A Note on Krugman's Liquidity Trap

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Note on Krugman's Liquidity Trap University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Economics Department Working Paper Series Economics 2018 A Note on Krugman's Liquidity Trap Stefano Di Bucchianico Department of Economics, Roma Tre University (Italy) Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umass.edu/econ_workingpaper Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Di Bucchianico, Stefano, "A Note on Krugman's Liquidity Trap" (2018). UMass Amherst Economics Working Papers. 254. https://doi.org/10.7275/13358827 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Department Working Paper Series by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. For more information, please contact [email protected]. A NOTE ON KRUGMAN’S LIQUIDITY TRAP Stefano Di Bucchianico* November 2018 Abstract: The 1998 stylized model of Krugman constituted a ground-breaking contribution explaining the long lasting Japanese stagnation as the consequence of a ‘liquidity trap’ situation featuring a negative natural interest rate. Our critique to such a proposal will focus on three aspects. First, we will question the logical structure of the model, providing an alternative interpretation of its closure. Second, we will argue that aggregate demand has no role in the explanation, as the cause for the persistent excess of savings over desired investment is the result of a supply side shock plus a financial rigidity on the nominal interest rate. Finally, we will discuss the restrictive assumptions needed to get a negative natural interest rate, the concept that lies at the foundation of the entire theoretical apparatus. Our conclusion is that the explanation offered within the 1998 contribution does not provide a satisfying rationale for the Japanese stagnation. Keywords: Liquidity trap, Japanese stagnation, natural interest rate JEL Codes: E31, E40, E52, E58 *Department of Economics, Roma Tre University, [email protected] 1. Introduction Krugman (1998) discusses extensively the Japanese prolonged stagnation of the late eighties – nineties, many times referred to as the Japanese ‘lost decade’, trying to trace back its ultimate causes. His aim was to provide a possible explanation for that situation by means of a new analytical concept. Later on such contribution has been often cited by the author himself as one of his best pieces, and has gained widespread acceptance in the academy as a path-breaking article. Its importance rests also in the fact that the analytical germ of what, after the Great Recession, will be called the ‘demand side Secular Stagnation’ strand of thought (Summers 2014, 2015) can be found in this contribution. In particular, in this stylized model we find a formal treatment of how a negative natural real interest rate can appear in an economy; when the latter is coupled with the zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate, an underemployment equilibrium emerges. The analysis carried out in this paper has a twofold goal: on the one hand, we want to ascertain whether the novelty constituted by an equilibrium position featuring a negative natural real interest rate is analytically justified, on the other hand, we analyse what is the role of aggregate demand in the explanation for the long term economic stagnation of the Japanese economy. In our discussion we will highlight how the conclusions that Krugman drew from the model appear unwarranted from both a theoretical and an empirical viewpoint. In particular, we will see that the steps for the convergence to an equilibrium can be read differently from what the author proposed, and that the negative natural interest rate appearance is tied to a series of overtly restrictive assumption. Moreover, on the empirical side there is no confirm for the fundamental hypothesis of a decreasing potential output, which lies at the basis of his explanation. We further complement these arguments by maintaining that aggregate demand does not play any role in this theoretical apparatus, which basically relies on a supply side shock and a rigidity on the nominal interest rate to interpret the Japanese stagnation. Given that Summers has recently described the issue of Secular Stagnation for the US economy using a close analogy to the reasoning of Krugman, this work can also serve to recognize what are the roots of the demand side Secular Stagnation theory. In section 2 we are going to reconstruct the model of Krugman, which starts from an endowment economy and is then refined with the price rigidity case and an example to study investment, in section 3 we discuss the questionable assumptions needed to get the underemployment equilibrium and the irrelevant role that aggregate demand plays in such a model, while section 4 concludes. 2 2. The 1998 seminal contribution of Paul Krugman about Japan Krugman, in the writing of the model, was mainly interested in retrieving the Keynesian ‘liquidity trap’ category from the old – fashioned IS – LM analysis.1 This is the objective of the first half of the paper, while the second is devoted to applying the conclusions of the model to the Japanese case. In working out such task however, Krugman aimed also at updating that tool with three features: i) an intertemporal structure based on rational expectations, ii) an open economy treatment with foreign trade and capital mobility, iii) the role of financial intermediaries. In what follows, we are going to deal with the basic formulation of the model. Our interest points mostly to the general formulation, since in that framework the natural real interest rate is shown to be negative given some specific condition, and the zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate prevents the economy from