Genoeconomics: a Primer and Progress Report

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Genoeconomics: a Primer and Progress Report Genoeconomics: A Primer and Progress Report Daniel J. Benjamin CESR and Economics Department, USC Berkeley Institute for Transparency in the Social Sciences • 9 June 2017 Main Collaborators Jonathan Beauchamp (University of Toronto) David Cesarini (New York University) Christopher Chabris (Geisinger Health Systems) Tõnu Esko (University of Tartu) Magnus Johanesson (Stockholm School of Economics) Philipp Koellinger (VU Amsterdam) David Laibson (Harvard University) James Lee (University of Minnesota) Aysu Okbay (VU Amsterdam) Patrick Turley (Harvard University) Peter Visscher (University of Queensland) We gratefully acknowledge NIH’s NIA and OBSSR, NSF, the Ragnar Söderberg Foundation, and the Swedish Research Council for financial support! Some Promises for Social Science 1. Biological mechanisms for behavior § Complementary with neuroeconomics. 2. Non-genetic empirical work A. Empirical proxies for structural parameters (preferences, abilities, internal prod’n fns.) B. Instrumental variables C. Control variables 3. Studying genetic heterogeneity and targeting interventions § E.g., older individuals with at-risk cognitive health. Outline 1. Super Quick Genetics Primer 2. Traditional Candidate-Genes Studies 3. The Power Problem 4. Genome-Wide Association Studies 5. Example: Educational Attainment Genetics Primer • Human DNA is a sequence of ~3 billion pairs of nucleotide molecules (spread across 23 chromosomes). • This human genome has 20,000-25,000 subsequences called genes. • Genes provide instructions for building proteins that in turn affect body function. • At the vast majority of locations, there is no variation in nucleotides across individuals. • Single-nucleotide polymorphisms (SNPs): Nucleotides where individuals differ (a small % of all nucleotides). (There are also other types of variation.) • At vast majority of SNP locations, there are only 2 possible nucleotides: – major allele (more common) – minor allele (less common). • From each parent, may inherit either allele; SNP unaffected by which received from whom. • Genotype for each SNP: #minor alleles (0,1,2). Note. Genotyping costs from multiple sources. Sequencing costs from NIH (genome.gov/sequencingcosts). Outline 1. Super Quick Genetics Primer 2. Traditional Candidate-Genes Studies 3. The Power Problem 4. Genome-Wide Association Studies 5. Example: Educational Attainment Traditional Candidate-Gene Study • Specify ex ante hypotheses about small set of � SNPs (often � = 1) based on believed biological function. • Estimate + �% = �'�%' + �%�' + �%'. • Set significance threshold a = .05 / K. • Virtually all existing work in social-science genetics. (Reviews: Ebstein, Israel, Chew, Zhong, and Knafo, 2010; Beauchamp et al., 2011; Benjamin et al., 2012) • Eminently reasonable, and has worked when hypotheses are direct. (e.g., APOE and Alzheimer’s disease) • But in social-science genetics, replication record has been inconsistent. – My own Icelandic saga. – Example: candidate genes for cognitive function. Pooled estimates (11 SNPs + APOE) • Eminently reasonable, and has worked when hypotheses are direct. (e.g., APOE/Alzheimer’s) • But in social-science genetics, replication record has been inconsistent. – My own Icelandic saga. – Example: candidate genes for cognitive function. • Problem with premise: assumed a few genes have large effects (detectable with N ≈ 100 to 3,000). – But we now know that effects of any particular genetic variant likely to be very small. – Having plausible hypotheses lent spurious credibility to statistically suspicious findings. The Three Big Problems 1. Multiple hypothesis testing – Typically many measured loci in the dataset. – Typically several phenotypes. – Many possible specifications/controls. 