What GDP Indicators Do Not Tell You: Alternative Indicators of Economic Growth and Real Convergence

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

What GDP Indicators Do Not Tell You: Alternative Indicators of Economic Growth and Real Convergence s_578_594 2.12.2005 11:30 Stránka 578 UDC: 330.55 JEL Classification: O11 Keywords: gross domestic product – terms of trade – real gross domestic income – real convergence – qualitative changes – statistical paradoxes What GDP Indicators Do Not Tell You: Alternative Indicators of Economic Growth and Real Convergence RÛÏena VINTROVÁ* This paper points out the limits of GDP and the importance of supple- menting it with other indicators available in the national accounts. The wealth of a country does not depend on the volume of goods and ser- vices the economy manages to produce, but rather on its appropriate struc- ture and quality. Such quality is best reflected in foreign trade and this is especially true of small, open economies whose exports are a large share of total output. Economic analyses typically work with the GDP indicator, which however does not reflect the impact of the changes of terms of trade. The paper is organized as follows: In chapter 1 we analyze the impact of terms of trade on real income and the methodology of real gross domestic income indicator (RGDI). We also compare RGDI rates of growth in Cen- tral European countries based on our own calculations. In chapter 2 we ana- lyze the conditions under which real GDP growth does not fully reflect the progress of real convergence. We investigate the so-called Gerschenkron effect in the Central European countries and compare recent developments in Slovakia with the familiar statistical paradox of centrally planned eco- nomies. The influence of labor productivity and wage relations on the level of unit labor costs and cost competitiveness of Central European economies is compared. In the final chapter we suggest some implications for macro- economic analysis and economic policy. 1. The Impact of Terms of Trade on Real Income Real income – unlike real GDP – includes the impact of terms of trade. The Czech economy stands out – at least in the European context – owing to a substantial long-term improvement in terms of trade. These positive terms-of-trade changes affected the economic level of economic development in the country, maintenance of the macroeconomic balance, the real growth of income, and thus the process of real convergence. While in the short run import and export prices in the Czech Republic fluctuated, strongly influ- encing the external balance, in the long run the country benefitted from un- usually significant terms-of-trade gains. These “trading gains” are ignored in analyses that use only the “classic” indicator of GDP. * Centre for Economic Studies, University of Economics and Management, Prague (ruzena.vint- [email protected]) 578 Finance a úvûr – Czech Journal of Economics and Finance, 55, 2005, ã. 11-12 s_578_594 2.12.2005 11:30 Stránka 579 GRAPH 1 Terms of Trade in Goods and Services in Selected EU Countries (1995 = 100)a 115 110 Czech Rep. 105 Hungary Germany 100 Poland Austria 95 Slovakia ms of trade in good ms of trade r France Te and srvices (1995=100) 90 Slovenia 85 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Note: a according to import/export deflator from national accounts Source: (European Commission, 2005), p. 84 1.1 Terms-of-Trade Changes in Transitional Economies Terms of trade (T/T) capture the relationship between export and import prices and thus express the success of a country in its external trade. Their short-term fluctuations are usually associated with price volatility in pri- mary commodities (especially crude oil). These movements are an exoge- nous variable especially in the case of small open economies. In contrast, long-term terms-of-trade trends are for the most part en- dogenous.1 If an individual country’s position in T/T improves, then this fact increases its real income above its “physical” volume of total production. The Czech Republic belongs to such countries, as shown in terms-of trade comparison with the EU countries (Graph 1). From the countries investigated, the development of terms of trade in the Czech Republic is the most favorable. Whereas in the other Central Eu- ropean new member states (NMS-4)2 the index of terms of trade was lower in 2004 in comparison with 1995, in the Czech Republic it was higher by more than 12 %.3 The Czech economy has been very sensitive to one-off fluctuations in terms of trade. In some years the changes in T/T have had a greater influence on the formation of real income than the change in real GDP (Table 1).4 On the one hand, in 1998, GDP fell by 1.1 %, but this decrease was more than 1 Providing these trends do not reflect a longer-term phenomenon of redistribution between raw- -material exporting and manufacturing countries. 2 The NMS-4 are new Central European EU member states, which include the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia. The NMS-5 include the above and Slovenia, and NMS-8 are all post communist countries, i.e. NMS-10 with the exception of Malta and Cyprus. 3 The rapid rise in T/T in the Czech Republic between the years 1995 and 2004 partly compen- sated for the deep fall at the start of the transformation. On the same basis (1995 = 100) T/T in the year 1990 were 109.1 %. During 1991 however they fell (after 3 devaluations of the Czecho- slovak koruna in the preceding year) by more than 24 percentage points to 84.7 %. They did not return to the previous level of 1990 until 1998. A decline of T/T was also observed in the other transformation countries, such as Poland or Slovenia, at the start of transformation in the early 1990s, but it was not as steep as in the former Czechoslovakia. 