<<

COMPETITIVE MARKETS.

(Partial Equilibrium Analysis) Consider an with:

I , i =1,...I.

J firms, j =1,...J.

L , l =1,...L. Initial endowment of good l in the economy: ω 0. l ≥

Consumer i’s:

L Consumption set Xi R . ⊂

Utility function: ui : Xi R. →

L Production technology of firm j : Yj R . ⊂ y Y is a production vector y =(y , ...y ) j ∈ j j 1j Lj ∈ RL,j =1,...J.

Total (net) availability of good l in the economy: ωl + J j=1 ylj,l =1, ....L. P Pareto Optimality.

Definition. An economic allocation (x1, ..., xI,y1,...yJ) is a specification of a consumption vector x X for i ∈ i each i =1,...I,and a production vector y j ∈ Yj for each firm j =1....J.

The allocation is feasible if I J x ω + y for l =1,...L. li ≤ l lj iX=1 jX=1 Definition. A feasible allocation (x1,...,xI,y1,...yJ) is Pareto optimal (or, Pareto efficient) if there is no other feasible allocation (x10 ,...,xI0 ,y10 ,...yJ0 ) such that u (x ) u (x ) for all i =1,...I, i i0 ≥ i i and

ui(xi0) >ui(xi) for some i =1, ...I. Competitive Equilibria. Competitive economy: initial endowments and technological possibilities (firms) are owned by consumers.

Consumer i initially owns ω 0 of good l, ,l = li ≥ 1,...L,where I ωli = ωl. iX=1

Initial enowment vector of consumer i:

ωi =(ω1i, ...., ωLi).

In addition each consumer i owns a share θij of firm j giving her a share θij of the profits of firm j, j =1,...J. I θij =1. iX=1 Amarketexistsforallgoods.

All consumers and producers act as takers i.e., as- sume that market are unaffected by their actions.

Denote vector of prices: p =(p1,...pL). Definition. The allocation (x1∗, ..., xI∗,y1∗, ...yJ∗) and a price vector p RL constitute a competitive (or, Wal- ∗ ∈ + rasian) equilibrium if the following conditions are satis- fied:

(i) Profit maximization: For each firm j, yj∗ solves

max (p∗yj). y Y j∈ j

(ii) maximization: For each consumer i, xi∗ solves

max ui(xi) s.t. J p x p ω + θ (p y ). ∗ i ≤ ∗ i ij ∗ j∗ jX=1

(iii) Market clearing: For each good, l =1,...L,

I J xli∗ = ωl + ylj∗ . iX=1 jX=1 Sometimes we permit excess in equilibrium with price of the good being zero; assuming free disposal.

If goods are "desirable", for example if is always strictly positive, then this possibility is ruled out. Note: if p∗ >> 0 and (x1∗,...,xI∗,y1∗,...yJ∗) is a competi- tive equilibrium then so does the allocation (x1∗, ..., xI∗,y1∗,...yJ∗) and price vector αp∗ for any α>0.

So, we can always normalize prices without loss of gen- erality. Lemma. If the allocation (x1,...,xI,y1,...yJ) and price vector p>>0 satisfy the market clearing condition (iii) for all goods l = k, and if every consumer’s budget con- 6 straint is satisfied with equality so that J pxi = pωi + θij(pyj), for all i =1...I, (1) jX=1 then the market for good k also clears (i.e., (iii) holds for l = k). Proof. Adding (1) over i =1...L we get

I J p[ (x ω ( θ y ))] = 0 i − i − ij j iX=1 jX=1 so that L I I J p ( x ω θ y )=0 l li − l − ij lj lX=1 iX=1 iX=1 jX=1 i.e., L I J p ( x ω y )=0 l li − l − lj lX=1 iX=1 jX=1 or, I J I J pl( xli ωl ylj)= pk( xki ωk ykj) l=k i=1 − −j=1 − i=1 − −j=1 X6 X X X X and as the left hand side is zero, the RHS is zero and since pk > 0, we have I J ( x ω y )=0. ki − k − kj iX=1 jX=1 Partial Equilibrium Analysis.