attaining full employment. As Krugman formulates it, a ‘liquidity trap’ is “a situation in which conventional monetary policy has become impotent, because nominal interest rates are at or near zero: injecting monetary base into the economy has no effect, because base and bonds are viewed by the private sector as perfect substitutes”. (Krugman 1998, p. 141) Let us notice that by coupling this description with the negativity of the natural interest rate, we get the same picture described by the intuition of Summers (2014, 2015) about the US stagnation. Summers handles the US case proposing a reasoning in which the real natural interest rate turns negative when the demand for investment is peculiarly weak while the supply of savings is high. This causes the emergence of an underemployment situation since the zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate and the low inflations prospects prevent the Central Bank from being able to hit the equilibrium real interest rate. Therefore, it is in our opinion interesting to discuss the 1998 model as the first in which a negative real natural interest rate is presented as an impediment to full employment output realization, and to single out its relevance also in light of the recent discussion about Secular Stagnation. Given the very stylized nature of the model we are going to review, it is in our opinion useful starting with a narrative description of the most important messages that Krugman wants to convey to the reader. Then, we are going to follow Krugman in putting those clues in a simple model. The American economist aimed at recreating in a modern intertemporal two periods model a situation of Keynesian flavour in which, given a rigidity on the nominal interest rate determined on 1 Whose first proposer in a formalized model had been Hicks (1937). 3 the financial market, the real natural interest rate is not attainable by monetary policy.2 The initial version of the model is built upon these hypothesis: agents in the model are described by a single representative agent with a given utility function; there are two time periods, today and tomorrow. Once tomorrow comes about, the economy remains in the state described by the second period situation. Only the transition between the two periods is described; there is no production, as only endowments of a single consumption good are given to the representative agent today and tomorrow; the Quantity Theory of Money holds, as the Central Bank can raise the price level by injecting money into the economy; there is price flexibility for what concerns the price of the single consumption good available, but there is also a rigidity on the nominal interest rate, which cannot go below zero; the price level of tomorrow is given. Krugman, in the first place, wants to reproduce analytically a situation in which a liquidity trap emerges. As we will see, by supposing that the endowments of the consumption good are given for the two periods, and given the utility function of the representative agent, he can arrive at the real natural interest rate. When a specific assumption upon the amount of endowments available is made (namely, that the endowment tomorrow is adequately lower than the one of today), such a natural interest rate becomes negative. Given the zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate, the Central Bank can push the nominal interest rate at most down to zero, but no further; yet the attainment of the equilibrium real rate could be brought about by stimulating inflation. Indeed, even if the nominal interest rate is stuck at zero, raising inflation expectations can succeed in appropriately lowering the real interest rate down to the level of the natural rate, thus achieving equilibrium. It is here that the hypothesis about the given price level of tomorrow acquires an important role. Such an hypothesis in fact represents a way to formalize the idea that agents are so convinced about the reliability and willingness of the monetary authority to preserve price stability that they will not believe that the price level tomorrow will be considerably higher than today.
Recommended publications
  • Digitalisation and Monetary Policy
    Does the liquidity trap exist? Lhuissier, Mojon and Rubio-Ramirez AEA Congress, 4 January 2021 The views expressed here are mine and should not be attributed to the BIS Restricted “A liquidity trap may be defined as a situation in which conventional monetary policies have become impotent, because nominal interest rates are at or near zero: injecting monetary base into the economy has no effect, because base and bonds are viewed by the private sector as perfect substitutes” Paul Krugman (1998) Restricted 2 Outline 1. Motivation 2. Literature 3. Empirical analysis 4. Results 5. Discussion Restricted 3 1. Motivation: How low can long-term rates be? Central bank balance sheets1 Share of government bonds held by central banks2 % of GDP % of GDP % Restricted 4 1. Motivation: Is there a lack of monetary policy space? • Cutting down short rates and purchasing assets to cut long rates can go only so far and • the lack of “interest rate” space is very critical in several advanced economies • However, into the medium we still need to assess whether and how much MP can do when short-term rates are near the ZLB/ELB Restricted 5 Literature: The ZLB makes MP ineffective Japan . Krugman (1998) – Coenen and Wieland (2003) “John Hicks, in introducing both the IS-LM model and the liquidity trap, identified the assumption that monetary policy is ineffective, rather than the assumed downward inflexibility of prices, as the central difference between Mr. Keynes and the classics.” US and EA, before the facts . Early Fed attemps: Furher and Madigan (97); Orphanides and Williams & Reifschneider and Williams (2000) .