2. Population stratification – Genotype is correlated with ancestry, which is correlated with environmental factors. 3. Low power – Is N large enough, given true effect size bj and significance threshold (and prior)? Outline 1. Super Quick Genetics Primer 2. Traditional Candidate-Genes Studies 3. The Power Problem 4. Genome-Wide Association Studies 5. Example: Educational Attainment The Power Problem • Existing studies reporting significant gene-behavior associations usually had samples in the range 50 to 3000. (Ebstein et al., 2010; Beauchamp et al., 2011; Benjamin et al., 2012) • Implicit assumption: SNPs have explanatory power R2 ≥ 2%. – But would be found in N ≈ 60,000 GWASs of cognitive performance (Davies et al., 2015) and personality (De Moor et al., 2015). • Credible evidence from physical and medical literature: – Smoking and CHRNA3: R2 ≈ 0.5%. – BMI and FTO: R2 ≈ 0.3%. – Largest identified SNP for height: R2 ≈ 0.4%. • Credible evidence from GWAS for behavioral phenotypes: – Educational attainment: R2 ≈ 0.02%. – Depressive symptoms / neuroticism: R2 ≈ 0.04%. – Subjective well-being: R2 ≈ 0.02%. Calibration: Power Analysis Suppose: • � = 0.05 • R2 ≈ 0.02% • N = 3,000 What is power? 12%. Sample size for 80% power? 39,150. Bayesian Credibility (based on Wacholder et al., 2004; Ioannidis, 2005; Benjamin et al., 2012; Bayarri et al., 2016) Given signiFicant at α = .05, assuming eFFect size R2 = 0.02%. Sample size N = 100 N = 10,000 N = 100,000 (power = .05) (power = .29) (power = .99) Prior 0.1% 0.1% 0.6% 2% prob- 1% 1% 6% 17% ability 5% 5.2% 24% 51% 10% 10.4% 39% 69% Outline 1. Super Quick Genetics Primer 2. Traditional Candidate-Genes Studies 3. The Power Problem 4. Genome-Wide Association Studies 5. Example: Educational Attainment Genome-Wide Association Study (GWAS) • Atheoretical testing of all SNPs measured using modern technologies (~0.5-2.5M). – For polygenic traits, biological knowledge unlikely to pinpoint a few genes of large effect. • Set significance threshold a = 5 ´ 10-8 (since ~1M independent SNPs in genome). – Makes clear need for much larger samples. • Therefore, new research organization and culture: “Consortia” meta-analyze results from GWASs in many samples. – Coordinated “analysis plan” easy to preregister. Example: Schizophrenia Stefansson et al. (2009) Example: Schizophrenia Ripke et al. (2011) Example: Schizophrenia Ripke et al. (2014) Addressing the Problems 1. Multiple hypothesis testing (MHT) – All measured SNPs are tested. – Genome-wide significance threshold addresses. – (But with more large-scale GWAS data available, MHT may occur with phenotypes.) 2. Population stratification – Loosely speaking, can use the genome-wide data to estimate ancestry, then control for it. (Price et al., 2006) 3. Low power – Obtain large samples via consortia. Now at Genome-Wide Significance… (based on Wacholder et al., 2004; Ioannidis, 2005; Benjamin et al., 2012; Bayarri et al., 2016) Given signiFicant at α = 5 ´ 10-8, assuming eFFect size R2 = 0.02%. Sample size N = 100 N = 10,000 N = 100,000 (power = .00) (power = .00) (power = .16) Prior 0.1% 0.13% 36% 100% prob- 1% 1.3% 85% 100% ability 5% 7% 97% 100% 10% 13% 98% 100% These calculations make clear that in a world of tiny R2, we need large N. They also provide a Bayesian perspective for why we need stringent significance thresholds—not only for GWAS, but also for candidate-gene studies. 