based, components- intensive industries, notably automobiles and electronics, leaving behind heavy and chemical industries, there soon emerged new world-class manufacturers. Many of these manufacturers actually did not originate as keiretsu firms which were supposedly best coached by their main banks. These new companies started out as outsiders (non-keiretsu upstarts) and have largely remained as such.

A prime example is Toyota Motor Corporation, now the world’s most efficient car maker, which has had no affiliation either with any zaibatsu or keiretsu ever since its establishment in 1937. In fact, the company has persistently avoided external debts. Its internal reserves became enormous, so much so that Toyota itself came to be known as the “Toyota Bank.” 4

(Ozawa 1999). 4 Honda is another example, which in its infancy had a hard time securing bank loans because of its initial status as an independent upstart. It originated as a bike repair shop in the early postwar period. Only later on, the company became “affiliated” with the Mitsubishi Bank (now Tokyo-Mitsubishi Bank). Likewise, Matsushita Electric Industries quickly accumulated huge internal funds 12 Furthermore, some successful Japanese corporations were soon able to tap the bond market at home and international capital markets for their financing needs at low costs as the bond market was deregulated and as restrictions on borrowings from abroad were lifted with the amendment of the Foreign Exchange Control Law in 1980.5

As a result of ever-increasing internal funds and the opportunities to raise capital abroad, there was thus no reason for them to be subservient to their banks and to be dictated about how to run their own businesses by bank officials. Besides, the main bank system might not have been as beneficial for the affiliated firms as described by its proponents, who emphasize the magic of the system in solving the problems of information asymmetry and transaction costs.6

It was against the background of this rapid structural change in the market that an asset bubble (1987-1990), stemming from, and fed by, speculative investments in real estate and stocks, occurred. Because of the easy monetary policy adopted to combat the so-called “high-yen” recession after the Group-Five (G5) Plaza accord in 1985, the banks became awash in liquidity. Yet, they began to be “departed” by big corporations mainly because of the deregulation of and development of a corporate bond market, as explained above, and found themselves in the search for new, smaller, more risky borrowers, such as small- and medium-sized enterprises, real estate firms, distributors (both wholesalers and retailers), and construction companies. The share of this group of borrowers soon accounted for as much as one third of total bank loans. Real estate firms alone were responsible for one quarter of the total. In addition, the banks channeled loans through non-bank banks (e.g.,

and has ever since been practically free from external debt. It is also often called the “Matsushita Bank.” Sony was also no exception as a non-keiretsu firm.

5 “As a fraction of all securities issued by Japanese companies, overseas issues [reached] nearly 50 percent by 1985” (Kester 1991: 188). As far as bonds are concerned, “within three years of the revision of the Law, the value of bonds issued abroad exceeded the value of bonds issued domestically” (Weinstein and Yafeh 1998: 637). According to Hugh Patrick (his comment given to this author), “Interestingly, not only were most of these bonds underwritten by Japanese financial institutions, they were purchased by Japanese insurance companies and other Japanese institutions. This was because such foreign issue was far cheaper and easier because of persisting MoF [Ministry of Finance] restrictions on domestic bond issue. (MoF has been a slow learner when major transformations are occurring.)” 6 Over the 1983-87 period (that is, at the height of assembly-based “differentiated Smithian” manufacturing), retained earnings accounted for as much as 53 percent of the sources of funds in Japan. This Japanese percent compared with 72 percent of the sources of funds in , and 66 percent in over the same period (Baums 1994). One empirical study (Weinstein and Yafeh 1998) reveals (i) that the cost of capital of bank-affiliated firms was higher than that of their peers (nonblank-affiliated ones) and (ii) that most the benefits from relation banking were appropriated by the banks. No wonder, then, the “departure from banks” syndrome intensified. Japan’s main bank system was effective in capital allocation only during the early stages of Japan’s postwar FG catch-up --at most until the early 1980s with 1975 as its watershed year. 13 housing-loan companies and consumer credit firms), since the latter were less strictly regulated than the banks themselves. These non-bank bank loans accounted for as much as 37.8 percent of the total loans the real estate industry secured (Noguchi 1992).

Low interest rates and the abundance of liquidity fueled the rising prices of stocks and real estate. With the share prices and property values, firms and individuals borrowed even more since they used their assets as collateral. Both lenders and borrowers did not realize that they were under the illusion of no-declining property values, which had actually kept soaring over the preceding 40 years (1950-199). Thus a speculative spiral was set in. The dirigiste bank-based finance brought about the problem of moral hazard, but this time the moral hazard effect was thus of the degenerative type (in contrast to the earlier socially justifiable one).