    [Show full text]
  • Cities, Information, and Economic Growth
    Cities, Information, and Economic Growth Cities, Information, and Economic Growth Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University Great are the advantages which people following the same skilled trade get from near neighborhood to one another. The mysteries of the trade become no mysteries; but are, as it were, in the air. A. Marshall Principles of Economics For centuries economists have fervently sought to understand the forces behind economic progress. Smith (1776), Marx (1909), Marshall (1890), Young (1928), and Keynes (1936) all hotly pursued this topic. In the post-World War II period, economic theorists, develop- ment economists, macroeconomists, econometricians, economic historians, and growth economists have devoted considerable energy to thinking about the forces behind long- run growth rates. It would be impossible to claim that these economists have reached a consensus on the causes of growth, but it seems clear that the growth of economies does not involve the simple accumulation of capital and labor. Theoretical models of capital accumulation (based on Solow, 1956, for example) ultimately leave the growth rate as an unexplained outside parameter. Empirically the stunning range of cross-national experiences makes it clear that the forces driving growth are rich and varied. Instead of continuing to use simple capital accumulation models, economists (following Romer, 1986) have moved toward models in which the stock of knowledge, in the Nation and the world, plays a critical role in facilitating progress. The nature of intellectual capi- tal—mostly the presence of strong external effects—solves certain technical problems when explaining why global increasing returns, which are necessary to explain growth, can coexist with competition.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization: What Did We Miss?
    Globalization: What Did We Miss? Paul Krugman March 2018 Concerns about possible adverse effects from globalization aren’t new. In particular, as U.S. income inequality began rising in the 1980s, many commentators were quick to link this new phenomenon to another new phenomenon: the rise of manufactured exports from a group of newly industrializing economies. Economists – trade economists, anyway – took these concerns seriously. After all, standard models of international trade do say that trade can have large effects on income distribution: the famous 1941 Stolper-Samuelson analysis of a two-good, two-factor economy showed how trading with a labor-abundant economy can reduce real wages, even if national income grows. There was every reason to believe that the same principle applied to the emergence of trade with low-wage economies exporting not raw materials but manufactured goods. And so during the 1990s a number of economists, myself included (Krugman 1995), tried to assess the role of Stolper-Samuelson-type effects in rising inequality. Inevitably given the standard framework, such analyses did in fact find some depressing effect of growing trade on the wages of less-educated workers in advanced countries. As a quantitative matter, however, they generally suggested that the effect was relatively modest, and not the central factor in the widening income gap. Meanwhile, the political salience of globalization seemed to decline as other issues came to the fore. So academic interest in the possible adverse effects of trade, while it never went away, waned. 1 In the past few years, however, worries about globalization have shot back to the top of the agenda, partly due to new research, partly due to the political shocks of Brexit and Trump.
    [Show full text]
  • It's BAAACK! Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap
    IT’S BAAACK! JAPAN’S SLUMP AND THE RETURN OF THE LIQUIDITY TRAP In the early years of macroeconomics as a discipline, the liquidity trap - that awkward condition in which monetary policy loses its grip because the nominal interest rate is essentially zero, in which the quantity of money becomes irrelevant because money and bonds are essentially perfect substitutes - played a central role. Hicks (1937), in introducing both the IS-LM model and the liquidity trap, identified the assumption that monetary policy was ineffective, rather than the assumed downward inflexibility of prices, as the central difference between “Mr. Keynes and the classics”. It has often been pointed out that the Alice-in-Wonderland character of early Keynesianism, with its paradoxes of thrift, widow's cruses, and so on, depended on the explicit or implicit assumption of an accommodative monetary policy; it has less often been pointed out that in the late 1930s and early 1940s it seemed quite natural to assume that money was irrelevant at the margin. After all, at the end of the 30s interest rates were hard up against the zero constraint: the average rate on Treasury bills during 1940 was 0.014 percent. Since then, however, the liquidity trap has steadily receded both as a memory and as a subject of economic research. Partly this is because in the generally inflationary decades after World War II nominal interest rates stayed comfortably above zero, and central banks therefore no longer found themselves “pushing on a string”. Also, the experience of the 30s itself was reinterpreted, most notably by Friedman and Schwartz (1963); emphasizing broad aggregates rather than interest rates or monetary base, they argued in effect that the Depression was caused by monetary contraction, that the Fed could have prevented it, and implicitly that even after the great slump a sufficiently aggressive monetary expansion could have reversed it.
