DISTRIBUTION, WEALTH and DEMAND REGIMES in HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

DISTRIBUTION, WEALTH and DEMAND REGIMES in HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010 FMM WORKING PAPER No. 14 · January, 2018 · Hans-Böckler-Stiftung DISTRIBUTION, WEALTH AND DEMAND REGIMES IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010 Engelbert Stockhammer*, Joel Rabinovich**, Niall Reddy*** ABSTRACT Most empirical macroeconomic research limited to the period since World War II. This paper analyses the effects of changes in income distribution and in private wealth on consumption and investment covering a period from as early as 1855 until 2010 for the UK, France, Ger- many and USA, based on the dataset of Piketty and Zucman (2014). We contribute to the post-Keynesian debate on the nature of demand regimes, mainstream analyses of wealth effects and the financialisation debate. We find that overall domestic demand has been wage-led in the USA, UK and Germany. Total investment responds positively to higher wage shares, which is driven by residential investment. For corporate investment alone, we find a negative relation. Wealth effects are found to be positive and significant for consumption in the USA and UK, but weaker in France and Germany. Investment is negatively affected by private wealth in the USA and the UK, but positively in France and Germany. * Kingston University London & FMM Fellow. ** Université Paris 13. *** New York University. Distribution, wealth and demand regimes in historical perspective. USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010 Engelbert Stockhammer*, Joel Rabinovich** and Niall Reddy*** * Kingston University London, ** Université Paris 13, *** New York University Version 1.04 Oct 2017 Abstract Most empirical macroeconomic research limited to the period since World War II. This paper analyses the effects of changes in income distribution and in private wealth on consumption and investment covering a period from as early as 1855 until 2010 for the UK, France, Germany and USA, based on the dataset of Piketty and Zucman (2014). We contribute to the post-Keynesian debate on the nature of demand regimes, mainstream analyses of wealth effects and the financialisation debate. We find that overall domestic demand has been wage-led in the USA, UK and Germany. Total investment responds positively to higher wage shares, which is driven by residential investment. For corporate investment alone, we find a negative relation. Wealth effects are found to be positive and significant for consumption in the USA and UK, but weaker in France and Germany. Investment is negatively affected by private wealth in the USA and the UK, but positively in France and Germany. Keywords: historical macroeconomics, demand regimes, Bhaduri-Marglin model, wealth effects, financialisation JEL codes: B50, E11, E12, E20, E21, N10 Acknowledgements: This paper is part of the research project ‘Income Distribution, Asset Prices and Aggregate Demand Formation, 1850-2010: A post-Keynesian Approach to Historical Macroeconomic Data’ (INO16-00008) with financial support by the Institute for New Economic Thinking. Earlier versions of this paper have been presented at …. The authors are grateful to Paul Auerbach, Erik Bengtsson, Giorgos Gouzoulis, Rob Jump, Karsten Kohler, Ozlem Onaran, and Rafael Wildauer for helpful comments. All remaining errors are ours. 1 1. INTRODUCTION Empirical research in macroeconomics overwhelmingly analyses recent experience and utilises data of the past three or four decades. However, economic historians have compiled macroeconomic data that go back into the 19th century for several countries. With the renewed interest in financial crises some studies have taken a longer view. Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) offer broad historical coverage of financial crises while Piketty (2014) provides an analysis of wealth inequality, but neither of them offers an econometric analysis. Jorda et al (2016) compile long historic series on private debt and present an econometric analysis of the severity of recessions. However, important contemporary debates in macroeconomics on the effects of changes in income distribution and changes in wealth are marred by historical shortsightedness. The contribution of this paper is to analyse the effects of changes in functional income distribution and of private wealth for long periods for the UK (1855-2010), USA (1929-2010), France (1896-2010) and Germany (1870-2010), using the dataset compiled by Piketty and Zucman (2014). This is the first study that presents results for macroeconomic behavioural equations that cover most of the history of capitalism for the European countries and more than 80 years in the case of the USA. The paper contributes to two debates. The first is on the nature of demand regimes and the effects of changes in functional income distribution. The Bhaduri Marglin model has become a widely used workhorse model for