The bursting of the bubble began in early 1990, following the rise in the discount rate. The stock market peaked on the last trading day in 1989, and the urban land price started to fall later. The debacle was a disaster for borrowers in real estate, construction, distribution, and finance, as well as for banks as lenders. The latter thus came to be saddled with the ever-rising amounts of bad loans, the very initial cause of Japan’s present banking crisis.7

3.2. Keiretsu formation, cross-shareholdings and aftermath

The main bank system was organized with keiretsu formation, which emphasized collective collaboration not only within each keiretsu but also between the keiretsu and the government in industrial development.

Keiretsu was part and parcel of Japan’s industrial dirigisme, serving as the critical vehicle through which state- created capital was channeled into investment projects considered essential under industrial policies. Keiretsu served as an effective mechanism to reduce “coordination failures” in large-scale investment projects, which business firms individually are not willing or able to take risks. Only a collective investment can realize the potential of increasing returns, linkages and complementarities (dynamic external economies and indivisibilities) simultaneously in both supply and demand capabilities and spillovers. (This is a classical case

7 According to the latest tally of outstanding bad loans by the Japanese government, they stand somewhere between $337.9 billion (“nonperforming loans” only) and $1.23 trillion (at 122.52 yen =$1) (including “problem loans”), thus all depending on how “bad loans” are defined. As reported in “Debate persists on size of loan problem in Japan, clouding Tokyo’s ability to act,” Wall Street Journal, April 24, 2001.

14 of market failure once debated when the notions of “big push” and “balanced growth” were advanced as a strategy for industrialization in the early postwar period.)

Another feature of the main-bank-cum-keiretsu system is cross-shareholdings among affiliated banks and firms. Mutual holdings of shares were practiced as a way of cementing the business ties among intra-keiretsu organizations and reducing transaction costs (especially the costs of the principal-agent problem and opportunism). The main bank owns shares of its affiliated corporations and other affiliated (usually smaller) banks (up to the legal limit of 5 percent), and vice versa (no limit for non-financial firms, so long as they own other non-financial firms). The bank’s holdings of stocks are said to serve as an important means of influencing the course of business in their client firms, while inter-corporate stockholdings in the non-banking sector is also a symbol of mutual trust (and hostage exchange) and long-term relations. In fact, the interlocking of stock ownership and directorship is what characterizes the keiretsu system, both of the financial (kinyu) and industrial

(sangyo) types. It was supposed to serve as a mutual monitoring mechanism, but in reality it largely deepened the entrenchment of management, since hostile takeovers were hindered under this cross-shareholding arrangement. “Friendly and patient” capital was thus created. 10 to 25 percent of each constituent firm’s stock has come to be held by other firms in the group. In addition, interlocked directorships occur in two-thirds of these firms; in other words, they have full-time executives dispatched form affiliated firms.

It is against this unique background that cross-shareholdings and keiretsu formation have begun to unravel in the recent past, aggravating downward pressure on share prices as a large number of shares are “dumped” to the stock market

The dirigiste main bank system and the keiretsu formation (combined with Japanese-style labor relations to be discussed below) also caused, especially in the aftermath of the bubble burst, (i) the overcapacity, overdiversification and overstaffing of productive facilities in the non-financial (manufacturing, construction, wholesale and retailing and other services) sector (with too many unprofitable subsidiaries and too many employees to be profitable), and (ii) the excessive number of banks (too many banks to be profitable). The former is contributing to the current deflationary pressure, and the latter aggravating the unprofitable (as yet

15 fully restructured) banking sector. Thus the needs for business and financial restructuring have arisen out of

Japan’s once phenomenal growth.8

The Japanese system was a clear case of “insider control,” not only in the benign sense that the majority bloc of the capital stock is held by “friendly” affiliated banks and companies, but also and more importantly, because the government controlled the whole financial sector in such a way to encourage the use of stocks not as investment instruments per se but as a tool to support the main bank system through cross-shareholdings.

Many politicians and big businesses profited from the rigged stock markets at the cost of small investors. It was the Japanese version of “crony capitalism.” The macro-financial “insider control” scheme thus has turned out to be a breeding ground for corruption—and the subsequent disastrous banking mess that had to be cleaned up with the use of hundreds of billions of dollars of tax-payers’ money. .

3.3. The inner-dependent industries as a politically protected (pork-barrel) sector

3.3.1. Emergence of structural dualism and the “Japanese disease”

The Japanese economy has been successful in nurturing dynamic comparative advantages and climbing up the ladder of industrial upgrading under its own style of infant-industry protection strategy. It has been able to transform initially disadvantaged industries into competitive (and comparatively advantaged) ones under the IS-

EP industrial policy. In the meantime, however, Japan also has had many once heavily regulated and protected industries, protected from competition both domestic and foreign, but especially from the latter, if not by outright tariffs, quotas and bans on inward FDI, then by regulations and red tape. The upshot is that a new industrial dualism has emerged: a highly multinationalized (initially only outwardly) efficient sector and a secluded import-averse, inward FDI-restrictive sector (see Figure 3).