27 Outline 1. Super Quick Genetics Primer 2. Traditional Candidate-Genes Studies 3. The Power Problem 4. Genome-Wide Association Studies 5. Example: Educational Attainment The SSGAC • In 2011, David Cesarini, Philipp Koellinger, and I founded the Social Science Genetic Association Consortium (SSGAC). • What outcomes to study? – In tradeoff between larger sample and higher-quality measure, given plausible effect sizes, larger sample gives more power. (Chabris et al., 2013) Quality of Measure vs. Sample Size R2 vs. Sample Size (50% Power) 0.01 0.009 0.008 Rho=1 0.007 Rho=0.8 Rho=0.6 0.006 Rho=0.4 2 0.005 R Rho=0.2 0.004 0.003 0.002 0.001 0 0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 60,000 70,000 80,000 90,000 100,000 Sample Size The SSGAC • In 2011, David Cesarini, Philipp Koellinger, and I founded the Social Science Genetic Association Consortium (SSGAC). • What outcomes to study? – In tradeoff between larger sample and higher-quality measure, given plausible effect sizes, larger sample gives more power. (Chabris et al., 2013) • Proof-of-concept: education attainment, available in many medical datasets. EA1 • Discovery phase: 41 datasets with total sample size of N ≈ 100,000. – Each cohort ran GWAS of EduYears (years of schooling) and/or College (a binary indicator) according to preregistered analysis plan. – Uploaded GWAS results to a secure, central server. – Meta-analyzed GWAS results across cohorts to obtain overall GWAS coefficients and SEs. – One genome-wide significant association with EduYears and two with College. • Replication phase: 12 independent datasets with total sample size of N ≈ 25,000. – All three hits replicated at Bonferonni-adjusted 5% significance level. ! Effect size R2 ≈ 0.02% an order of magnitude smaller than for complex physical / medical traits. EA2 • 63 datasets with sample size of N = 293,723. • Similar preregistered analysis plan as EA1, except focused exclusively on EduYears (not College). • Found 74 approximately uncorrelated genome-wide significant SNPs. • After submission, first release of UK Biobank became available (N ≈ 110,000); used for replication. – Replication record somewhat better than expectation if all hits were true positive: • 72 out of the 74 lead SNPs have a consistent sign. • 52 are significant at the 5% level. • 7 reach genome-wide significance. EA3 (in progress) • Currently at N ≈ 770,000. • Essentially the same analysis plan as EA2. Transformation
Recommended publications
  • The Precision Medicine Issue Medicine Is Becoming Hyper
    The precision medicine issue Vol. 121 Nov/Dec $9.99 USD No. 6 2018 $10.99 CAD $2 million would save her life. The precision medicine issue Could you pay? Should you? Medicine is becoming hyper-personalized, hyper-accurate ... and hyper-unequal. p.38 The AIs taking over Curing cancer How to plan your from doctors with customized digital afterlife vaccines p.22 p.46 p.76 ND18_cover.indd 1 10/3/18 4:16 PM Artificial intelligence is here. Own what happens next. ND18 ETD19 Spread 16x10.875 D3.indd 2 9/28/18 10:59 AM March 25–26, 2019 St. egis Hotel San Francisco, CA Meet the people leading the next wave of intelligent technologies. Andrew Kathy Daphne Sergey Harry Anagnost Gong Koller Levine Shum President and Cofounder and Founder and Assistant Executive Vice CEO, Autodesk CEO, WafaGames CEO, Insitro Professor, EECS, President, UC Berkeley Microsoft Artifi cial Intelligence and Research Group EmTechDigital.com/2019 ND18 ETD19 Spread 16x10.875 D3.indd 3 9/28/18 10:59 AM 02 From the editor It’s been nearly two decades since the help meet the ballooning healthcare first human genome was sequenced. needs of an aging population. That achievement opened up the prom The problem? As medicine gets ise of drugs and treatments perfectly more personalized, it risks getting more tailored to each person’s DNA. But per unequal. Our cover story is Regalado’s sonalized or “precision” medicine has gripping and troubling account page always felt a bit like flying cars, sexbots, 38 of the parents who raise millions of or labgrown meat­one of those things dollars to finance genetherapy cures for we’re perpetually being promised but their children’s ultrarare diseases.