post-Keynesian economists. Its hallmark is that it can depict wage-led as well as profit-led demand regimes depending on the relative size of the saving differential between capital and labour and the profit sensitivity of investment. The model provides a framework for the controversy between the Kaleckian and Marxist-inspired Goodwinians and has sparked a substantial empirical literature with impressive geographical scope (Bowles & Boyer, 1995; Stockhammer and Onaran 2005; Naastepad & Storm, 2006; Hein & Vogel, 2008; Stockhammer, Onaran, & Ederer, 2009; Onaran & Galanis, 2014; Hartwig 2015; Kiefer & Rada, 2015; Stockhammer & Wildauer, 2016; Onaran & Obst 2016). The demand regime approach has recently also been taken up by comparative political economists (Baccaro and Pontusson 2016). However, all existing studies have so far been limited to the postwar era. The second debate that we contribute concerns the effect of wealth on consumption 2 and investment. Consumption studies commonly use mainstream frameworks based on life time utility maximizing individuals who may be credit-constrained and consume part of their wealth (Slacalek 2009, Ludwig and Slok 2004). There are disagreements on the size of wealth effects and whether they differ for financial and housing wealth (Case et al 2005) but these studies rarely cover the period before 1970. The discussion on the impact of wealth on (business) investment has largely taken place outside the mainstream under the heading of financialisation, where several authors have highlighted the negative impact of financial activity on real investment (Stockhammer 2004, Krippner 2005, Onaran and Tori 2017). Again, these contributions cover only the past few decades. This paper builds on Stockhammer & Wildauer (2016), who synthesise these effects in a post-Keynesian macro model, and apply this framework to historic macroeconomic data. We estimate error correction models (ECM) for each country. For consumption we find positive long-run effect of wages for the USA, the UK, and Germany. Our investment results are potentially surprising – they indicate positive or no effects of the wage share on total investment, which comprises business and residential accumulation. For France and the USA we also perform estimations for corporate investment and find that the wage share has a negative effect. This suggests that the residential component is driving the outcome in total investment estimations. Since total investment responds positively to an increase in the wage share, overall domestic private demand is wage-led in the USA, UK and Germany. Regarding wealth effects, we find that effects on consumption are large in the USA and UK and smaller and less significant in France and Germany, which is consistent with the distinction between market-based and bank-based financial systems (Jackson and Deeg 2006). For the investment equation we find a negative effect in the USA and UK, but positive effects in Germany and France. While these effects are not always statistically significant, they suggest that financialisation effects on investment have been operating for longer than previously recognized. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 motivates our consumption and invstement functions and analyses demand regimes with respect to changes in distribution and wealth. Section 3 reviews the existing empirical literature. Section 4 presents data sources and the econometric methodology. Section 5 presents the 3 econometric results and section 6 analyses demand regimes and results for subperiods. Finally, section 7 concludes. 2. DISTRIBUTION, WEALTH AND DEMAND REGIMES We will use general consumption (C) and investment (I) functions that depend on income (Y), the functional distribution of income measured by the wage share (WS) and private wealth (PW): = ( , , ), with ∂C/∂Y, ∂C/∂WS, ∂C/∂PW > 0 Consumption depends positively on income (∂C/∂Y>0). Following a long tradition in classical, Marxist and post-Keynesian theory we assume that the marginal propensity to consume is higher for workers (or recipients of wage incomes) than for capitalists (or recipients of capital incomes), therefore a higher wage share will positively affect consumption (∂C/∂WS > 0). Neoclassical economics usually does not attribute any effect on consumption arising from the distribution of income. Wealth is generally expected to have a positive effect on consumption (∂C/∂PW>0), although there are varying theoretical explanations for this. 1 In mainstream economics this result is generally derived from the utility maximization of rational households (e.g. Aron et al 2012), whereas the financialisation literature emphasises the active role of lenders and non-rational consumption norms (Cynamon & Fazzari, 2008). For New Keynesians, households
Recommended publications
  • Reception Hosted by the Cliometric Society: Saturday, January 5Th, 5:30-7:30 Pm Coronodo Room and Terrace Westin Gaslamp Quarter