The former may be called the outer-focused (OF) sector and the latter the inner dependent (ID) sector. The

OF sector was best represented by automobiles and electronics, while the ID sector included the erstwhile

8 It should also be mentioned in passing that the stock market in Japan was once often “influenced” by the government in terms of administrative guidance rather than actual purchases and sales in the market Until the mid-1980s, for example, the share prices of major Japanese banks remained nearly constant for long periods of time, since regulators wanted “to limit stock price fluctuations in an effort to influence the public’s perception of risk at banks” (Genay, 1999) through administrative guidance. 16 sheltered “inefficient” primary industries (e.g., and fisheries) and services industries (such as

telecommunications, transportation, wholesaling and retailing, construction, finance, insurance, and

maintenance services --e.g., auto repair), as well as some manufacturing industries that are heavily domestic-

market focused (e.g., food and beverage). In the beginning, extensive protection and a web of regulations were

applied to the entire economy. In general, the OF sector was under the purview of the Ministry of International

Trade and Industry (MITI), while the ID sector was under the supervision of a variety of inward-looking

ministries: the Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, the Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications,

the Ministry of Transportation, the Ministry of Construction, the Ministry of Finance, the Ministry of Internal

Affairs, the Ministry of Health and Welfare, and the Ministry of Labor, although some of them also had

overlapping regulatory power over the OF sector in varying degrees and forms.9

These government ministries have been the home of the interventionists promoting the development of

domestic industries under their jurisdictions, thus continuing the bureaucratic tradition established by the

Japanese government after the Meiji Restoration of 1868. As a latecomer nation, government ministries and

agencies were created, as Johnson (1982) so aptly observed, not so much as “civil servants” per se, as in the

United States, but rather as “task-oriented mobilization and development agencies” whose main functions were

originally “to guide Japan’s rapid forced development in order to forestall incipient colonization by Western

imperialists.” That is to say, their current predispositions toward controls are path dependent—and justified

from a nationalistic point of view.

The OF sector began to emerge as Japan pursued a FG-style strategy of dynamic “infant industry” protection

(that is, IS-EP). For example, to modernize the heavy machinery sector (such as electric turbine and generator)

which Japan had already built in the prewar days, the motto was “the first machine imported, the second

machine domestically produced under licenses.” What made Japan’s infant industry protection work was the

test of exporting; import-substituting domestic production was ultimately aimed at export markets, forcing the

9 Although MITI has often been perceived by outsiders as a staunch protectionist guarding Japan’s manufacturing sector, it was the first ministry to become “internationalist” or “globalist”—by Japan’s past standard if not by international standards—simply because of the need of most Japanese manufacturers to go overseas as multinationals. MITI has become much more internationally minded than, say, the Ministry of Finance and the Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications, not to speak of the Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, and the Ministry of Labor. 17 industry to improve on not only prices but also quality, eventually enabling it to leap scale economies (dynamic increasing returns). Japan’s automobile industry, which initially had to come up with “less scale- dependent/scaled-down technologies,” is the best example; the early-on protection of a small domestic market and a large number (more than ten) of domestic automobile producers who vigorously competed in entering this growth industry, as depicted by the “reserved competition” formula (Ozawa 1997), created a conducive/compelling environment for the birth of a so-called “lean or flexible production” originally at the hands of Toyota Motor Corp. (Ohno 1978; Womack, Jones, and Roos, 1990).

As dynamic comparative advantages were acquired in the OF sector, its rising trade surplus began to cause a sharp appreciation of the yen and an ever-rising competitive pressure on the ID sector. Hence this intersectoral effect via the is the Japanese version of the “Dutch disease.” Imports should have become available to Japanese consumers at cheaper and cheaper prices in yen terms, but they were either hindered by trade and inward FDI barriers or they were not delivered/passed through at cheaper retail prices

(i.e., the exchange gains were simply pocketed by the highly regulated/protected distribution sector). In fact, instead of having competitive forces rationalize the ID sector, the government used to hold on to—and even reinforced through administrative guidance—its regulatory involvement to further shelter the ID sector. The reason was that the ID sector as a whole (but especially finance, construction and distribution) was the key political power base (that is, financial source) of the Liberal Democratic Party, Japan’s long-lasting political party since the early postwar period. This is the reason why the ID sector may be most appropriately called a

“pork-barrel sector.”