    [Show full text]
  • The Secret of Our Non-Success
    Print edition version: Monday October 22, 2012 The Secret of Our Non-Success By PAUL KRUGMAN The U.S. economy finally seems to be recovering in earnest, with housing on the rebound and job creation outpacing growth in the working-age population. But the news is good, not great — it will still take years to restore full employment — and it has been a very long time coming. Why has the slump been so protracted? Fred R. Conrad/The New York Times Paul Krugman The answer — backed by overwhelming evidence — is that this is what normally happens after a severe financial crisis. But Mitt Romney’s economic team rejects that evidence. And this denialism bodes ill for policy if Mr. Romney wins next month. About the evidence: The most famous study is by Harvard’s Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff, who looked at past financial crises and found that such crises are typically followed by years of high unemployment and weak growth. Later work by economists at the International Monetary Fund and elsewhere confirmed this analysis: crises that followed a sharp run-up in private-sector debt, from the U.S. Panic of 1893 to the Swedish banking crisis of the early 1990s, cast long shadows over the economy’s future. There was no reason to believe that this time would be different. This isn’t an after-the-fact rationalization. The Reinhart-Rogoff “aftermath” paper was released almost four years ago. And a number of other economists, including, well, me, issued similar warnings. In early 2008 I was already pointing out the distinction between recessions like 1973-5 or 1981-2, brought on by high interest rates, and “postmodern” recessions brought on by private-sector overreach.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America
    Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America Sebastian Edwards* Economics Working Paper 19106 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 April 25, 2019 According to Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e. the Federal Reserve) – to finance large fiscal deficits that will ensure full employment and good jobs for everyone, through a “jobs guarantee” program. In this paper I analyze some of Latin America’s historical episodes with MMT-type policies (Chile, Peru. Argentina, and Venezuela). The analysis uses the framework developed by Dornbusch and Edwards (1990, 1991) for studying macroeconomic populism. The four experiments studied in this paper ended up badly, with runaway inflation, huge currency devaluations, and precipitous real wage declines. These experiences offer a cautionary tale for MMT enthusiasts.† JEL Nos: E12, E42, E61, F31 Keywords: Modern Monetary Theory, central bank, inflation, Latin America, hyperinflation The Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper Series allows authors to distribute research for discussion and comment among other researchers. Working papers reflect the views of the author and not the views of the Hoover Institution. * Henry Ford II Distinguished Professor, Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA † I have benefited from discussions with Ed Leamer, José De Gregorio, Scott Sumner, and Alejandra Cox. I thank Doug Irwin and John Taylor for their support. 1 1. Introduction During the last few years an apparently new and revolutionary idea has emerged in economic policy circles in the United States: Modern Monetary Theory (MMT). The central tenet of this view is that it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • How to Escape a Liquidity Trap with Interest Rate Rules Fernando Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No
    How to Escape a N O . 776 Liquidity Trap with M A Y 2 0 1 6 Interest Rate Rules REVISED JANUARY 2019 Fernando Duarte How to Escape a Liquidity Trap with Interest Rate Rules Fernando Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 776 May 2016; revised January 2019 JEL classification: E43, E52, E58 Abstract I study how central banks should communicate monetary policy in liquidity trap scenarios in which the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates is binding. Using a standard New Keynesian model, I argue that the key to preventing self-fulfilling deflationary spirals and anchoring expectations is to promise to keep nominal interest rates pegged at zero for a length of time that depends on the state of the economy. I derive necessary and sufficient conditions for this type of state contingent forward guidance to implement the welfare-maximizing equilibrium as a globally determinate (that is, unique) equilibrium. Even though the zero lower bound prevents the Taylor principle from holding, determinacy can be obtained if the central bank sufficiently extends the duration of the zero interest rate peg in response to deflationary or contractionary changes in expectations or outcomes. Fiscal policy is passive, so it plays no role for determinacy. The interest rate rules I consider are easy to communicate, require little institutional change and do not entail any unnecessary social welfare losses. Key words: zero lower bound (ZLB), liquidity trap, new Keynesian model, indeterminacy, monetary policy, Taylor rule, Taylor principle, interest rate rule, forward guidance _________________ Duarte: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (email: [email protected]) The author thanks Sushant Acharya, Tobias Adrian, Christine Breiner, Marco Del Negro, Gauti Eggertsson, Marc Giannoni, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Alfonso Irarrazabal, Chris Sims, Rui Yu, and, particularly, Anna Zabai for comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • A Neoclassical Theory of Liquidity Traps
    A Neoclassical Theory of Liquidity Traps Sebastian Di Tella∗ Stanford University August 2017 Abstract I propose a flexible-price model of liquidity traps. Money provides a safe store of value that prevents interest rates from falling during downturns and depresses in- vestment. This is an equilibrium outcome — prices are flexible, markets clear, and inflation is on target — but it’s not efficient. Investment is too high during booms and too low during liquidity traps. The optimal allocation can be implemented with a tax or subsidy on capital and the Friedman rule. 1 Introduction Liquidity traps occur when the role of money as a safe store of value prevents interest rates from falling during downturns and depresses investment. They can be very persistent, and are consistent with stable inflation and large increases in money supply. Liquidity traps are associated with some of the deepest and most persistent slumps in history. Japan has arguably been experiencing one for almost 20 years, and the US and Europe since the 2008 financial crisis. This paper puts forward a flexible-price model of liquidity traps and studies the optimal policy response. The baseline model is a simple AK growth model with log utility over consumption and money and incomplete idiosyncratic risk sharing. Markets are otherwise complete, prices are flexible, and the central bank follows an inflation-targeting policy. During downturns idiosyncratic risk goes up and makes risky capital less attractive. Without money, the real interest rate would fall and investment would remain at the first best level. ∗ I’d like to thank Manuel Amador, Pablo Kurlat, Chris Tonetti, Chad Jones, Adrien Auclert, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Narayana Kocherlakota, Bob Hall, and John Taylor.
