Tf Iuprene (Court of Tme Mnitetb Tate

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Tf Iuprene (Court of Tme Mnitetb Tate <1AV 7O7 CD ,Z 0 · - , .CD° i 4, , iI : INo. -NO. II - ) tf iuprene (Court of tMe Mnitetb tate -. ) .- OCTOBER TERM, 1982 , . .. 0u FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, ET AL., PETITIONERS oo~ V~. O - GROLIER INCORPORATED PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO I: THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT-OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT .. REX E. LEE Solicitor General J. PAUL MCGRATH Assistanit Attorney General .. · - KENNETH S. GELLER Deputy Solicitor General . - SAMUEL A. ALITO,:JR. Assistant to the Solicitor General LEONARD SCHAITMAN ALFRED MOLLIN $4 Attorneys Department ofq'Justice Washington, D.C. 20530 (202) 633-2217 JOHN H. CARLEY General Counsel Federal Trade Comnmission Washingtonz, D.C. 20580 o , ,6 - QUESTION PRESENTED Whether Exemption 5 of the Freedom of Information 3. .: Act, 5 U.S.C. 552(b)(5), exempts from mandatory clis- ,~.P=-= ~0 0 closure the work-product of government attorneys when the litigation for which the material was prepared has ended and the government cannot demonstrate that re- 3o . ': .. ,- lated litigation exists or potentially exists. CDC, , .- : . .:, ?'; O . l - . PARTIES TO THE PROCEEDING The parties in the court of appeals, in addition to those · , " -,- ,. named in the caption, were the members of the Federal ,-_ . .. '. Trade Commission. At present, the members of the Com- mission are James C. -". r'?' "': Miller, III, Chairman, and Michael Pertschuk, David M. Clanton, and Patricia P. Bailey, Commissioners. ':.'-.:' :,'i:~ .:,'o. r.. : .: .... ,.' '% -: ' '. ';' ,,?:'': . .- . -,t:;, = - i 'A,j: ' - ':1,-'l e(- ,?t - ".';,, f?' ·.8.., ., (I) > iii111 C D OFiiTABLE CONTENTS TABLE OF CONTENTS Cases-Continued Page Page CD m CnO Upjohn v. United States, 449 U.S. 383 ............. 7 Opinions below ....................................... 1 uc,,, , Jurisdiction .......................................... 1 Statutes, and rule: 00 Statute involved ................................. 1 Freedom of Information Act, 5 U.S.C. 552: Statement ........................................... 3 5 U.S.C. 552(a)(3) ............................ 2, 8 5 U.S.C. 552(a)(4)(B) ........................ 2, 15 9s .. Reasons for granting the petition ....................... CD 6 5 U.S.C. 552(b)(5) ............... 2-3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 10, 15 rtD Conclusion ........................................... 16 Fed. R. Civ. P.: -. Rule 26(b)(3) ............................. 4, 7, 14 Appendix A .......................................... la Rule 26(c)(2) ................................. 8 Appendix B .......................................... 15a Miscellaneous: Appendix C .......................................... 16a H.R. Rep. No. 1479, 89th Cong., 2d Sess. (1966) .... 8, 9 Appendix D .......................................... 19a Notes of Advisory Committee on 1970 Amendment to Rules, 28 U.S.C. App. at 442 .................... 7 Appendix E .......................................... 21a S. Rep. No. 813, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. (1965) ....... 7 TABLE OF AUTHORITIES Cases: Duplan Corp. v. Deering Milliken, Inc., 540 F.2d 1215 11 Duplan Corp. v. Moulinage et Retorderie de Chavanoz, 487 F.2d 480; 509 F.2d 730, cert. denied, 420 U.S. 997 11 EPA v. Mink, 410 U.S. 73 ........................ 8 FOMC v. Merrill, 443 U.S. 340 .................... 7, 15 Hercules, Inc. v. Exxon Corp., 434 F.Supp. 136 ..... 13-14 Hickman v. Taylor, 329 U.S. 495 ............... 7,10, 13 Midland Investment Co. v. Van Alstyne, Noel & Co., 59 F.R .D . 134 .................................... 14 Moody v. IRS, No. 81-2142 (D.C. Cir. June 25, 1982) 15 p Murphy, In re, 560 F.2d 326 ...................... 5, 11 NLRB v. Sears, Roebuck & Co., 421 U.S. 132 ................................ 4, 6, 7, 8, 9, 12, 15 PhiladelphiaElectric Co. v. Anaconda American Brass Co., 275 F.Supp. 146 ........................... 14 Republic Gear Co. v. Borg-Warner Corp., 381 F.2d 551 .............................................. 13, 14 United States v. Leggett & Platt,Inc. 542 F.2d 655, cert. denied, 430 U.S. 945 ........................... 11 3 I i ·.1 .) - °. 0 C3 x3 O° In toe upremte Court of- tte niteb *tateo °~1j C) - ) Co O a> _ OCTOBER TERM, 1982 No. CDc i FiEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, ET AL., PETITIONERS CD ( '-Om~.