    The Newsletter of The Cliometric Society Winter 2013 Vol 27 No. 2 Economic History Association Annual Meeting 2012 By Shawn Michael Adrian, Steve Bannister, Fan Fei, Mary Eschelbach Hansen, Roy Mill, and Marlous van Waijenburg The 72nd annual meeting of the Economic History transport costs in international trade. Association convened from September 21-23, 2012, at the Sheraton Wall Centre Hotel in Vancouver. EHA Adrian Leonard (Cambridge) presented the final President Jeremy Atack, the program committee paper of the session—with perfect English diction. (Robert Margo, Ran Abramitzky, Leah Boustan, His early exploration of “The Pricing Revolution and Eugene White) and the local arrangements in Marine Insurance” uses new data to explain how committee (Angela Redish, David Jacks, Mauricio London companies became the leading insurers of Drelichman, Morten Jerven, and Catherine maritime trade in the 17th century. Discussant Eric Douglas) provided an outstanding weekend of lovely Hilt (Wellesley) encouraged Leonard to focus on accommodations and stimulating sessions. This article asymmetries of information (moral hazard and adverse summarizes the sessions at which original papers were selection) in the complex insurance market. presented. The theme of Session 2 was “Cities in Economic Session 1 covered the historical evolution of trade History.” Jim Sidola (UC-Irvine) presented “Razing and transport costs. Brandon Dupont (Western San Francisco: The 1906 Disaster and the Legacy Washington Univ.), Drew Keeling (Univ. of Zurich), of Urban Land Use” to an almost full room. The and Thomas Weiss (Univ. of Kansas) kicked off disastrous “experiment” allows Sidola to study the conference with a paper on tourism history. This whether land developers are hampered by prior early look at “Passenger Fares for Ocean Travel from development by comparing residential density in non- 1826 to 1916” focused on the relationship between affected areas to density in destroyed areas.
    [Show full text]
  • Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics After World War I
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER June 2018 Working Paper 2018-06 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2018/06/ Suggested citation: Lopez, Jose A., Kris James Mitchener. 2018. “Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2018-06. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2018-06 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER* May 9, 2018 ABSTRACT. Fiscal deficits, elevated debt-to-GDP ratios, and high inflation rates suggest hyperinflation could have potentially emerged in many European countries after World War I. We demonstrate that economic policy uncertainty was instrumental in pushing a subset of European countries into hyperinflation shortly after the end of the war. Germany, Austria, Poland, and Hungary (GAPH) suffered from frequent uncertainty shocks – and correspondingly high levels of uncertainty – caused by protracted political negotiations over reparations payments, the apportionment of the Austro-Hungarian debt, and border disputes. In contrast, other European countries exhibited lower levels of measured uncertainty between 1919 and 1925, allowing them more capacity with which to implement credible commitments to their fiscal and monetary policies.
    [Show full text]
  • A Cliometric Counterfactual: What If There Had Been Neither Fogel Nor
    A Cliometric Counterfactual: What if There Had Been Neither Fogel nor North? By Claude Diebolt (CNRS, University of Strasbourg) and Michael Haupert (University of Wisconsin-La Crosse Author contact information: [email protected] [email protected] Preliminary draft, please do not quote Abstract 1993 Nobel laureates Robert Fogel and Douglass North were pioneers in the “new” economic history, or cliometrics. Their impact on the economic history discipline is great, though not without its critics. In this essay, we use both the “old” narrative form of economic history, and the “new” cliometric form, to analyze the impact each had on the evolution of economic history. Introduction In December of 1960 the “Purdue Conference on the Application of Economic Theory and Quantitative Techniques to Problems of History” was held on the campus of Purdue University.1 It is recognized as the first meeting of what is now known as the Cliometric Society.2 While it was the first formal meeting of a group of like-minded applicants of economic theory and quantitative methods to the study of economic history, it was not the first time such a concept had been practiced or mentioned in the literature.3 Cliometrics was a long time in coming, but when it arrived, it eventually overran the approach to the discipline of economic history, leading to a bifurcation of the economists and historians who practice the art, and the blurring of the distinction between cliometricians and theorists who use historical data. Clio’s roots are historical in nature, and its focus on theory has actually come full circle over the last century and a half.