This aggravated all the more severely the structural gap between the two sectors in respect to their openness to the outside world and productivity, a gap which continued to be reflected in price discrepancies between home and foreign markets at the retail level. To cope with the ever-rising yen, the OF sector had to keep raising productivity to remain export competitive. As the sector succeeded in this endeavor, however, it again faced another round of yen appreciation because the ID sector did not absorb imports sufficiently enough to relieve the upward pressure on the . In other words, the OF sector came to be entrapped in a treadmill: a

18 “vicious” cycle from a struggle for productivity improvement and a greater trade surplus, to a higher-value yen,

and to an even greater need for cost cutting (Ozawa 1997).10

It should be stressed that the two structurally differentiated sectors are not totally separate, but are

interconnected in a variety of ways. For example, the manufacturing side of Japan’s automobile industry is in

the OF sector, but its domestic distribution side and some of its suppliers of inputs are in the ID sector. Japan’s

automakers established their own networks of exclusive dealerships as well as their own multi-layered systems

of parts suppliers. There is little doubt that their tight control on distribution was one important hindrance to car

imports. Even though one automaker’s exclusive dealership discriminate equally all other compatriot

competitors (hence some argue that it is not discriminatory only to imports), the exclusive dealerships set up by

all the major domestic producers as a whole surely became a barrier to imports.

Particularly as the result of their exclusive keiretsu sales arrangements, Japan’s automakers have been able to

maintain relatively price-stable and profitable market conditions at home, which until recently was enhanced by

Japan’s steady macroeconomic growth (Itami 1994). The same situation applies to the consumer

electric/electronics goods industry. Thus, the keiretsu groups straddle both the OF and the ID sectors. And the

OF portion of their business activities often benefit form the ID portion (distribution). This may explain, at

least in part, why price duality occurred between home and abroad (Ito and Maruyama 1991).11

3.3.2. Excessive outward FDI and the “price-industry-flow (a la David Hume)” syndrome

In the OF sector, the incessant drive to product and process innovations, and notably the spreading of “lean

or flexible production” techniques from the automobile industry to other assembly-based OF industries such as

electronics, further helped expand Japan’s manufacturing exports, causing inevitable trade conflicts overseas.

Assembly-based firms (that is, “differentiated Smithian” industries) first set up assembly operations in their

10Thus the Japanese version of the “Dutch disease” became even more complicated and aggravated because of interactive feedbacks between the two sectors—and needs to be identified sui generis as the “Japanese disease.” The Japanese genre is self-inflictied by politics and aggravating on the OF sector, while the Dutch genre is externally inflicted by a high world price of natural gas (i.e., the market) and involves a situation in which one sector damages others uni-directionally. And Japan’s present problem with deflationary pressure stems from this origin of the disease 11 In addition to the keiretsu, the more protected the domestic market is, the easier it is for Japanese producers to price discriminate against their home consumers. Price discrimination is a “hidden” form of creating subsidies—that is, let domestic consumers indirectly subsidize exports and domestic production. The OF-ID dual structure provides a mechanism that allows such subsidization (Ozawa 1997). 19 core export markets, North America and Europe. This move actually increased Japanese exports of parts and

components, further ballooning Japan’s trade surplus. In the meantime, the ID sector continued to hinder

imports—hence a further appreciation of the yen and an aggravation of the “Japanese disease.” The ID-sector-

connected government ministries and politicians continued to protect their own turfs, resulting in a

rigidification a la Olson (1982) of macro-organizational institutions (Japan’s old catch-up regime) and their

practices.

The super-yen began to wipe out the price competitiveness of the OF manufacturers. In response, these

manufacturers began to transplant more price-sensitive segments of production involving low-end products and

standardized parts and components to low-cost countries, mostly in Asia, via FDI, original equipment

manufacturing (OEM), and subcontracting. And Japanese manufacturers in the OF sector began to import from

their own overseas ventures and business affiliates. Thus, many once exporting industries in the OF sector have

become multinational users of imports—and in fact, become import-promoting due to the appreciating yen. In

other words, paradoxically, it is not so much the ID sector but the initially export-competitive OF sector that

has become increasingly more and more import-dependent.

There is strong evidence that during the abnormally overvalued yen period (over 1985-1995) Japanese firms

did transplant production excessively abroad—excessively because some FDIs were induced not so much

because they lost real competitive/ comparative advantages, but rather because the abnormally high yen made it

distortionally more costly to produce at home than abroad. The “price-distortion” effect of the foreign

was thus the primary cause of the sharp growth in Japan’s outward FDI in the 1985-1996 period

(actually comprising two surging waves of outward FDI in 1986-1991 and 1994-1996).12 In other words, FDI

became overwhelmingly a financial manifestation a la Aliber (1993) rather than a real-market optimization.

This meant that Japan became a high-cost country, and many Japanese firms moved out of Japan not so much because they were genuinely attracted to overseas host countries (which offered, say, some promising local markets or truly favorable, first-best industrial milieu) but rather because they had to escape from the

12 This means that the “assembly-transplanting” type of outward investment shown in Figure 1 became exaggerated. 20 ever-increasing cost burden of home-based production.13 One government agency study (Small and Medium

Enterprise Agency 1996: 268) reveals a close correlation between the trend (curve) of “internal-external price differential” and that of outward FDI (as a ratio of domestic capital investment) over the 1975-1994 period.