    [Show full text]
  • Daniel J. Benjamin (As of 10/4/2019)
    Daniel J. Benjamin (as of 10/4/2019) Contact Information University of Southern California Center for Economic and Social Research Dauterive Hall 635 Downey Way, Suite 301 Los Angeles, CA 90089-3332 Phone: 617-548-8948 Professional Experience: Professor (Research) of Economics, CESR, USC, 2019-present Associate Professor (Research) of Economics, CESR, USC, 2015-2019 Visiting Associate Professor (Research) of Economics, CESR, USC, 2014-2015 Associate Professor (with tenure), Economics Department, Cornell University, 2013-2015 Assistant Professor, Economics Department, Cornell University, 2007-2013 Visiting Research Fellow, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), 2011-2012 Research Associate, NBER, 2013-present Faculty Research Fellow, NBER, 2009-2013 Research Fellow, Research Center for Group Dynamics, Institute for Social Research, 2006-2017 Research Fellow, Population Studies Center, Institute for Social Research, 2006-2007 Graduate Studies: Ph.D., Economics, Harvard University, 2006 M.Sc., Mathematical Economics, London School of Economics, 2000 A.M., Statistics, Harvard University, 1999 Undergraduate Studies: A.B., Economics, Harvard University, summa cum laude, prize for best economics student, 1999 Honors, Scholarships, and Fellowships: 2013 Norwegian School of Economics Sandmo Junior Fellowship (prize for a “promising young economist”) 2012-2013 Cornell’s Institute for Social Science (ISS) Faculty Fellowship 2009-2012 ISS Theme Project Member: Judgment, Decision Making, and Social Behavior 2011-2012 NBER Visiting Fellowship
    [Show full text]
  • Why Is It Hard to Find Genes That Are Associated with Social Science Traits? Theoretical and Empirical Considerations
    “Why Is It Hard to Find Genes …” – p. 1 Why Is It Hard to Find Genes that are Associated with Social Science Traits? Theoretical and Empirical Considerations Christopher F. Chabris1†* James J. Lee2† Daniel J. Benjamin3 Jonathan P. Beauchamp4 Edward L. Glaeser4 Gregoire Borst2 Steven Pinker2 David I. Laibson4 1. Department of Psychology, Union College, Schenectady, NY, USA 2. Department of Psychology, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA 3. Department of Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY, USA 4. Department of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA † These authors contributed equally to the work. * Address correspondence to: Christopher F. Chabris Department of Psychology Union College 807 Union Street Schenectady, NY 12308 USA [email protected] “Why Is It Hard to Find Genes …” – p. 2 Abstract Though most behavioral traits are moderately to highly heritable, the genes that influence them are elusive: many published genetic associations fail to replicate. With physical traits like eye color and skin pigmentation, in contrast, several genes with large effects have been discovered and replicated. We draw on R.A. Fisher’s geometric model of adaptation to explain why traits of interest to behavioral scientists may have a genetic architecture featuring hundreds or thousands of alleles with tiny individual effects, rather than a few with large effects, and why such an architecture makes it difficult to find robust associations between traits and genes. In the absence of strong directional selection on a trait, alleles with large effect sizes will probably remain rare, and such a lack of strong directional selection is likely to characterize most traits currently of interest in social science.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics Without Borders
    ECONOMICS WITHOUT BORDERS Economic Research for European Policy Challenges Edited by Richard Blundell Estelle Cantillon Barbara Chizzolini Marc Ivaldi Wolfgang Leininger Ramon Marimon Laszlo Matyas (Lead Editor) and Frode Steen March 8, 2016 Cambridge University Press Contents List of illustrations page xii List of tables xiv Foreword xv 0 Introduction Blundell, Cantillon, Chizzolini, Ivaldi, Leininger, Ma- rimon, Matyas, and Steen 1 1 Innovation and Growth: The Schumpeterian Perspective Philippe Aghion and Ufuk Akcigit 30 1.1 Introduction 30 1.2 Looking for Growth Paradigms to Think about Growth Policy 32 1.2.1 The Neoclassical Growth Model 32 1.2.2 The AK Model 33 1.2.3 The Product-variety Model 33 1.2.4 The Schumpeterian Model 34 1.3 Some Main Applications and Extensions of Schumpeterian Growth Theory 36 1.3.1 Growth Meets IO 36 1.3.2 Schumpeterian Growth and Firm Dynamics 38 1.3.3 Growth Meets Development: Appropriate Institutions 40 1.3.4 Growth Meets Development: Firm Dynamics in Developing Countries 42 1.3.5 Growth and Unemployment 43 1.4 Enhancing Productivity Growth in Advanced Countries 45 1.4.1 Pillars of Innovation-led Growth 45 1.4.2 Competition Policy against Industrial Policy 45 1.4.3 Reforming the State 48 1.4.4 Macroeconomic Policy 49 iv Contents 1.4.5 Innovation, Inequality, and Social Mobility: Making Growth Inclusive 50 1.5 Technological Waves and the Debate on Secular Stagnation 53 1.5.1 The Debate 53 1.5.2 Historical Wave Patterns 54 1.6 Schumpeterian Insights into R&D Policy 56 1.6.1 R&D Policies and Firm Selection