    [Show full text]
  • Handbook of Cliometrics
    Handbook of Cliometrics Claude Diebolt • Michael Haupert Editors Handbook of Cliometrics With 59 Figures and 20 Tables Editors Claude Diebolt Michael Haupert BETA/CNRS, University of Strasbourg University of Wisconsin – La Crosse Institute for Advanced Study La Crosse, WI, USA Strasbourg, France ISBN 978-3-642-40405-4 ISBN 978-3-642-40406-1 (eBook) ISBN 978-3-642-40407-8 (print and electronic bundle) DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-40406-1 Library of Congress Control Number: 2015943062 Springer Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2016 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made.
    [Show full text]
  • The Integration of Economic History Into Economics
    Cliometrica https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-018-0170-8 ORIGINAL PAPER The integration of economic history into economics Robert A. Margo1 Received: 28 June 2017 / Accepted: 16 January 2018 Ó Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2018 Abstract In the USA today the academic field of economic history is much closer to economics than it is to history in terms of professional behavior, a stylized fact that I call the ‘‘integration of economic history into economics.’’ I document this using two types of evidence—use of econometric language in articles appearing in academic journals of economic history and economics; and publication histories of successive cohorts of Ph.D.s in the first decade since receiving the doctorate. Over time, economic history became more like economics in its use of econometrics and in the likelihood of scholars publishing in economics, as opposed to, say, economic history journals. But the pace of change was slower in economic history than in labor economics, another subfield of economics that underwent profound intellec- tual change in the 1950s and 1960s, and there was also a structural break evident for post-2000 Ph.D. cohorts. To account for these features of the data, I sketch a simple, overlapping generations model of the academic labor market in which junior scholars have to convince senior scholars of the merits of their work in order to gain tenure. I argue that the early cliometricians—most notably, Robert Fogel and Douglass North—conceived of a scholarly identity for economic history that kept the field distinct from economics proper in various ways, until after 2000 when their influence had waned.
    [Show full text]
  • Cliometrics: a Market Account of a Scientific Community (1957-2006)
    Lect. Econ., 66 (enero-junio), pp. 47-82. © Universidad de Antioquia-Lecturas de Economía, 2007. Cliometrics: A Market Account of a Scientific Community (1957-2006) Angela Milena Rojas –Introduction. –I. A Pseudo-market for Scientific Communities. –II. The Golden Age: 1957-1975. –III. Internal Contraction and International Diffusion: 1976-1990. –IV. Toward Disciplinary and Global Integration: 1991-2006. –Conclusions. –References. Primera versión recibida en enero de 2007; versión final aceptada en abril de 2007 Lecturas de Economía. 66 (enero-junio 2007), pp 47-82 Angela Milena Rojas Cliometría: Una comunidad científica en el pseudo-mercado del conocimiento (1957-2006) Resumen: Este artículo tiene como objetivo evaluar las principales contribuciones de la cliometría en la integración global y disciplinaria de las ciencias sociales. A través de una analogía de un pseudo-mercado del conocimiento son analizadas las presiones y respuestas que los cliometristas han enfrentado en tanto una empresa cuyo objetivo es proveer respuestas a ciertas preguntas que la sociedad formula. Basado en una valoración general de los productos cliométricos se encuentra que esta comunidad científica norteamericana revolucionó la práctica de la historia económica y ganó terreno frente a la competencia representada por la historia tradicional. Posteriormente, los cliometristas difundieron sus innovaciones internacionalmente, pero atravesaron divisiones internas que en última instancia han enriquecido sus prácticas y llamado a cooperar con otras comunidades científicas. Palabras clave: cliometría, nueva historia económica, metodología en historia económica, comunidad científica, paradigma de investigación científica, métodos en ciencias sociales. Clasificación JEL: N01, A12, B41. Abstract: This paper aims at assessing the main contributions of cliometrics toward the global and disciplinary integration of social sciences.