4 For more details see (Vintrová, 2004). Finance a úvûr – Czech Journal of Economics and Finance, 55, 2005, ã. 11-12 579 s_578_594 2.12.2005 11:30 Stránka 580 TABLE 1 Real GDP Growth and the Impact of Terms of Trade in the Czech Republic 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Real GDP growth (in %)a 4.2 –0.7 –1.1 1.2 3.9 2.6 1.5 3.2 4.7 Change in T/T (in % of GDP)b 1.6 0.2 3.5 –0.3 –1.8 1.7 2.2 0.1 0.3 in bn. CZK 24 4 62 –6 –37 37 51 2 7 Notes: a In constant prices, calculated on the basis of the chaining method, i.e. GDP of the current year in average prices of the previous year related to GDP of the previous year in current prices. b Change of T/T adjusted to previous year average prices related to GDP of previous year in current prices. Source: (Czech Statistical Office, 2005) – author’s adjustment offset by an improvement in terms of trade equivalent to 3.5 % of GDP. In 2002 the gain in T/T was 2.2 % of GDP, which was greater than the gain in real GDP growth (1.5 %). On the other hand, in 2000, real GDP grew fast at 3.9 %, but unfavorable T/T development lowered real resources by 1.8 % of GDP, and real income growth was lower than in 1998, the year of the big- gest GDP decline. In absolute terms the favorable impact of terms of trade peaked in 1998, when it raised real income by 62 bn. constant CZK. The fall of 37 bn. CZK in 2000, caused by higher import prices, was reversed during the following year. The subsequent favorable development in terms of trade in 2002 led to a growth in real income of 51 bn. CZK. In summary, such large changes in real domestic income are difficult to ignore. Long-term improvements in terms of trade are endogenous and reflect qualitative changes in the tradable output of the given country. These are qualitative changes in the widest sense of the word, and not just improve- ments in technical parameters, which statisticians try to include in price indices according to the possibilities available.5 These qualitative changes reflect transfers of labor and capital to: (i) activities with higher value added, (ii) to more sophisticated products, and (iii) to superior technologies. In ad- dition, these changes reflect an improvement in the price premia of domestic brands and/or an elimination of discount for ‘goods from the east’ and a bett- er integration into the international trade network. These factors may in- crease export prices and raise real income without any growth in the ‘phy- sical volume’ of exported goods and services. Such changes accelerated in the Czech economy following the inflow of foreign direct investment (FDI) at the end of the 1990s. 1.2 Real Income Indicator Changes in terms of trade are excluded from the measure of GDP in con- stant prices. This comes from the principle on which this indicator is based: “What would happen if there were no changes either in domestic or foreign prices?” Thus, real GDP considers only the growth in volume of production, 5 The impact of quality changes in transition economies is analyzed in more detail in (Filer – Hanousek, 2000). 580 Finance a úvûr – Czech Journal of Economics and Finance, 55, 2005, ã. 11-12 s_578_594 2.12.2005 11:30 Stránka 581 while its valuation in foreign markets as well as import price changes are ignored. However, unlike domestic price changes, export and import price changes influence the real income available for consumption and invest- ment in a given country. For this reason GDP may not provide a full pic- ture of the overall achievements of an economy.
Recommended publications
  • The Soviet Union After 1945: Economic Recovery and Political Repression
    The Soviet Union after 1945: Economic Recovery and Political Repression Mark Harrison* Department of Economics, University of Warwick Centre for Russian & East European Studies, University of Birmingham Hoover Institution on War, Revolution, and Peace, Stanford University Abstract Salient features of the Soviet Union after World War II include rapid economic recovery and the consolidation of Stalin’s rule. Both economic recovery and political consolidation are explained in large part by temporary factors arising from the war. Rapid postwar growth is attributed to the scope arising from a combination of preceding shocks that included the war itself but also stretched back into the prewar years. Political-economy considerations link Stalin’s capacity to organizing recovery while delaying reforms to the quality of repression, based on his exploitation of the war as a source of new information about the citizens over whom he ruled. JEL Codes: E1, N4, P2 * Mail: Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, UK. Email: [email protected]. First draft: December 11, 2006. This version: April 14, 2010. The Soviet Union after 1945: Economic Recovery and Political Repression The story of the Soviet Union’s postwar years appears almost as remarkable as the story of the war.1 The USSR came to victory in 1945 only after first coming close to total defeat. In 1945 the Red Army occupied Tallinn, Riga, Vilnius, Warsaw, Berlin, Vienna, Prague, Budapest, and Sofia, but behind the army the country lay in ruins. Its people had suffered 25 million premature deaths. The survivors were profoundly weary. Many hoped for reconciliation and relaxation.