= V. - .0 00 ' -. GROLIER INCORPORATED PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT The Solicitor General, on behalf of the Federal Trade Commission, et al., petitions for a writ of certiorari to review the judgment of the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit in this case. OPINIONS BELOW The opinion of the court of appeals (App. A, infra, la-14a) is reported at 671 F.2d 553. The opinion of the district court (App. E, infra, 21a-23a) is not reported. JURISDICTION The judgment of the court of appeals was entered on February 5, 1982 (App. B, infra, 15a) and a timely peti- tion for rehearing was denied on April 7, 1982 (Apps. C and D, infra, 16a, 19a). By orders of June 29, 1982 and August 3, 1982, the Chief Justice extended the time with- in which to file a petition for a writ of certiorari to and including September 4, 1982. The jurisdiction of this Court is invoked under 28 U.S.C. 1254(1). (1) r11 o -Z~ 2 (NCD C) F ( CD O 0 3 0D 0 °O OD PU)Q ; C- STATUTE H O) ,-. INVOLVED CA (5) inter-agency or intra-agency memorandums >C 'D 0 Subsection (a)(3) of the Freedom of Information Act, 5 or letters which would not be available by law to a 3- - a O U.S.C. 552(a)(3), provides: party other than an agency in litigation with the 0 Except with respect to the records made available agency. U) =I- W- CD CD g - - . o) under paragraphs (1) and (2) of this subsection, each a STATEMENT ?i e o-. agency, upon any request for records which (A) reas- -. o O- onably describes such records and (B) is made in This Freedom of Information Act ("FOIA") suit arose 0C) accordance with published rules stating the time, out of a request by respondent Grolier Incorporated for C) place, fees (if any), and procedures to be followed, documents of the Federal Trade Commission ("FTC") shall make the records promptly available to any 0 concerning, among other things, a covert person. investigation by the FTC of one of Grolier's subsidiaries, the Americana Subsection (a)(4)(B) of the Freedom of Information Corporation (App. A, infra, la).' Americana had been the Act, 5 U.S.C. 552(a)(4)(B), provides: defendant in a civil penalty action filed by the Depart- On complaint, the district court of the United ment of Justice in 1972 (United States v. Americana States in the district in which the complainant re- Corp., Civil No. 388-72 (D.N.J.)) (App. A, infra, la).2 sides, or has his principal place of business, or in The FTC complied in part with the FOIA request, but it which the agency records are situated, or in the withheld part or all of seven documents relating to the District of Columbia, has jurisdiction to enjoin the investigation of Americana. Grolier then brought suit in agency from withholding agency records and to order the production of any agency records the United States District Court for the District of Col- improperly withheld from the complainant. In such a umbia to compel release of those documents. case the court shall determine the matter de novo, and may examine the contents of such agency rec- ords in camera to determine whether such records or I In addition to records relating to the Americana investigation any part thereof shall be withheld under any of the exemptions set forth in subsection (b) of this section, ("Category A" records), Grolier also requested records relating to and the burden is on the agency to sustain its actions. covert investigations of any of its 14 subsidiaries ("Category B" records) and records relating to covert investigations of any related Subsection (b)(5) of the Freedom of Information Act, 5 person, company or entity ("Category C" records). However, Gro- U.S.C. 552(b)(5), provides: lier's district court complaint was confined to Category A and B records, and Grolier later withdrew any claim for further disclosure (b) This section does not apply to matters that of Category B documents. Thus, Grolier's appeal involved only Cate- are- gory A records. See Appellant's Opening Brief at 2 n. 1. * * * * * 2 The civil penalty action was based upon an alleged violation of a 1949 cease and desist order prohibiting misrepresentations in door- to-door sales and false advertising. It was dismissed with prejudice in 1976 after the Commission declined to comply with a district court order directing it to turn over certain documents to the defendant (App. A, infra, 2a). C-C1> ~ 4 'C5 CD CD SCLc C) 5 a, 1 0 CD The FTC contended that certain of the documents," A divided including the four still at issue (i.e., Numbers 3, 5, 6, and court of appeals vacated the district court's C) judgment regarding 7), fell within Exemption 5 of the FOIA, 5 U.S.C. those four documents. The panel majority 552(b)(5), because they were work-product compiled by conceded that "[t]here is no question that the C) X ES F<) . documents FTC attorneys in anticipation of the civil penalty action involved were work-product prepared as a W - O -. part of the Americana action" (App. A, infra, 2a). How- 00 against Americana and therefore would normally be priv- ever, the ileged in the civil discovery context. Because Exemption majority stated that the applicability of Exemp- 0 C: 5 tion 5 of the FOIA depended upon 5 "exempt[s] those documents, and only those docu- "whether these docu- ments continue ments, normally privileged in the civil discovery context" to be privileged against disclosure several C ,) years after the Americana suit was terminated" (ibid.). C) (NLRB v. Sears, Roeback & Co., 421 U.S. 132, 149 3 The court below (1975)), the FTC maintained that the documents sought noted (App.
Recommended publications
  • The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals
    Volume 86 Issue 3 Dickinson Law Review - Volume 86, 1981-1982 3-1-1982 The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals John A. Maher Follow this and additional works at: https://ideas.dickinsonlaw.psu.edu/dlra Recommended Citation John A. Maher, The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals, 86 DICK. L. REV. 403 (1982). Available at: https://ideas.dickinsonlaw.psu.edu/dlra/vol86/iss3/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Reviews at Dickinson Law IDEAS. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dickinson Law Review by an authorized editor of Dickinson Law IDEAS. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals John A. Maher* I. Introduction A. Recent Events December 17, 1980 is a remarkable date for those interested in either quality of government or, more particularly, evolution of the Federal Trade Commission's sense of the unfair.' On that day, the five Commissioners then in office2 purported to renounce Commis- sion reliance on what they apparently regarded as a non-exclusive substantive rule of decision concerning the content of their enabling 3 act's use of "unfair . .acts or practices." That renounced can be said to possess the cachet of Supreme Court approval by reason of a unanimous opinion in FTC.v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co.4 (S&H). * A.B. 1951, University of Notre Dame; LL.B. 1956, LL.M. (Trade Regulation) 1957, New York University; Professor, Dickinson School of Law. Professor Maher currently serves the Banking & Business Law Section of the Pennsylvania Bar Association as chairperson of its antitrust committee and as a member of its committee for reform and recodification of Penn- sylvania's corporation and partnership laws.
    [Show full text]
  • Amazon's Antitrust Paradox
    LINA M. KHAN Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox abstract. Amazon is the titan of twenty-first century commerce. In addition to being a re- tailer, it is now a marketing platform, a delivery and logistics network, a payment service, a credit lender, an auction house, a major book publisher, a producer of television and films, a fashion designer, a hardware manufacturer, and a leading host of cloud server space. Although Amazon has clocked staggering growth, it generates meager profits, choosing to price below-cost and ex- pand widely instead. Through this strategy, the company has positioned itself at the center of e- commerce and now serves as essential infrastructure for a host of other businesses that depend upon it. Elements of the firm’s structure and conduct pose anticompetitive concerns—yet it has escaped antitrust scrutiny. This Note argues that the current framework in antitrust—specifically its pegging competi- tion to “consumer welfare,” defined as short-term price effects—is unequipped to capture the ar- chitecture of market power in the modern economy. We cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive. These concerns are height- ened in the context of online platforms for two reasons. First, the economics of platform markets create incentives for a company to pursue growth over profits, a strategy that investors have re- warded. Under these conditions, predatory pricing becomes highly rational—even as existing doctrine treats it as irrational and therefore implausible.