    [Show full text]
  • Short Waves in Hungary, 1923 and 1946: Persistence, Chaos, and (Lack Of) Control
    Short Waves in Hungary, 1923 and 1946: Persistence, Chaos, and (Lack of) Control Christopher A. Hartwell Professor of Financial Systems Resilience Bournemouth University, the Business School Bournemouth, UK [email protected] and Professor Kozminski University Warsaw, Poland ABSTRACT Monetary policies follow a complex and chaotic process, one that is enhanced when monetary growth is taken to the extreme, as in hyperinflation. While we have a basic understanding of the complex dynamics of hyperinflation, a less-explored phenomenon accompanying hyperinflationary episodes is the effect that they have on institutional development. Building on recent advances in economic history examining monetary policy and institutions, this analysis uses more explicit recourse to complexity theory and in particular complex adaptive systems to examine two separate hyperinflationary episodes in Hungary, 1923 and 1946. Delving into the institutional and cultural roots of the inflationary policies of the Hungarian government and detailing the institutional effects which succeeded hyperinflation, this paper shows that the twin experiences of Hungary were both chaotic and created a chaotic and complex aftermath, the results of which are still being felt. Indeed, Hungary’s 1923 and especially its 1946 hyperinflation shows that some economic chaos cannot be restrained by political institutions and in fact the institutions themselves were changed. When staring into the abyss, Hungary also found that the abyss stared back. JEL Codes: E42, N14, B52 Keywords: hyperinflation, complex adaptive systems, chaos, monetary policy, Hungary ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: The author has a huge debt of gratitude to Ladislav Krištoufek at the Institute of Economic Studies, Charles University, for his assistance in the chaos calculations.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Reflections on Paul Hohenberg's Recent Presidential
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Komlos, John Working Paper How useful is anthropometric history? Some reflections on Paul Hohenberg’s recent presidential address to the American Economic History Association Munich Discussion Paper, No. 2009-6 Provided in Cooperation with: University of Munich, Department of Economics Suggested Citation: Komlos, John (2009) : How useful is anthropometric history? Some reflections on Paul Hohenberg’s recent presidential address to the American Economic History Association, Munich Discussion Paper, No. 2009-6, Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität München, Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät, München, http://dx.doi.org/10.5282/ubm/epub.10587 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/104291 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Pricking Germany's 'Stock Market Bubble' in 1927 and the Slide
    With a Bang, not a Whimper: Pricking Germany’s “Stock Market Bubble” in 1927 and the Slide into Depression HANS-JOACHIM VOTH In May 1927, the German central bank intervened indirectly to reduce lending to equity investors. The crash that followed ended the only stock market boom during Germany’s relative stabilization 1924–1928. The evidence strongly suggests that the German central bank under Hjalmar Schacht was wrong to be concerned about stock prices—there was no bubble. Also, the Reichsbank was mistaken in its belief that a fall in the market would reduce the importance of short-term foreign borrowing and improve conditions in the money market. The misguided intervention had important real effects. Investment suffered, helping to tip Germany into depression. uring November and December 1928, the American economist James DW. Angell was conducting fieldwork for his book on the German econ- omy. Visiting more than 50 factories and mines in the process, he came away deeply impressed by the prosperity and dynamism he encountered: “[O]nly six years after her utter collapse, Germany is once again one of the great industrial nations . and she is rapidly increasing her power. It is one of the most spectacular recoveries in the world’s entire economic history.”1 From the ashes of hyperinflation, the country had apparently turned itself into one of continental Europe’s great success stories. Inflation was low and stable, and the prewar exchange rate vis-à-vis the dollar had successfully been restored. Employment was rising rapidly, export volumes were surging, and labor productivity was increasing at twice the prewar rate.2 The image of prosperity that captivated Angell was in many ways a final flourish, followed by a rapid downturn that had already begun before his visit.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cliometrics of Academic Chairs. Scientific Knowledge and Economic Growth: the Evidence Across the Italian Regions 1900-19591