Thus, an orderly transplantation of only comparatively disadvantaged industrial activities was switched to a distortional, premature and disorderly transfer of still comparatively advantaged activities from Japan.

The excessive overseas investment compelled by the overvalued yen caused fears about a possible

“hollowing-out” of Japanese industry and rising unemployment. In response, Japanese industry kept minimizing the contraction of domestic productive facilities instead of closing down while simultaneously expanding overseas production. The upshot was an additional rise in excessive corporate productive capacities, which is now haunting Japanese industry.

In short, it is a paradoxical development, since such a successful and strong industrial buildup in automobiles and electronics at home has been accompanied with precipitous industrial outflows (a threat of industrial hollow-out). The more cost-competitive they became in their effort to remain in business at home, the greater the need for shifting production from home to overseas This paradox can be described as the “price-industry- flow” mechanism by paraphrasing David Hume’s (1752) “price-specie-flow” mechanism. Hume stressed the fact that even if a country tries to run trade surpluses and accumulate precious metals by pursuing mercantilist policy, the precious metals thus gained will be drained out of the country, since its domestic money supply

(under a metallic standard) will automatically rise, thereby causing inflation and making the initial trade surplus disappear (hence an outflow of precious metals). Similarly, the more successful Japan’s neo-mercantilist industry policy to build up manufacturing at home under protection and promotion was, the greater the upward pressure on the yen and wages at home—amplified by the distortion effect of the OF-ID dual structure; hence, the eventual decline of Japan’s home-based manufacturing. This analogy is surely appropriate, especially in light of Japan’s present struggle to dismantle and reform its FG catch-up regime.

13 Stephen Hymer’s (1960) seminal work emphasized the possession of “advantages,” the “removal of competition” and the “diversification” of business risks) as key motives for investing overseas. And these advantages are supposed to be substantially large enough to offset any cost of doing business overseas; otherwise, firms would stay home. The recent Japanese experience has another motive, a motive to escape from the rising unfavorable costs of home-based production which squeeze profits—that is, the “home- disadvantaged production”. 21 3.4. The principle of “job primacy over efficiency” as an implicit social contract

Although Japan did experience a brief period of labor strife between leftist-inspired unionists and

management in the very early postwar period, it soon came to develop harmonious labor relations and began to concentrate on rebuilding Japan—especially after the sudden change in the occupation forces’ initially liberal labor policy and the subsequent crackdown on communist-controlled unions with the onset of the Cold War.

What has evolved from the early postwar chaos is the unique Japanese style of management and industrial relations, which Ozaki (1991) even called “human capitalism” or the “humanistic enterprise system, ” because of its strong emphasis on human resource development. Sasakibara (1993, p. 4) argues that “the fundamental principle underlying the Japanese model of mixed economy is anthropocentricism.” In particular, “lifetime employment,” “seniority system” and “company unions” were until very recently singled out as the defining characteristics of the Japanese brand of corporatism.

Of course, in the war-devastated early-postwar Japan collaboration and cooperation were, on the whole, the necessities for survival rather than a choice. But Japan is also basically an egalitarian society, and Japanese businessmen have been traditionally beholden, with a strong sense of loyalty and obligation, to their own groups and subordinates. Unlike American society which is strongly embedded in individualism, self-centered and opportunistic behavior is not looked upon favorably in Japan. Hence, against the backdrop of the adverse economic conditions right after the war, the Japanese company came to be organized and governed as a multi- stake sharing unit, representing the interests of its employees (in job security and income), its creditors (in loan obligations) and its suppliers (in steady and reliable orders for sub-assemblies, parts, components and accessories)—in addition to the stake of its stock holders (in long-term corporate growth as “patient capital”).

This feature is called “stakeholder model” and identified as a form of “shared growth” by the World Bank

(1993) when it explored the secrets of “the East Asian Miracle.”

Indeed, one may argue that without such a “humanistic” orientation of the Japanese system the now-world- renowned “flexible production” paradigm would have never seen the light of the day during the “differentiated

Smithian” stage of assembly-based growth. This new production paradigm is also called “Toyotaism” as opposed to “Fordism-Taylorism.” What is especially revolutionary about it is the activation of intellectual 22 capabilities of shop-floor workers; they are no longer treated merely as “brawn workers” who only take orders

as under Fordism-Taylorism but considered as “brain workers” who can figure out operational problems they

encounter every day, suggest ways of solving them, and keep improving their own work processes. Aoki

(1988) calls this phenomenon an active use of the “information-processing capacity” of workers. This practice

soon spread to other industries and a variety of flexible production came to be innovated throughout Japan’s

manufacturing sector.