    [Show full text]
  • Caspar Weinberger and the Reagan Defense Buildup
    The University of Southern Mississippi The Aquila Digital Community Dissertations Fall 12-2013 Direct Responsibility: Caspar Weinberger and the Reagan Defense Buildup Robert Howard Wieland University of Southern Mississippi Follow this and additional works at: https://aquila.usm.edu/dissertations Part of the American Studies Commons, Military History Commons, Political History Commons, and the United States History Commons Recommended Citation Wieland, Robert Howard, "Direct Responsibility: Caspar Weinberger and the Reagan Defense Buildup" (2013). Dissertations. 218. https://aquila.usm.edu/dissertations/218 This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by The Aquila Digital Community. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations by an authorized administrator of The Aquila Digital Community. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The University of Southern Mississippi DIRECT RESPONSIBILITY: CASPAR WEINBERGER AND THE REAGAN DEFENSE BUILDUP by Robert Howard Wieland Abstract of a Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate School Of The University of Southern Mississippi In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements For the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy December 2013 ABSTRACT DIRECT RESPONSIBILITY: CASPAR WEINBERGER AND THE REAGAN DEFENSE BUILDUP by Robert Howard Wieland December 2013 This dissertation explores the life of Caspar Weinberger and explains why President Reagan chose him for Secretary of Defense. Weinberger, not a defense technocrat, managed a massive defense buildup of 1.5 trillion dollars over a four year period. A biographical approach to Weinberger illuminates Reagan’s selection, for in many ways Weinberger harkens back to an earlier type of defense manager more akin to Elihu Root than Robert McNamara; more a man of letters than technocrat.
    [Show full text]
  • Academia and Law, 63-64 Administrative Law Judges (Aljs), 54, 86
    INDEX academia and law, 63-64 administrative law judges (ALJs), 54, 86, 153-54 advertising, 72 and children, 77 corrective, 52-53 industry study, 54-55 Joe Camel campaign, 167-68 Aleinikoff, T. Alexander, 184 American Bar Association Antitrust Law Section, 42,43,44,45, 93, 108-109, 138 Commission to Study the FTC, 42-50 second Kirkpatrick Commission Report, 84, 124 Anthony, Sheila, 163 AOL (America On Line), 140, 147-48 Areeda, Phillip E., 68, 71 Areen, Judith, 100, 101, 108, 184 Arnold & Porter, 30, 52, 60, 92, 178, 180, 182, 187 Ashenfeld, Orley, 143 Askanaga, Mary, 123 Association of American Law Schools (AALS), 67 automobile industry, 75-76 Baer, William J., 89-90, 124, 135, 160, 171 Baker, Jonathan, 124 Bar Association of the District of Columbia, 93-94 Bartel, Paul, 81 Bator, Paul, 64, 68, 70, 71 Baxter, William, 91 Beard, Dita, 87 Beechnut/Heinz, 142, 145-46 Bernstein, Jodie, 51-52, 124, 128, 133, 135, 139, 154, 165, 167, 171 Bar Association of the District of Columbia, 93, 94 and Food and Drug Administration (FDA), 173 identity theft measures, 176-77 review process changes, 169-70 Bernstein, Lewis, 28 Bingaman, Anne, 116-17,121, 137 Black, Charles, 19 Blake, Harlan, 39,40,43, 62 Boast, Molly, 171 Boies, David, 125, 156, 157 -AI- Bok, Betty, 43 Bork, Robert, 3 8, 120 BP/Arco, 148-49 Brandeis, Louis D., 125 Brennan, William J., 5, 100 Breyer, Stephen, 60, 68, 71, 152 Brown, Charles, 157 Browne, John, 148 Buc, Nancy, 5 1,56 Bureau of Consumer Protection. See Federal Trade Commission Burson, Charles, 119 Bush, George, 121, 179 Bush, George W., 163, 179, 180 Califano, Joseph, 33,61,68, 100, 106 Calkins, Stephen, 124 cartels, 128-30 Carter, James E.