Analysis of market for one (or several) goods that form a small part of the economy. Marshall (1920): consider one good that accounts for small fraction of consumer’s total expenditure.

The wealth (or ) effect on the for the good can be negligible.

Substitution effect of change in the price of the good is dispersed among all goods and so prices of other goods are approximately unaffected.

So, for the analysis of this market, we can take prices of all other goods as fixed.

Expenditure on all other goods taken to be a composite commodity - the numeraire. The Basic Quasi-linear Model:

Consumers i =1,...I.

Two commodities: good l and the numeraire. xi : consumer i0s consumption of good l. mi : consumer i0s consumption of the numeraire (i.e., expenditure on all other goods).

Consumption set of consumer i : R R+. ×

(Allow negative consumption of the numeraire good - "borrowing" - assumption avoids dealing with corner so- lution). Utility function:

ui(mi,xi)=mi + φi(xi),i=1, ...., I

Assume:

φi(.) is bounded above, twice continuously differentiable,

φi(0) = 0,

φ (x ) > 0,φ”(x ) < 0, x 0. i0 i i i ∀ i ≥

Quasi-linear formulation: no wealth effect. Normalize price of the numeraire good to equal 1.

Let p be the price (relative price) of good l,

Then, one can think of φi(xi) as measuring utility in terms of the numeraire good .

Firm j =1,...J, produces qj units of good l using (at least) amount cj(qj) of the numeraire good. cj(qj):"cost function" of firm j.

Technology of firm j:

Y = ( z ,q ):q 0,z c (q ) . j { − j j j ≥ j ≥ j j } Assume: cj : R+ R+ is twice differentiable. → c (q ) > 0 and c”(q ) 0 at all q 0. j0 j j j ≥ j ≥

[Think of cj(qj) as derived from a cost minimization problem with fixed input prices.]

Non-decreasing marginal (allows for constant and decreasing ).

Also continuity of cj at 0 rules out any fixed cost that is not sunk

(cost can be avoided by producing zero). Initial endowment: No initial endowment of good l.

Consumer i’s initial endowment of the numeraire good : ωmi > 0.

Let I ωm = ωmi iX=1 be the total endowment of the numeraire good in the economy. Competitive Equilibrium:

Profitmax.

Given equilibrium price p∗ for good l, firm j’s equilibrium output qj∗ solves

max[p∗qj cj(qj)] q 0 − j≥ Necessary and sufficient first order condition:

p c (q ), if q =0 (2) ∗ ≤ j0 j∗ j∗ = cj0 (qj∗), if qj∗ > 0. (3) Utility max.

Given p∗ and the solution to the firms’ profit maximiza- tion problems, consumer i’s equilibrium consumption (mi∗,xi∗) solves:

max [mi + φi(xi)] mi R,xi R+ s.t.∈ ∈ J m + p x ω + θ (p q c (q )) i ∗ i ≤ mi ij ∗ j∗ − j j∗ jX=1 Budget constraint holds with equality in any solution to the above problem. Rewrite the problem without of loss of generality as one of choosing only the consumption of good l: J max [ωmi + θij(p∗qj∗ cj(qj∗)) p∗xi + φi(xi)] xi R+ − − ∈ jX=1 or equivalently, xi∗ must solve

max[φi(xi) p∗xi] xi 0 − ≥ and mi∗ is determined by J m = ω + θ (p q c (q )) p x . i∗ mi ij ∗ j∗ − j j∗ − ∗ i∗ jX=1 A necessary and sufficient first order condition:

p φ (x ), if x =0, (4) ∗ ≥ i0 i∗ i∗ = φi0(xi∗), if xi∗ > 0. (5) Thus, an equilibrium allocation is characterized fully by a price p∗ of good l and the vector (x1∗, ...., xI∗,q1∗,...,qJ∗) of consumption and production of good l. Finally, market clearing for good l requires: I J xi∗ = qj∗. (6) iX=1 jX=1 Proposition: The allocation (x1∗, ...., xI∗,q1∗, ..., qJ∗) and price p∗ constitutes a competitive equilibrium if and only if.