    THE CLIOMETRICS OF ACADEMIC CHAIRS. SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE EVIDENCE ACROSS THE ITALIAN REGIONS 1900-19591 Cristiano Antonelli, Dipartimento di Economia, Università di Torino & Collegio Carlo Alberto (BRICK); Nicola Crepax, Compagnia San Paolo; Università Bocconi & Università del Piemonte Orientale; Claudio Fassio, Dipartimento di Economia, Università di Torino & Collegio Carlo Alberto (BRICK). ABSTRACT. The analysis of the evolution of the academic chairs of an academic system is a promising area of investigation. The exploration of the evolution of the size and the disciplinary composition of the stock of academic chairs in Italy in the years 1900-1959 provides an opportunity to understand the contribution of scientific knowledge to economic growth. The basic assumption is that knowledge is not a homogeneous activity, but rather a bundle of highly differentiated disciplines that have different characteristics both in terms of generation and exploitation that bear a differentiated impact on economic growth. Advances in scientific knowledge are likely to have a direct, positive effect on economic growth according to their fungibility, appropriability and complementarity with other sources of technological knowledge and hence exploitation conditions. Advances in scientific knowledge that can be converted into technological knowledge with high levels of fungibility, appropriability and complementarity have a higher chance to affect economic growth. The econometric analysis confirms that advances in engineering and chemistry, as proxied by the number of chairs, had much a stronger effect on economic growth than in other scientific fields. These results have important implications for research policy as they highlight the differences in the economic effects of academic disciplines. KEY WORDS: ACADEMIC CHAIRS, TYPES OF KNOWLEDGE, KNOWLEDGE FUNGIBILITY, KNOWLEDGE EXPLOITATION, KNOWLEDGE EXTERNALITIES OF KNOWLEDGE TYPES.
    [Show full text]
  • Cliometrics and the Evolution of Human Capital Claude Diebolt, Roger Fouquet, Ralph Hippe
    Cliometrics and the Evolution of Human Capital Claude Diebolt, Roger Fouquet, Ralph Hippe To cite this version: Claude Diebolt, Roger Fouquet, Ralph Hippe. Cliometrics and the Evolution of Human Capital. Kouli Y., Pawlowsky P., Hertwig M. Wissensökonomie und Digitalisierung. Geschichte und Perspektiven, Springer VS, pp.11-32, 2020, 978-3-658-22332-8. 10.1007/978-3-658-22333-5_2. hal-02920429 HAL Id: hal-02920429 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-02920429 Submitted on 26 Aug 2020 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Cliometrics and the Evolution of Human Capital Claude Diebolt1, Roger Fouquet2 and Ralph Hippe3 Abstract Human capital has been seen to be a key factor for current and future economic growth. In a broader sense, it appears that we are moving towards a knowledge economy driven by human capital, technological progress and digitalization. However, although this evolution may be a new trend, similar developments have occurred in history before. In line with this reasoning, the scholarly field of cliometrics has received ever more attention during the last years. In consequence, this paper presents the foundations of cliometrics, and provides insights into the basic conceptual framework and evolution of human capital during the last centuries.
    [Show full text]
  • 8 World Congress of Cliometrics
    8th World Congress of Cliometrics July 4-7, 2017 Strasbourg, France Information, Schedule, and Abstracts Register to attend at: http://www.cliometrie.org/en/conferences/world-congress-of-cliometrics World Congress Information and Abstracts -- 1 Sponsors of the 8th World Congress of Cliometrics The Cliometric Society The National Science Foundation (United States) The University of Strasbourg World Congress Information and Abstracts -- 2 University of Hawaii Economic Research Organization Centre national de la recherche scientifique World Congress Information and Abstracts -- 3 World Congress Information and Abstracts -- 4 World Congress Information and Abstracts -- 5 GLOCREd is a Research Network of Eight R&D Projects (Sponsored by Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness) World Congress Information and Abstracts -- 21 The 8th World Congress of Cliometrics Organization, Program and Administration Congress Organizers Claude Diebolt, CNRS and University of Strasbourg Michael Haupert, University of Wisconsin, La Crosse Sumner La Croix, University of Hawaii Carolyn Moehling, Rutgers University Program Committee Claude Diebolt, CNRS and University of Strasbourg Christopher Hanes, Binghamton University Chulhee Lee, Seoul National University Carolyn Moehling, Rutgers University Cormac Ó Gráda, University College Dublin Tirthankar Roy, London School of Economics Susan Wolcott, Binghamton University Local Arrangements Committee Géraldine Del Fabbro, University of Strasbourg Claude Diebolt, CNRS and University of Strasbourg Ralph Hippe,
    [Show full text]