    [Show full text]
  • Panel Consisting of Robert Pitofsky, Professor of Law, Georgetown University Law Center, Washing- Ton, Dc; Cass R
    572 PANEL CONSISTING OF ROBERT PITOFSKY, PROFESSOR OF LAW, GEORGETOWN UNIVERSITY LAW CENTER, WASHING- TON, DC; CASS R. SUNSTEIN, PROFESSOR, UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO LAW SCHOOL AND DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, CHICAGO, IL; AND MARTHA MATTHEWS, STAFF AT- TORNEY, NATIONAL CENTER FOR YOUTH LAW, AND FORMER LAW CLERK TO JUDGE STEPHEN G. BREYER, SAN FRAN- CISCO, CA STATEMENT OF ROBERT PITOFSKY Mr. PITOFSKY. Thank you, Senator Kennedy. It is a privilege to be invited to testify in these important hearings. I believe that Steve Breyer from all points of view is an outstand- ing nominee to the Supreme Court. I will concentrate today, how- ever, on that part of his record dealing with economic regulation and particularly his record in antitrust. That record has been sub- ject to very thoughtful questions by Senator Metzenbaum and oth- ers on the committee, and subject to some criticism by witnesses who testified a little earlier today. I recognize two themes in the criticism. One is sort of a numbers game approach that Judge Breyer is supposed to have decided an unusual number of cases in favor of defendants in antitrust cases, and then there has been some criticism of specific decisions. As far as the numbers game is concerned, first of all, if people are going to use the numbers game approach, they ought to get their numbers right. The claim is—I nave heard it repeatedly today—that he decided 16 consecutive cases against the defendant. Actually, the score was 14 to 2, and I cited two cases for the plain- tiff in my prepared testimony.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust and Deregulation Abstract
    HOWARD SHELANSKI Antitrust and Deregulation abstract. Because regulation works alongside antitrust law to govern market structure and economic conduct in the United States, deregulatory cycles can create gaps in competition enforce- ment. Antitrust is sometimes portrayed as just another form of government intervention that a deregulatory administration should also diminish. This Feature argues that policy makers should resist that political logic. Instead, antitrust should become stronger as regulation becomes weaker. Antitrust as a countercyclical force to deregulation will most directly help to protect consumers from enforcement gaps that result as competition-related rules recede. But antitrust enforcement in deregulating markets can also help to demonstrate where antitrust can govern markets more effectively and efficiently than regulation; it canovide pr the federal courts with an opportunity to clarify recent Supreme Court decisions on the boundary between antitrust and regulation; and it can better inform ongoing policy debates about the effectiveness of antitrust by providing a more accurate view of what antitrust enforcement can accomplish with its existing legal and analytic framework. Not only is each of these benefits of countercyclical antitrust enforcement important in its own right, but together they can lead to better policy choices between antitrust and regula- tory solutions as political cycles change over time. author. Professor of Law, Georgetown University; Partner, Davis Polk & Wardwell LLP. The author previously served as Administrator of the White House Office of Information and Regula- tory Affairs and as Director of the Federal Trade Commission’s Bureau of Economics. The author is grateful to Jonathan Sallet, Scott Hemphill, Catherine Waddams, Erik Herron, workshop par- ticipants at the University of East Anglia, and participants in the conference on “Unlocking the Promise of Antitrust Enforcement” at American University for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Bait-And-Switch" Regulation
    William & Mary Business Law Review Volume 4 (2013) Issue 2 Article 6 April 2013 Explaining "Bait-and-Switch" Regulation David Adam Friedman Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmblr Part of the Commercial Law Commons Repository Citation David Adam Friedman, Explaining "Bait-and-Switch" Regulation, 4 Wm. & Mary Bus. L. Rev. 575 (2013), https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmblr/vol4/iss2/6 Copyright c 2013 by the authors. This article is brought to you by the William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/wmblr EXPLAINING “BAIT-AND-SWITCH” REGULATION * DAVID ADAM FRIEDMAN ABSTRACT “Bait and switch” can describe a range of commercial behaviors com- mon in the everyday marketplace, but virtually ignored in the academic literature. The traditional definition of unlawful bait and switch applies to insincere offers to sell one item in order to induce the buyer to purchase another. Certain sellers have historically employed bait-and-switch tactics, including urban retailers, aluminum siding companies, and supermarkets. Colloquially, this definition can also cover lawful or other borderline sales tactics, including the use of teaser rates or low introductory pricing, or even “free offers.” Even common lawful tactics, like the deliberate routing of customers past other retail displays on their way to purchase high-volume or featured items, may involve “bait” to induce other purchases. Why are some of these behaviors lawful and others unlawful? In this Article, I examine several different flavors of bait-and-switch tactics, ex- ploring the underlying behaviors behind the tactics and the welfare impli- cations of regulating them.