p c (q ), if q =0 ∗ ≤ j0 j∗ j∗ = cj0 (qj∗), if qj∗ > 0,j =1, ....J

p φ (x ), if x =0, ∗ ≥ i0 i∗ i∗ = φi0(xi∗), if xi∗ > 0,.i=1,...I

I J xi∗= qj∗. iX=1 jX=1

The above (I+J+1) conditions determine the (I+J+1) equilibrium values (x1∗, ...., xI∗,q1∗, ..., qJ∗, p∗).

The equilibrium allocation and price of good l are entirely independent of the of initial endowments and ownership shares of firms. Observe: since φ (x ) > 0, x 0, it follows that the i0 i ∀ i ≥ equilibrium price p∗ > 0.

Assume:

max φi0(0) > min cj0 (0). i j

Then, in equilibrium, total consumption and production I J of good l : xi∗= qj∗ > 0. iX=1 jX=1

[If all consumers consume 0 and all firms produce 0,then

c (0) p φ (0),i=1,...I,j =1,...J, j0 ≥ ∗ ≥ i0 so that

max φi0(0) min cj0 (0), i ≤ j a contradiction.] One can derive the equilibrium through traditional Mar- shallian demand-supply analysis. Demand :

For any p, each consumer’s first order condition:

p φ (x ), if x =0, ≥ i0 i i = φi0(xi), if xi > 0.

Note φi0 is a continuous and strictly decreasing function on R+ with range [0,φi0(0)].

Individual Walrasian demand function of consumer i :

xi(p)=0,p φi0(0), 1≥ = φ0− (p),p (0,φ (0). i ∈ i0

Note individual demand xi(p) is independent of wealth, continuous & non-increasing in p and strictly decreasing in p on (0,φi0(0)). Aggregate (market) demand for good l:

I x(p)= xi(p) iX=1

- independent of endowment & the distribution of endow- ments,

- continuous & non-increasing in p and

- strictly decreasing in p on (0, maxi φi0(0)).

Note that individual and aggregate demand is infinite at zero price.

Also, aggregate demand is zero for p max φ (0). ≥ i i0 Supply:

For any p, firm j0sprofit max yields the following first order condition:

p c (q ), if q =0 ≤ j0 j j = cj0 (qj), if qj > 0.

If p

Suppose cj is strictly convex (upward sloping marginal cost) and c (q) as q . j0 →∞ →∞

Then, for each p>cj0 (0), there is a unique qj such that p = cj0 (qj). The firm’s supply curve in that case:

q (p)=0,p c (0), j ≤ j0 1 = cj0− (p),p>cj0 (0). qj(p) is

- continuous and non-decreasing in p &

- strictly increasing for p>cj0 (0). The aggregate (market) supply curve is given by:

J q(p)= qj(p). jX=1

Note that q(p)=0for p min c (0). ≤ j j0

For p>minj cj0 (0),q(p) is strictly positive, strictly in- creasing and continuous. The market equilibrium price p∗ is given by the point where aggregate demand and supply intersect i.e.,

x(p ) q(p )=0 (7) ∗ − ∗ Let z(p)=x(p) q(p). Then, − z(p)=x(p) > 0,p min cj0 (0) ≤ j = q(p) < 0,p max φi0(0). − ≥ i z(p) is continuous and strictly decreasing in p on (minj cj0 (0), max

Unique p (min c (0), max φ (0)), such that z(p )= ∗ ∈ j j0 i i0 ∗ 0 i.e.,(7) holds. The equilibrium allocation is given by setting xi∗ = xi(p∗),i= 1,...I,qj∗ = qj(p∗),j =1,...J.