In short, Japan’s labor relations which have thus evolved and contributed so much to the phenomenal growth

in labor productivity are institutionalized/ingrained as a national asset and cannot be easily dismantled just for

the sake of showing a favorable near-term “bottom line” by cutting payrolls so as to please investors in the

stock market. The Japanese simply cannot put the livelihood interest of workers behind the pecuniary interest

of financiers or rentiers. And this “belief system “ needs to be taken fully into account when one wonders why

corporate Japan is so indecisive and slow in carrying out institutional reforms (or becoming more like the

U.S.).14

4. Final assessment

Japan was once successful in pursuing the FG strategy of catch-up growth. In fact, it enjoyed high growth

(a growth rate of about 10 percent annually) during the so-called Golden Age of Capitalism (1950-1974) by

capitalizing on the favorable global environment, especially in the context of stable exchange rates (under the

original IMF system) and intensification of the Cold War. In those years the United States opted for a foreign

policy in favor of security, even at some cost to its own economic interests, to ensure Asia’s “continuous

orientation toward Washington” (Cumings 1984). This policy allowed Japan an opportunity to harvest benefits

from America’s liberal trade regime, the opportunity to pursue dirigiste capitalism or FG catch-up.

Japan’s dirigiste catch-up regime was quite effective in facilitating rapid industrial upgrading at home

without creating foreign ownership of domestic industries. This regime worked nicely up until the late1970s.

Japan had by then gone through heavy and chemical industrial modernization (i.e., “nondifferentiated Smithian”

14 Japan’s societal value of egalitarianism was also taken advantage of as a political rationale for the ID sector --and particularly for providing a justification for pork-barrel politics (Patrick’s comment). 23 stage) and begun to build up assembly-based, component-intensive industries, notably cars and electronics (i.e.,

“differentiated Smithian” stage).

To recapitulate, the FG catch-up regime was built on a unique set of four key institutional arrangements:

state-directed bank-based finance of development (the main bank system), keiretsu formation, the ID (“pork

barrel”)sector, and Japanese-style management. This institutional setup proved quite effective, combined with a

high level of postwar education and human capital formation, in inducing quick technological absorption,

productivity increases and adaptive innovations. Learning occurred mostly in the form of licensing agreements.

But, as Japan succeeded climbing the ladder of industrial development, these arrangements quickly became not

only obsolete but more importantly obstructive to further growth. Bank-loan capitalism resulted in the 1987-

1990 bubble and the present prolonged banking crisis with rising bad debts. The growth of a dual industrial

structure (OF vs. ID) led to huge trade surpluses, sharp appreciation of the yen, and lopsided outflows of

investment (both FDI and portfolio). Constrained by its social contract for job security, post-bubble Japan

ended up with excess capacities, contributing to downward pressure on prices. Liberalization of imports in the

distribution sector added to this woe. And all of a sudden, Japan found itself in a deflationary spiral. This is

the “hidden” side, and an undesirable outcome, of Japan’s once successful FG strategy. The FG model is

incomplete unless its institutional dimension is fully taken into account.

References

Akamatsu, Kaname (1935). Wagakuni yomo kogyohin no susei [Trend of Japan’s wooden product industry]. Shogyo Keizai Ronse (Journal of Higher Commercial School), 13, 129-212.

Akamatsu, Kaname (1961). A theory of unbalanced growth in the world economy. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 86 (2), 196-215.

Akamatsu, Kaname (1962). A historical pattern of economic growth in developing countries. The Developing Economies, preliminary issue, No.1, March-August, 1-23.

Aliber, Robert Z. (1993). The multinational paradigm. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Aoki, Masahiko (1988). Information, incentives, and bargaining in the Japanese economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

24 Aoki, Masahiko (1994). Toward an of the Japanese firm. In Ken’ichi Imai and Ryutaro Komiya (Eds.), Business enterprise in Japan: views of leading Japanese (pp. 39-71). Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Aoki, Masahiko, Kevin Murdock, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara (1997). Beyond the East Asian miracle: Introducing the market-enhancing view. In Masahiko Aoki, Hyung-Ki Kim, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara (eds.), The role of government in East Asian economic development (pp. 1-40). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Aoki, Masahiko and Hugh Patrick, (Eds.) (1994). The Japanese main bank system: Its relevance for developing and transforming economies. Oxford: .

Arisawa, Hiromi (Ed.) (1967). Nihon sangyo hyakunenshi [100-year history of Japanese industry]. Volume 1, Tokyo: Nihon Keizai.

Baums, Theodor (1994). The German banking system and its impact on corporate finance and governance. In Masahiko Aoki and Hugh Patrick (Eds.), The Japanese main bank system (pp. 409-449). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Berri, David and Terutomo Ozawa (1997). Pax Americana and Asian exports: Revealed trends of comparative advantage recycling. Journal, 11 (1), Spring: 39-67.

Cumings, Bruce (1984). The origins and development of the northeast Asian political economy: Industrial sector, product cycles and political consequences. International Organization 38 (winter),149-153.

Dowling, Malcolm, and Chia Tien Cheang (2000). Shifting comparative advantage in Asia: new tests of the `flying geese’ model. Journal of Asian Economics 11, 443-463.