    [Show full text]
  • 1962 Annual Report
    Annual Report of the FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION For the Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1962 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Washington, D.C., 20402 - Price 45 cents (paper cover) Federal Trade Commission PAUL RAND DIXON, Chairman SIGURD ANDERSON, Commissioner WILLIAM C. KERN, Commissioner PHILIP ELMAN, Commissioner EVERETTE MACINTYRE, Commissioner JOHN V. BUFFINGTON, Assistant to Chairman JOSEPH W. SHEA, Secretary JOHN N. WHEELOCK, Executive Director FRANK C. HALE, Program Review Officer JAMES MCI. HENDERSON, General Counsel EARL J. KOLB, Director of Hearing Examiners DANIEL J. MURPHY, Director Bureau of Deceptive Practices WILLIAM F. MUELLER, Director Bureau of Economics SAMUEL L. WILLIAMS, Director Bureau of Field Operations BRYAN H. JACQUES, Director Bureau of Industry Guidance JOSEPH E. SHEEHY, Director Bureau of Restraint of Trade HENRY D. STRINGER, Director Bureau of Textiles and Furs ii EXECUTIVE OFFICES OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Pennsylvania Avenue at Sixth Street Northwest, Washington 25, D.C. Field Offices 30 Church St., New York 7, N. Y. Room 10511, U.S. Courthouse and Federal Building, 515 Rusk Avenue, Houston, Tex. Room 1310, 226 West Jackson Boulevard, Chicago 6, Ill. Room 811, U. S. Courthouse, Seattle 4, Wash. Room 306, Pacific Building, San Francisco 3, Room 1128, Standard Building, Cleveland 13, Calif. Ohio. Room 405, 215 West Seventh Street, Los Angeles Room 2806, Federal Office Building, Kansas 14, Calif. City, Mo. Room 1001, 131 State Street, Boston 9, Mass. Room 915, Forsyth Building, Atlanta 3, Ga. Room 1000, Masonic Temple Building, New 958 North Monroe Street, Arlington 1, Va. Orleans 12, La.
    [Show full text]
  • The F.T.C., Oligopoly, and Shared Monopoly Faculty Research Working Paper Series
    The F.T.C., Oligopoly, and Shared Monopoly Faculty Research Working Paper Series F.M. Scherer Harvard Kennedy School September 2013 RWP13-031 Visit the HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series at: http://web.hks.harvard.edu/publications The views expressed in the HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or of Harvard University. Faculty Research Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate on important public policy challenges. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. www.hks.harvard.edu THE F.T.C., OLIGOPOLY, AND SHARED MONOPOLY F. M. Scherer September 2013 One of the most important but equally difficult problems faced by antitrust agencies is posed by oligopolistic firms sufficiently few in number that they refrain from active price competition even without entering into explicit price-fixing agreements. Expanding upon a tradition extending back in time at least to A. A. Cournot (1838), Edward H. Chamberlin crystallized the dilemma in his 1933 classic (from p. 48 of the 1948 edition): If each [seller] seeks his maximum profit rationally and intelligently, he will realize that when there are only two or a few sellers his own move has a considerable effect upon his competitors, and that this makes it idle to suppose that they will accept without retaliation the losses he forces upon them. Since the result of a cut by any one is inevitably to decrease his own profits, no one will cut, and, although the sellers are entirely independent, the equilibrium result is the same as though there were a monopolistic agreement among them.