If cj is convex but not strictly convex (for example, lin- ear), there may not be unique solution to the profitmax problem and so qj(p) is a correspondence (upper hemi- continuous, using Maximum Theorem).

Similar analysis goes through with more technical argu- ments. Important case: Constant returns to scale. cj(qj)=cjqj where cj > 0 is the constant average as well as marginal cost ("unit cost").

Firm j’s supply function

qj(p)=0,pc . ∞ j

The aggregate supply is infinite (not well defined as a real number) for p>cj.

If all firms have constant returns to scale technology with cost functions cj(qj)=cjqj,j =1,...J, then the unique equilibrium price p∗ =minj cj. Only firms with the minimum unit cost can produce in equilibrium (such firms are indifferent between all levels of output at that price).

The total quantity of good l produced and consumed is given by the aggregate demand function and equals x(p∗).

If there are multiple firms with the minimum unit cost, the way the total quantity demanded x(p∗) is produced across these firms is not uniquely determined. Recall, supply: J q(p)= qj(p) jX=1 where

1 q (p)=c0− (p), j such that q (p) > 0. j j ∀ j

For any y>0, the inverse of the aggregate supply func- 1 tion given by q− (y) indicates the equalized marginal 1 cost of all firms that produce this output: q− (y) is the industry’s marginal cost curve. Define the industry’s aggregate cost of producing any level of total output y by: J C(y)= min cj(qj) qj,j=1,...J jX=1 J s.t. q = y, q 0,j =1,..J. j j ≥ jX=1

Lagrangean:

J J L(q1, ....q ,λ)= c (q )+λ(y q ) J j j − j jX=1 jX=1 First order necessary and sufficient conditions:

cj0 (qj)=λ, qj > 0 λ, qj =0 b ≥ b b

-allfirms that produce strictly positive output, marginal cost is equalized to λ

-all firms that produce zero output, marginal cost at zero is no larger than λ

For any p,lettingλ = p, we can see that qj = qj(p),j = 1,...J, must minimize industry’s aggregate cost of pro- J b ducing y = qj(p). jX=1 Further, using envelope theorem:

C0(y)=λ = c (q ), j such that q > 0. j0 j ∀ j J b b Thus, industry’s marginal cost of producing y = qj(p) jX=1 is given by cj0 (qj(p)), for all j such that qj(p) > 0 i.e., 1 q− (y), the inverse aggregate supply curve. Therefore, q

C(q)=C(0) + C0(y)dy Z0 q 1 = C(0) + q− (y)dy Z0 so that

q q 1(y)dy = C(q) C(0) − − Z0

The area under the aggregate supply curve is equal to the (minimized) total variable cost of the industry (i.e., the total cost excluding the ).

The area under individual supply curve is the total vari- able cost of the firm. Recall, I x(p)= xi(p) iX=1 where

1 x (p)=φ0− (p), i such that x (p) > 0. i i ∀ i

1 Let P (y)=x− (y) be the inverse aggregate demand function.

Then, for any y, P(y)=φ (x (P (y))), i such that i0 i ∀ xi(p) > 0.

In other words, P (y) represents the marginal benefitfrom consumption of good l toaconsumerthatconsumes strictly positive quantity when the price is P (y) and total quantity y is consumed.

So, P (y) represents the marginal benefittosocietyfrom total consumption of amount y. For any y>0, define the (maximum) social benefitfrom total consumption of amount y :

B(y)= max[φi(xi)] x ,i 1,..I i − I s.t. x = y, x 0,i=1,..I. i i ≥ iX=1 Define Lagrangean I I L(x1, ....x ,μ)= (φ (x )) + μ(y x ) I i i − i iX=1 iX=1 First order necessary and sufficient conditions:

φi0(xi)=μ, xi > 0 μ, xi =0 b ≤ b so that for all consumers that consumeb strictly positive amount of good l, marginal utility is equalized to μ and for all consumers that consume zero amount, marginal utility at zero does not exceed μ.