    [Show full text]
  • Breaking the Mould: an Institutionalist Political Economy Alternative to the Neoliberal Theory of the Market and the State Ha-Joon Chang, May 2001
    Breaking the Mould An Institutionalist Political Economy Alternative to the Neoliberal Theory of the Market and the State Ha-Joon Chang Social Policy and Development United Nations Programme Paper Number 6 Research Institute May 2001 for Social Development The United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD) thanks the governments of Denmark, Finland, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom for their core funding. Copyright © UNRISD. Short extracts from this publication may be reproduced unaltered without authorization on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to UNRISD, Palais des Nations, 1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland. UNRISD welcomes such applications. The designations employed in UNRISD publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the presentation of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of UNRISD con- cerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. The responsibility for opinions expressed rests solely with the author(s), and publication does not constitute endorse- ment by UNRISD. ISSN 1020-8208 Contents Acronyms ii Acknowledgements ii Summary/Résumé/Resumen iii Summary iii Résumé iv Resumen v 1. Introduction 1 2. The Evolution of the Debate: From “Golden Age Economics” to Neoliberalism 1 3. The Limits of Neoliberal Analysis of the Role of the State 3 3.1 Defining the free market (and state intervention) 4 3.2 Defining market failure 6 3.3 The market primacy assumption 8 3.4 Market, state and politics 11 4.
    [Show full text]
  • Macro-Economics of Balance-Sheet Problems and the Liquidity Trap
    Contents Summary ........................................................................................................................................................................ 4 1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................... 7 2 The IS/MP–AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................ 9 2.1 The IS/MP model ............................................................................................................................................ 9 2.2 Aggregate demand: the AD-curve ........................................................................................................ 13 2.3 Aggregate supply: the AS-curve ............................................................................................................ 16 2.4 The AD/AS model ........................................................................................................................................ 17 3 Economic recovery after a demand shock with balance-sheet problems and at the zero lower bound .................................................................................................................................................. 18 3.1 A demand shock under normal conditions without balance-sheet problems ................... 18 3.2 A demand shock under normal conditions, with balance-sheet problems ......................... 19 3.3
    [Show full text]
  • JAPAN's TRAP Paul Krugman May 1998 Japan's Economic Malaise Is First and Foremost a Problem for Japan Itself. but It Also Poses
    JAPAN'S TRAP Paul Krugman May 1998 Japan's economic malaise is first and foremost a problem for Japan itself. But it also poses problems for others: for troubled Asian economies desperately in need of a locomotive, for Western advocates of free trade whose job is made more difficult by Japanese trade surpluses. Last and surely least - but not negligibly - Japan poses a problem for economists, because this sort of thing isn't supposed to happen. Like most macroeconomists who sometimes step outside the ivory tower, I believe that actual business cycles aren't always real business cycles, that some (most) recessions happen because of a shortfall in aggregate demand. I and most others have tended to assume that such shortfalls can be cured simply by printing more money. Yet Japan now has near-zero short-term interest rates, and the Bank of Japan has lately been expanding its balance sheet at the rate of about 50% per annum - and the economy is still slumping. What's going on? There have, of course, been many attempts to explain how Japan has found itself in this depressed and depressing situation, and the government of Japan has been given a lot of free advice on what to do about it. (A useful summary of the discussion may be found in a set of notes by Nouriel Roubini . An essay by John Makin seems to be heading for the same conclusion as this paper, but sheers off at the last minute). The great majority of these explanations and recommendations, however, are based on loose analysis at best, purely implicit theorizing at worst.
    [Show full text]