    [Show full text]
  • ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT and INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: Promoting Innovation and Competition
    ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: Promoting Innovation and Competition ISSUED BY THE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE AND THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION APRIL 2007 ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: Promoting Innovation and Competition ISSUED BY THE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE AND THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION APRIL 2007 This Report should be cited as: U.S. DEP’T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM’N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION (2007). This Report can be accessed electronically at: www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf www.ftc.gov/reports/index.shtm TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................................. 1 CHAPTER 1: THE STRATEGIC USE OF LICENSING: UNILATERAL REFUSALS TO LICENSE PATENTS ................................................. 15 I. Introduction ......................................................... 15 II. The Kodak and CSU Decisions .......................................... 16 A. The Basic Facts and Holdings of the Cases .................. 16 B. Panelist Views on Kodak .................................. 17 C. Panelist Views on CSU ................................... 18 D. Ambiguity as to the Scope of the Patent Grant .............. 19 III. Policy Issues Relating to Unilateral Refusals to License ................... 20 A. Should Antitrust Law Accord Special Treatment to Patents? .. 21 B. Should Market Power Be Presumed with Patents? ........... 22 C. If an Antitrust Violation Were Found, Would There Be Workable Remedies for Unconditional, Unilateral Refusals to License Patents? .............................. 22 D. What Would Be the Effect of Liability for Refusals to License Patents on Incentives to Innovate? .................. 23 E. Competitive Effects of Refusals to License Patents ........... 24 IV. Legal Analysis of Unilateral Refusals to License Patents ................... 25 A. Does Section 271(d)(4) of Title 35 of the U.S. Code Create an Immunity for Unilateral Refusals to License Patents? .....
    [Show full text]
  • Chartcommissioners and Chairmen of the Federal
    COMMISSIONERS AND CHAIRMEN OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION MARCH 2013 CHAIRMEN OF THE FTC AND THE DATES SERVED Chairmen Selected by Commissioners 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 1. Davies (D) Mar 16, 1915 to Jun 30, 1916 2. Hurley (D) Jul 01, 1916 to Jan 31, 1917 GEORGE RUBLEE (P) 03/16/15-09/08/16 3. Harris (D) Feb 01, 1917 to May 06, 1918 JOHN F. FORT (R) 03/16/17-11/30/19 4. Colver (D) May 07, 1918 to Jun 30, 1919 NELSON B. GASKILL (R) 02/01/20-02/24/25 5. Fort (R) Jul 01, 1919 to Nov 30, 1919 WILLIAM E. HUMPHREY (R) 02/25/25-10/07/33 6. Murdock (P) Dec 01, 1919 to Nov 30, 1920 GEORGE C. MATHEWS (R) 10/27/33-06/30/34 7. Thompson (D) Dec 01, 1920 to Nov 30, 1921 ROBERT E. FREER (R) 08/27/35-12/31/48 8. Gaskill (R) Dec 01, 1921 to Nov 30, 1922 9. Murdock (P) Dec 01, 1922 to Nov 30, 1923 JOHN CARSON (IND) 09/28/48-03/31/53 10. Thompson (D) Dec 01, 1923 to Nov 30, 1924 EDWARD F. HOWREY (R) 04/01/53-09/12/55 11. Van Fleet (R) Dec 01, 1924 to Nov 30, 1925 SIGURD ANDERSON (R) 09/12/55-02/29/64 12. Nugent (D) Dec 01, 1925 to Nov 30, 1926 WILL H.
    [Show full text]
  • Using the "Consumer Choice" Approach to Antitrust Law Neil W
    University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2007 Using the "Consumer Choice" Approach to Antitrust Law Neil W. Averitt Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission Robert H. Lande University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation Using the "Consumer Choice" Approach to Antitrust Law, 74 Antitrust L.J. 175 (2007) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. USING THE "CONSUMER CHOICE" APPROACH TO ANTITRUST LAW NEIL W. AVERITT ROBERT H. LANDE* The current paradigms of antitrust law-price and efficiency-do not work well enough. True, they were an immense improvement over their predecessors, and they have served the field competently for a genera­ tion, producing reasonably accurate results in most circumstances. Accu­ mulated experience has also revealed their shortcomings, however. The price and efficiency paradigms are hard to fully understand and are not particularly transparent in their application. Moreover, in a disturbingly large number of circumstances they are unable to handle the important issue of nonprice competition. In this article we suggest replacing the older paradigms with the somewhat broader approach of "consumer choice." 1 The choice framework has several advantages.
    [Show full text]