Genay, Hesna (1999). Japanese banks and market discipline. Chicago Fed Letter, No. 144, August.

Gregory, R.G. (1986). Overview. In Mutoh, Hiromichi et al. (Eds.), Industrial policies for Pacific economic growth (pp. 1-22). Sydney: Allen & Unwin.

Hymer, Stephen (1960). The international operations of national firms. Ph.D. dissertation at MIT, later published by MIT Press (1976).

Itami, Hiroyuki (1994). Nihon no jidosha sangyo: Naze kyu bureiku ga kakkatanoka [Japan’s auto industry: Why a sudden brake?]. Tokyo: NTT.

Ito, Takatoshi, and Masayoshi Maruyama (1991). Is the Japanese distribution system really inefficient? In (Ed.), Trade with Japan: has the door opened wider? Chicago: University of Chicago Press:

Johnson, Chalmers (1982). MITI and the Japanese miracle: The growth of industrial Policy, 1925-1975. Stanford: Press.

Kester, Karl W. (1991). Japanese takeovers: the global contest for corporate control. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.

Kojima, Kiyoshi (2000). The `flying geese’ model of Asian economic development: origin, theoretical extensions, and regional policy implications.” Journal of Asian Economics 11: 375-401.

25 Kojima, Kiyoshi and Terutomo Ozawa (1984). Micro- and macro-economic models of direct foreign investment: toward a synthesis. Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 25 (1), June: 1-20.

Kojima, Kiyoshi and Terutomo Ozawa (1985). Toward a theory of industrial restructuring and dynamic comparative advantage.” Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 26 (2), December: 135-145.

Komiya, Ryutaro et al (1988). Industrial policy of Japan. Tokyo: Academic Press.

Korhonen, Pekka (1994). Japan and the Pacific free trade area. London: Routledge.

Miyazaki, Yoshikazu (1980). Excessive competition and the formation of keiretsu. In Kazuo Sato (Ed.), Industry and business in Japan (pp. 53-73). White Plain, New York: Sharpe.

Noguchi, Yukio (1992). Baburu no keizaigaku: Nihon keizai ni nani go okkottanoka [Economics of bubble: What happened to the Japanese economy]. Tokyo: Hihon Keizai Shimbunsha.

North, Douglass C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

North, Douglass C. (1999). Understanding the process of economic change. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

Ohno, Tai’ichi (1978). Toyota seisan hoshiki: Datsu-kibo no keiei o mezashite [Toyota production formula: toward non-scale-based management]. Tokyo: Daiyamondo.

Olson, Mancur (1982). The rise and decline of nations: economic growth, stagnation and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Ozaki, Robert S. (1991). Human capitalism: the Japanese enterprise system as world model. Tokyo: Kodansha International.

Ozawa, Terutomo (1993). Foreign direct investment and structural transformation: Japan as a recycler of market and industry. Business & the Contemporary World, 5 (2), spring, 129-149. . Ozawa, Terutomo (1997). Japan. In John Dunning (Ed.), Governments, globalization, and International business (pp. 377-406). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Ozawa, Terutomo (1999). Bank loan capitalism and financial crisis: Japanese and Korean experiences. In Alan Ragman and Gavin Boyd (Eds.), Deepening integration in the Pacific economies: corporate alliances, contestable markets and free trade (pp. 214-248). Cheltenham, UK.: Edward Elgar.

Ozawa, Terutomo (2000a). The `flying-geese’ paradigm: toward a co-evolutionary theory of MNC-assisted growth. In Khosrow Fatemi (Ed.), The new world order: internationalism, regionalism and the multinational corporations (pp. 209-223). Amsterdam & New York: Pergamon.

Ozawa, Terutomo (2000b). Japanese firms in deepening integration: evolving corporate governance. In Stephen Cohen and Gavin Boyd (Eds.), Corporate governance and globalization: long range planning issues (pp. 216-244). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

26 Ozawa, Terutomo (2001). Borrowed growth: current-account deficit-based development finance. In Khosrow Fatemi (Ed.), International public policy and regionalism at the turn of the century (pp. 95-113). Oxford, UK: Elsevier Science.

Patrick, Hugh (1994a). Comparisons, contrasts and implications. In Hugh Patrick and Yung Chul Park (Eds.), The Financial development of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan (pp. 325-372). New York: Oxford University Press.

Patrick, Hugh (1994b). The relevance of Japanese finance and its main bank system. In Masahiko Aoki and Hugh Patrick (Eds.), The Japanese main bank system: its relevance for developing and transforming economies (pp. 353-408). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Patrick, Hugh and Henry Rosovsky (Eds.) (1976). Asia’s new giant: how the Japanese economy works. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution.

Sasakibara, Eisuke (1993). Beyond capitalism: the Japanese model of market economics. Lanham, MD: University Press of America.