For any p, letting μ = p, we can see that xi = xi(p),i= 1,...I, must maximize society’s benefitfromconsuming I b y = xi(p). jX=1 Further, using envelope theorem:

B0(y)=μ = φ (x ), i such that x > 0. i0 i ∀ i Thus, society’s marginal benefitfromconsumingy = I b b x (p) is given by φ (x (p)), i such that x (p) > 0 i i0 i ∀ i jX=1 (the height of the individual demand curves at xi(p)) i.e., P (y), the inverse aggregate demand curve.

Therefore, (using B(0) = 0) x B(x)= B0(y)dy Z0 x = P (y)dy Z0 The area under the aggregate demand curve is equal to the (maximum) social benefit from consumption of good l.

The area under individual demand curve is the total ben- efit to the individual consumer. To sum up:

1. Profit maximization by price taking firms ensures that the total output produced by the industry at any price minimizes the industry’s cost of producing this amount (i.e., market distributes total output across firms opti- mally).

2. Utility maximization by price taking consumers en- sures that the total consumption in society is distributed across consumers so as to maximize the total benefitto society (optimal distribution of consumption). 3. The height of the aggregate supply curve indicates the industry’s marginal cost of production.

The area under the aggregate (inverse) supply curve in- dicates the industry’s total variable cost.

4. The height of the aggregate demand curve indicates the society’s marginal benefit from consumption.

The area under the aggregate (inverse) demand curve in- dicates society’s total benefit from consumption of good l. Pareto Optimality & Competitive Equilibrium.

Fix the consumption and the production levels of good l at (x1, ...., xI, q1, ..., qJ) where I J xi= qj. iX=1 jX=1 The total amount of the numeraire available for distrib- ution amount consumers is J ωm c (q ). − j j jX=1 Quasilinear utility: transferable utility.

Transferring numeraire good across consumers in various ways one can generate a utility possibility set: I I J (u1,u2,...,u ): u φ (x )+ωm c (q ) { I i ≤ i i − j j iX=1 iX=1 jX=1

The right hand side of the inequality defining the set is a constant (given (x1, ...., xI, q1,...,qJ)).

So, the frontier of this utility possibility set is a hyperplane with normal vector (1, 1, ..., 1).

Changing the consumption and production levels of good l i.e., the vector (x1, ...., xI, q1,...,qJ) shifts the frontier of the utility possibility set in a parallel fashion. The frontier moves outward or inward according to whether I J φ (x )+ωm c (q ) i i − j j iX=1 jX=1 increases or decreases when we change (x1, ...., xI, q1, ..., qJ).

As long as the frontier can be shifted outwards by change in the vector (x1, ...., xI, q1, ..., qJ) the original situation is not Pareto optimal. Thus, every Pareto optimal allocation must involve con- sumption and production profile (x1, .....xI, y1,...,yJ) for good l so as to shift the frontier as far out as possible e e e e i.e., (x1, .....xI, y1,...,yJ) solves I J e e e e max [ φi(xi) cj(qj)] (x ,...,x ) 0 − 1 I ≥ i=1 j=1 (q1,....qJ) 0 X X s.t. ≥ I J xi = qj iX=1 jX=1 The maximand I J [ φ (x ) c (q )] i i − j j iX=1 jX=1 is often called the Marshallian aggregate surplus (or total surplus).

It measures the net benefit to society from producing and consuming good l. There exists a solution to the surplus maximization prob- lem.