    [Show full text]
  • Essays on Genetics and the Social Sciences Genoeconomics, Social-Science Genetics, Or Biological Economics
    413 AYSU OKBAY Evidence from behavior-genetic studies of twins, adoptees and other pairs of relatives shows that virtually all human traits, including economic preferences and behaviors, are at least moderately heritable. With increasing availability of genetic data, it is now becoming feasible to identify specific genetic variants associated with complex outcomes, thus blurring the disciplinary boundaries between biological and Essays on Genetics and social sciences. Building on these developments, this thesis explores questions at the intersection of economics and biology and thus contributes to an emerging field of research commonly referred to as: - Essays on Genetics and the Social Sciences OKBAY AYSU genoeconomics, social-science genetics, or biological economics. the Social Sciences The research described here identifies specific genetic variants robustly associated with a suite of complex outcomes – ranging from educational attainment, to subjective well-being, neuroticism and depression – and shows how these findings can be used, in conjunction with quasi-experimental research designs from economics, to conduct rigorous and well-powered investigations of the interactions between genes and environment. It illustrates some hard-won lessons about the relative merits of various research strategies that have been proposed for efforts to discover genetic associations with complex traits. Furthermore, it provides a framework for quantifying tradeoffs between outcome heterogeneity and sample-size in gene-discovery efforts. The results reported in this thesis strongly suggest that there will be many settings in which genetic data will prove valuable to social sciences. In addition to broadening our knowledge about the biological mechanisms underlying behavioral outcomes, these advances will provide researchers from many disciplines with increasingly powerful tools that can be used to integrate genetic factors into a wide range of empirical models.
    [Show full text]
  • An Epigenome-Wide Association Study Meta-Analysis of Educational Attainment
    OPEN Molecular Psychiatry (2017) 22, 1680–1690 www.nature.com/mp IMMEDIATE COMMUNICATION An epigenome-wide association study meta-analysis of educational attainment R Karlsson Linnér1,2,57, RE Marioni3,4,57, CA Rietveld2,5,6,57, AJ Simpkin7, NM Davies8, K Watanabe1, NJ Armstrong9, K Auro10,11, C Baumbach12, MJ Bonder13, J Buchwald10, G Fiorito14,15, K Ismail10, S Iurato16, A Joensuu10,11, P Karell10, S Kasela17,18, J Lahti19,20, AF McRae21, PR Mandaviya22,23, I Seppälä24,25, Y Wang26, L Baglietto27, EB Binder16,28, SE Harris3,4, AM Hodge29,30, S Horvath31, M Hurme32,33,34, M Johannesson35, A Latvala36, KA Mather37, SE Medland38, A Metspalu17,18, L Milani17, RL Milne29,30, A Pattie39, NL Pedersen26, A Peters12, S Polidoro14, K Räikkönen19, G Severi14,29,40, JM Starr4,41, L Stolk22,42, M Waldenberger12, BIOS Consortium, JG Eriksson43,44,45, T Esko17,46, L Franke13, C Gieger12, GG Giles29,30, S Hägg26, P Jousilahti11, J Kaprio10,36, M Kähönen47,48, T Lehtimäki24,25, NG Martin49, JBC van Meurs23,42, M Ollikainen10,36, M Perola10,11, D Posthuma1, OT Raitakari50,51, PS Sachdev37,52, E Taskesen1,53, AG Uitterlinden6,23,42, P Vineis14,54, C Wijmenga13, MJ Wright55, C Relton8, G Davey Smith8, IJ Deary4,39,58, PD Koellinger1,2,58 and DJ Benjamin56,58 The epigenome is associated with biological factors, such as disease status, and environmental factors, such as smoking, alcohol consumption and body mass index. Although there is a widespread perception that environmental influences on the epigenome are pervasive and profound, there has been little evidence to date in humans with respect to environmental factors that are biologically distal.