Schumpeter, Johseph A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Originally published in German. English translation, New York: Oxford University Press.

Small and Medium Enterprise Agency (1996). Chusho kigyo hakusho [white paper on small and medium enterprises]. Tokyo: Ministry of Finance Printing Office.

Tabb, William K. (1995). The postwar Japanese system: cultural economy and economic transformation. New York: Oxford University Press.

Teranishi, Juro (1994). Japan: development and structural change of the financial system. In Hugh Patrick and Yung Chul Park (Eds.), The financial development of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan (pp. 27-80). New York: Oxford University Press.

UNCTAD (1995). World investment report 1995. New York and Geneva: UN.

Wallich, Henry and Mabel Wallich (1976). Banking and finance. In Hugh Patrick and Henry Rosovsky (Eds.), Asian’s new giant: how the Japanese economy works (pp. 249-315). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Weinstein, David E. and Yishay Yafeh (1998). On the costs of a bank-centered financial system: evidence from the changing main bank relations in Japan. Journal of Finance, Vol. LII (2), 635-672.

Womack, James P., Daniel T. Jones, and Daniel Roos (1990). The machine that changed the world. New York: Macmillan.

World Bank (1993). The East Asian miracle: economic growth and public policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

27 Figure 1 Japan’s industrial upgrading and overseas investment: comparative advantage Recycling (CAR) as adaptive efficiency enhancement (AEE)

Stages of industrial upgrading (a leading-growth-sector model)

I Labor-driven “Heckscher-Ohlin” industries (e.g., textiles) II Scale-driven “nondifferentiated Smithian” industries (e.g., steel) III Component-intensive, assembly-based industries (e.g., autos and early- generation electronics) IV Innovation-focused R&D-intensive “Schumpeterian” industries (e.g., new materials, biotechnology and latest-generation electronics)

Domestic IV output III Value

II

I

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

I’ Overseas Investment II’ Value III’

IV’

Phases of overseas investment

I’ Low-wage-labor-seeking “elementary” FDI II’ Resource-seeking and house-cleaning FDI III’ Assembly-transplanting/market-seeking FDI (inclusive of low-wage-seeking FDI in parts/components/accessories and low-end products) IV’ Alliance-seeking (strategically networking)) FDI in production, marketing and R&D

Note: The above trend curves are not drawn to exact scale—for illustrative purposes only. Output and FDI may be alternatively expressed in percentage terms when these trends are empirically verified.

Source: based on Ozawa (1993) with modifications. 28 Figure 2 The dirigiste catch-up regime (“institutional matrix”) of Japan’s FG development

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Phase I Phase II Phase III Phase IV “Input-driven” high growth “Efficiency-driven” growth “Shared growth” heavy & chemical industrialization lean production (“Growth with equity”) Implicit social contract

A. State-directed bank-based Moral hazard Reforms finance (the “main bank” “Socially desirable” type “degenerative” type system and stakeholder Bad-debt model ) Effective crisis Stock-market till mid-‘70s Bubble capitalism, (1987- U.S.-style? B. Keiretsu formation h “One-set” principle/ “reserved competition” 1990) h Cross-shareholdings Unraveling of Stock market cross-shareholdings slump

C. “Privatized welfare”/ ”pork-barrel” sector Dual industrial structure High yen/ Escape from Industrial productivity dilemma high-cost home overcapacity nOuter-focused (OF), comparatively advantaged industrial sector Deflationary (dynamic “infant industry” protection) spiral

nInner-dependent (ID), heavily regulated/ protected sector (LDP-connected) Bank of Japan’s (agriculture, telecommunications, banking & “quantitative financial services, construction, retailing, easing” wholesaling, utilities, food & beverage) 3/19/01

D. Principle of job primacy over efficiency hLifetime employment practice Towards a merit-based system, but at large firms: seniority system still a humanistic ideology of labor relations 29 Figure 3 Structural dualism, the “Japanese disease” and the “price-industry-flow (a la David Hume)” syndrome

Outer-focused (OF) A treadmill of cost- sector: Initially Export cutting & higher yen comparatively promotion: Export disadvantaged but “infant- growth Excessive eventually industry” Drive to Export outward FDI advantaged strategy productivity expansion Hollowing out? industries growth

Lopsided Yen trade appreciation surplus Excess capacity at home/abroad

Inner-dependent (ID) Heavy Import/inward Olsonian Slow pace of Sector: Perennially protection, FDI ossification of deregulation: disadvantaged regulations restrictions institutions “pork-barrel” industries and controls sector

ID-sector: Agriculture, forestry, fisheries, food and beverage, telecommunications, transportation, wholesaling and retailing, construction, finance, insurance, real estate and other domestic-market-focused services.

The Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, the Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications, the Ministry of Transportation, the Ministry of Construction, the Ministry of Finance, the Ministry of Health and Welfare, etc.

Source: Ozawa (1996)

30