While there are a continuum of Pareto optimal allocations corresponding to points on the highest utility possibility frontier, they all must involve a consumption and pro- duction vector for good l such as (x1, .....xI, y1,...,yJ) which solves the surplus max problem. e e e e In particular, if the solution to the surplus max problem is unique (for example, when cj is strictly convex):

- all Pareto optimal allocations must involve exactly the same production and consumption vector for good l

- the only difference in various Pareto optimal alloca- tions would arise from differences in distribution of the numeraire good

(that can transfer utility from one to another unit for unit). Lagrangean: I J J I L = φ (x ) c (q )+μ[ q x ] i i − j j j − i iX=1 jX=1 jX=1 iX=1 First order necessary and sufficient condition (maximand is concave, feasible set is convex):

μ c (q ), if q =0 ≤ j0 j j = cj0 (qj), if qj > 0,j =1, ...J. e e e e

φ (x ) μ, if x =0, i0 i ≤ i = μ, if xi =0,i=1, ...I e e J e I qj = xi jX=1 iX=1 e e Setting μ = p∗, we see that these conditions are satisfied by the production and consumption profile for good l in any competitive equilibrium allocation. The First Fundamental Theorem of welfare Eco- nomics.

Proposition.

If the price p∗ and the allocation (x1∗, ...., xI∗,q1∗,...,qJ∗) constitutes a competitive equilibrium, then this allocation is Pareto optimal. Conversely, consider any Pareto optimal allocation.

The production and consumption levels of good l in any such allocation must solve the surplus max problem and setting p = μ we can check that the solution to surplus max (x1, .....xI, y1, ..., yJ) is a competitive equilibrium.

e e e e Consider this competitive equilibrium.

The price, the equilibrium consumption and production of good l and the profits of firms are unaffected by any transfer of the numeraire good from one agent to another.

Transferring the numeraire good from one agent to an- other changes the utility of the agents by exactly the amount of the transfer. Therefore, can always generate the exact profile of util- ities and numeraire good consumption in the candidate Pareto optimal allocation by transferring numeraire good from one agent to another.

CanattainanypointontheParetooptimalboundaryof the utility possibility set by transferring numeraire good across consumers. The Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Eco- nomics.

Proposition.

For any Pareto optimal levels of utility (u1∗,...,uI∗), there are transfers of the numeraire commodity (T1, ....TI) sat- I isfying i=1 Ti =0such that a competitive equilibrium reachedP from the endowments (ωm1+T1, ...., ωmI +Ti) yields precisely the (u1∗,...,uI∗).

Convex structure important for this result. Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium.

Social welfare function: assigns social welfare value (real number) to each profile of utility levels (u1,u2,...uI):

W (u1,u2,...uI)

(Utilitarian welfare).

Assume: W is strongly monotonic in its arguments. For any given consumption and production levels of good l, (x1,...xI,q1, ..., qJ), where I J xi= qj, iX=1 jX=1 the utility vectors that are attainable are given by: I I J (u1,u2,...,u ): u φ (x )+ωm c (q ) . { I i ≤ i i − j j } iX=1 iX=1 jX=1 As the boundary of this set expands, the maximum social welfare W attainable on this set (through redistribution of the numeraire good) increases (strictly). Thus,

*For any strongly monotonic social welfare function W, a change in the consumption and production of good l leads to an increase in (the maximum attainable) social welfare if and only if it increases the Marshallian surplus:

I J S(x1,...x ,q1, ...q )=[ φ (x ) c (q )]. I J i i − j j iX=1 jX=1 Thus, social welfare analysis of changes in the consump- tion and production of good l can be carried out exclu- sively in terms of the Marshallian surplus.