    [Show full text]
  • David Laibson “Be Careful with More Freedom in the Pension System”
    BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS INTERVIEW David Laibson “Be careful with more freedom in the pension system” RUBEN ith his research into savings and self-con- teams can use that company’s consumer base. Because of VAN OOSTEN trol problems, David Laibson is one of the the scope of this collaboration it is then much easier to Editor ESB founders of contemporary behavioral eco- find corporate partners.” nomics. His groundbreaking research focu- Wses on people’s inner struggle when having to make inter- Do you already see any results of that project? temporal choices (box 1). About his 1994 thesis (Laibson, “Absolutely. For example, the first meeting, also recorded in 1994), in which he formalizes the work of the psychologist a Freakonomics podcast (Freakonomics, 2018), acted as a George Ainslie, The New York Times (2001) wrote: “In catalyst for my study on facilitating laptop use in the class- the histories of economics still to be written, the spring of room, which I didn’t think would become a formal study. At 1994 will almost certainly be flagged as momentous.” Not the beginning of the year, students are offered the choice on much later Laibson is appointed as professor at Harvard; which side of the lecture hall they want to sit: the side where the first one to have actually trained as a behavioral econo- everyone can use a laptop, or where laptops aren’t allowed. mist (The New York Times, 2001). The first meeting of the Behavior Change for Good initia- Laibson just stepped down as dean of the Harvard tive yielded enough momentum, so that we could convert economics faculty.
    [Show full text]
  • The Promises and Pitfalls of Genoeconomics Daniel J
    The Promises and Pitfalls of Genoeconomicsà Daniel J. Benjamin,1 David Cesarini,2 Christopher F. Chabris,3 Edward L. Glaeser,4 and David I. Laibson4 Age, Gene/Environment Susceptibility-Reykjavik Study Vilmundur Guðnason,5 Tamara B. Harris,6 Lenore J. Launer,6 Shaun Purcell,7 and Albert Vernon Smith5 Swedish Twin Registry Magnus Johannesson8 and Patrik K.E. Magnusson9 Framingham Heart Study Jonathan P. Beauchamp10 and Nicholas A. Christakis11 Wisconsin Longitudinal Study Craig S. Atwood,12 Benjamin Hebert,13 Jeremy Freese,14 Robert M. Hauser,15 and Taissa S. Hauser15 Swedish Large Schizophrenia Study Alexander Grankvist,9 Christina M. Hultman,9 and Paul Lichtenstein9 Annu. Rev. Econ. 2012. 4:627–62 Keywords First published online as a Review in Advance on genetics, heritability, GWAS June 18, 2012 The Annual Review of Economics is online at Abstract economics.annualreviews.org This article reviews existing research at the intersection of genetics This article’s doi: and economics, presents some new findings that illustrate the state of 10.1146/annurev-economics-080511-110939 genoeconomics research, and surveys the prospects of this emerging Copyright © 2012 by Annual Reviews. field. Twin studies suggest that economic outcomes and preferences, All rights reserved once corrected for measurement error, appear to be about as herita- JEL codes: A12, D03, Z00 ble as many medical conditions and personality traits. Consistent by Harvard University on 09/19/12. For personal use only. 1941-1383/12/0904-0627$20.00 with this pattern, we present new evidence on the heritability of ÃPlease see the Acknowledgments section permanent income and wealth. Turning to genetic association stud- Annu.
    [Show full text]
  • Research Transparency and Reproducibility Training (RT2) Participant Manual Los Angeles, CA September 5-7, 2018
    Research Transparency and Reproducibility Training (RT2) Participant Manual Los Angeles, CA September 5-7, 2018 Contents About RT2 ........................................................................................................................................................................................................... 2 Pre-Training Actions ................................................................................................................................................................................ 3 1. Sign up for an OSF account ............................................................................................................................................... 3 2. Review study pre-registration ......................................................................................................................................... 3 3. Install Git and create Github.com account ........................................................................................................... 3 4. Install software for Dynamic Documents – for R or Stata ....................................................................... 4 5. Install Anaconda - for Jupyter Notebooks ............................................................................................................. 4 6. Install LaTeX .................................................................................................................................................................................... 5 7. Install a decent text editor
    [Show full text]
  • Are Genetic Markers of Interest for Economic Research? Steven F
    Lehrer and Ding IZA Journal of Labor Policy (2017) 6:2 DOI 10.1186/s40173-017-0080-6 REVIEW Open Access Are genetic markers of interest for economic research? Steven F. Lehrer1,2,3* and Weili Ding1,2 * Correspondence: [email protected] 1School of Policy Studies and Abstract Department of Economics, Queen’s University, Kingston K7L3N6, The idea that genetic differences may explain a multitude of individual-level outcomes Ontario, Canada studied by economists is far from controversial. Since more datasets now contain 2NYU-Shanghai, 1555 Century measures of genetic variation, it is reasonable to postulate that incorporating genomic Avenue Office 1127, Pudong New District, Pudong 200122, Shanghai, data in economic analyses will become more common. However, there remains much China debate among academics as to, first, whether ignoring genetic differences in empirical Full list of author information is analyses biases the resulting estimates. Second, several critics argue that since genetic available at the end of the article characteristics are immutable, the incorporation of these variables into economic analysis will not yield much policy guidance. In this paper, we revisit these concerns and survey the main avenues by which empirically oriented economic researchers have utilized measures of genetic markers to improve our understanding of economic phenomena. We discuss the strengths, limitations, and potential of existing approaches and conclude by highlighting several prominent directions forward for future research. JEL Classification: I12, J19, I26 Keywords: Genetic markers, Gene–environment interactions, Genome-wide association studies, Candidate genes, Genetic instruments, Within-family variation 1 Introduction It would not be an exaggeration to say that the mere mention of the word genetics to an economist a decade ago could cause alarm.
    [Show full text]
  • The Genetic Architecture of Economic and Political Preferences
    The genetic architecture of economic and political preferences Daniel J. Benjamina,1, David Cesarinib,c, Matthijs J. H. M. van der Loosd, Christopher T. Dawese, Philipp D. Koellingerd, Patrik K. E. Magnussonf, Christopher F. Chabrisg, Dalton Conleyh, David Laibsoni, Magnus Johannessonj,2, and Peter M. Visscherk,2 aDepartment of Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853; bCenter for Experimental Social Science, Department of Economics, New York University, New York, NY 10012; cResearch Institute of Industrial Economics, SE-102 15 Stockholm, Sweden; dDepartment of Applied Economics, Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University Rotterdam, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands; eDepartment of Politics, New York University, New York, NY 10012; fDepartment of Medical Epidemiology and Biostatistics, Karolinska Institutet, SE-171 77 Stockholm, Sweden; gDepartment of Psychology, Union College, Schenectady, NY 12308; hDepartment of Sociology, New York University, New York, NY 10012; iDepartment of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138; jDepartment of Economics, Stockholm School of Economics, SE-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden; and kUniversity of Queensland Diamantina Institute, Princess Alexandra Hospital, Woolloongabba 4102, Australia Edited* by Eric S. Lander, The Broad Institute of MIT and Harvard, Cambridge, MA, and approved March 22, 2012 (received for review December 19, 2011) Preferences are fundamental building blocks in all models of Existing studies claiming to have established genetic associa- economic and political behavior. We study a new sample of tions with economic and political traits typically use samples of comprehensively genotyped subjects with data on economic and several hundred individuals, and no such study has used a sample political preferences and educational attainment. We use dense larger than 3,000 individuals (for a recent review, see ref.
    [Show full text]
  • Genetic and Economic Interaction in the Formation of Human Capital: the Case of Obesity
    Genetic and Economic Interaction in the Formation of Human Capital: The Case of Obesity. Pietro Biroli ∗ January 10, 2015 Please download the latest version here Abstract Small genetic differences at birth confer a comparative advantage in health and human capital formation, and can lead to substantial inequality in long term social and economic outcomes. I develop a structural model of health and human capital formation illustrating the dynamic interaction between genetic inheri- tance and investments in health over the life cycle. Genetic heterogeneity across individuals can change the utility cost of investments and the production func- tion of health, shifting the incentives to invest in healthy habits. Focusing on Body-Mass-Index (BMI) as a measure of poor health, I consider physical activity and food intake as investments in health, and I evaluate their interaction with specific variants in FTO and other genes associated with BMI in Genome-Wide Association Studies. Applying this model to two different datasets, one of British adolescents and one of US adults, I find that Gene-Environment interaction plays a pivotal role in the evolution of BMI. Food intake has a stronger impact on BMI for those individuals with a particular genetic makeup, and yet they tend to dis- play a higher demand for food. The association of variants in the FTO gene with the hypothalamic regulation of food intake gives a biological foundation to the observed differences in healthy investments. This analysis provides an economic framework of health and human capital formation that integrates recent findings in genetics and molecular biology and sheds light on the interdependence between genes and economic choices of investment.
    [Show full text]