Indeed, as we have seen, Pareto efficiency also requires that the consumption and production of good l must satisfy

max S(x1,...xI,q1,...qJ) (x1,...,x ) 0 I ≥ (q1,....q ) 0 J ≥ I J s.t. xi= qj. iX=1 jX=1 Consider a consumption and production vector of good I l, (x1,...xI, q1, ...qJ) such that for y = xi iX=1 b b b b b b (i) (x1, ...xI) solves: I b b max [ φi(xi)] xi,i 1,..I − iX=1 I s.t. x = y, x 0,i=1,..I. i i ≥ iX=1 b

(ii) (q1, ...qJ) solves J b b min cj(qj) qj,j=1,...J jX=1 J s.t. q = y, q 0,j =1,..J. j j ≥ jX=1 b We have seen that:

φ (x )=P (y)=B (y), i such that x > 0 i0 i 0 ∀ i b b b b

c (q )=C (y), j such that q > 0, j0 j 0 ∀ j where P is theb inverse aggregateb demandb function, B0(.) is the industry marginal benefitandC0(.) is the industry marginal cost (or the aggregate inverse supply function). I J S(x1,...x , q1,...q )=[ φ (x ) c (q )] I J i i − j j iX=1 jX=1 b b b b = B(y) bC(y) b − y y b b = B0(y)dy C(0) C0(y)dy b − − b Z0 Z0 y y

= P (y)dy C0(y)dy C(0) b − b − Z0 Z0 y

=[[P (y) C0(y)]dy] S(0) b − − Z0 Note: y

[ [P (y) C0(y)]dy] b − Z0 is the area between the aggregate demand and supply surves and can be written as : y

[ [P (y) C0(y)]dy] b − Z0 y =[[P (y) yP(y)] + [yP(y) (C(y) C(0))] b − − − Z0 = CS(P (y)) +b PSb(P (y))b b b where CS(p) andb PS(p) denoteb the aggregate consumer and producer surplus generated in a (hypothetical) mar- ket with price taking consumers and producers at price market price p. Therefore, in partial equilibrium analysis, social welfare maximization, Marshallian surplus maximization and Pareto efficiency are roughly equivalent in their implication for the production and consumption of "the good" and even- tually reduce to maximization of CS + PS. y

It is easy to see that [ [P (y) C0(y)]dy] is maximized b − Z0 at the output where:

P (y∗)=C0(y∗) i.e., social marginal benefit equates industry’s marginal cost. As C0(y) is inverse aggregate supply curve, this is also the aggregate output consumed and produced in a com- petitive equilibrium (supply=demand).

Thus, competitive equilibrium outcome is equivalent to Marshallian surplus maximization. Allofthisassumesnoexternalitiesorotherdistortions (taxes, subsidies etc).

Welfarelossduetodistortionsismeasuredbythechange in CS +PS i.e., the area between aggregate demand and the supply (or industry MC curve).

Sometmes, called . Example. Welfare loss due to a distortionary tax (in a competitive market).

Sales tax on good l: t per unit paid by consumers.

Tax revenue returned to consumers through lump sum transfer (non distortionary spending). Let (x1∗(t), ..., xI∗(t),q1∗(t),...,qJ∗(t)) and p∗(t) be the competitive equilibrium allocation and price given tax rate t.

FOC:

φi0(xi∗(t)) = p∗(t)+t,foralli such that xi∗(t) > 0.

cj0 (qj∗(t)) = p∗(t), for all j such that xj∗(t) > 0. Let I x∗(t)=x(p∗(t)+t)= xi∗(t). iX=1

Market clearing:

x(p∗(t)+t)=q(p∗(t)) * Easy to check that (over the range where a strictly positive quantity is traded) p∗(t) is strictly decreasing in t and that (p∗(t)+t) is strictly increasing in t. x∗(t) is strictly decreasing in t (aslongasitisstrictly positice) and

x∗(t) 0.

Let S∗(t)=S(x1∗(t), ..., xI∗(t),q1∗(t),...,qJ∗(t)).

We have that

x∗(t) S (t)=[ [P (y) C (y)]dy] S(0) ∗ − 0 − Z0 W elfare change = S (t) S (0) ∗ − ∗ x∗(t) = [P (y) C0(y)]dy Z − x∗(0) which is negative since x∗(t) C (y) for all y [0,x (0)). 0 ∈ ∗