    [Show full text]
  • I from the CENTRALLY PLANNED ECONOMY to CAPITALIST
    FROM THE CENTRALLY PLANNED ECONOMY TO CAPITALIST GLOBALISATION: HOW ECONOMISTS UNDERESTIMATED THE GROWTH OF THE WORLD MARKET WILLIAM RICHARD JEFFERIES A thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements of the Manchester Metropolitan University for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Marketing the Manchester Metropolitan University 2013 i The copyright of this thesis belongs to the author under the terms of the Copyright Act 1987 as qualified by Regulation 4 (1) of the Multimedia University Intellectual Property Regulations. Due acknowledgement shall always be made of the use of any material contained in, or derived from, this thesis. © William Jefferies, 2013 All rights reserved. ii DECLARATION I hereby declare that the work has been done by myself and no portion of the work contained in this Thesis has been submitted in support of any application for any other degree or qualification on this or any other university or institution of learning. _______________ William Jefferies iii ACKNOWLEDGMENT. Thanks to Tony Hines and Paul Brook for their support, encouragement and criticism and Viv Davies and Hillel Fridman for their helpful comments throughout. iv DEDICATION. To my brother Rob. v TABLE OF CONTENTS COPYRIGHT PAGE. ii DECLARATION . iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENT . iv DEDICATION . v TABLE OF CONTENTS. viii LIST OF TABLES. ix LIST OF FIGURES. x GLOSSARY xi ABSTRACT 1 CHAP TER 1: Introduction. 3 1 .1 Opening 3 1.2 Chapter 2 4 1.3 Chapter 3 4 1.4 Chapter 4 10 1.5 Chapter 5 12 1.6 Chapter 6 13 1.7 Chapter 7 17 CHAPTER 2: Marxist Method. 18 2.1 Marx’s materialism and the dialectical method 18 2.2 Abstraction and the Labour Theory of Value 24 2.3 The nature of value 31 2.4 Transformation problem 37 2.5 National accounting and statistics 61 CHAPTER 3: The Measurement of Soviet Economic Growth.
    [Show full text]
  • The Industrialization and Economic Development of Russia Through the Lens of a Neoclassical Growth Model∗
    The Industrialization and Economic Development of Russia through the Lens of a Neoclassical Growth Model∗ Anton Cheremukhin, Mikhail Golosov, Sergei Guriev, Aleh Tsyvinski July 2014 Abstract This paper studies the structural transformation of Russia in 1885-1940 from an agrarian to an industrial economy through the lens of a two-sector neoclassical growth model. We construct a dataset that covers Tsarist Russia during 1885-1913 and Soviet Russia during 1928-1940. We use the growth model to develop a procedure that allows us to identify the types of frictions and economic mechanisms that had the largest quantitative impact on Russian economic de- velopment, as well as those that are inconsistent with the data. Our methodology identies frictions that lead to large markups in the non-agricultural sector as the most important rea- son for Tsarist Russia's failure to industrialize before WWI. Soviet industrial transformation after 1928 was achieved primarily by reducing such frictions, albeit at a signicant cost of lower TFP. We nd no evidence that Tsarist agricultural institutions were a signicant barrier to labor transition to manufacturing, or that "Big Push" mechanisms contributed to Soviet growth. ∗Cheremukhin: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; Golosov: Princeton; Guriev: NES and Sciences Po; Tsyvin- ski: Yale. The authors thank Mark Aguiar, Paco Buera, V.V. Chari, Hal Cole, Raquel Fernandez, Joseph Kaboski, Andrei Markevich, Joel Mokyr, Lee Ohanian, Richard Rogerson for useful comments. We also thank participants at Berkeley, EIEF, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Harvard, HEC, NBER EFJK Growth, Development Economics, and Income Distribution and Macroeconomics, New Economic School, Northwestern, Ohio State, Paris School of Economics, Princeton, Sciences Po.
    [Show full text]
  • China's Growth and Productivity Performance Debate Revisited
    Economics Program Working Paper Series China’s Growth and Productivity Performance Debate Revisited - Accounting for China’s Sources of Growth with a New Data Set Harry X. Wu Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo [email protected] & The Conference Board China Center, Beijing [email protected] January 2014 EPWP #14 – 01 Economics Program 845 Third Avenue New York, NY 10022-6679 Tel. 212-759-0900 www.conference-board.org/ economics CHINA’S GROWTH AND PRODUCTIVITY PERFORMANCE DEBATE REVISITED* - Accounting for China’s Sources of Growth with A New Data Set Harry X. Wu Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo [email protected] & The Conference Board China Center, Beijing [email protected] ABSTRACT This study explores problems with official Chinese economic data that are often ignored or overlooked in existing academic studies. They include structural breaks in employment statistics, implausibly high labor productivity figures relating to “non- material” services, serious inconsistencies between output measures in industrial statistics versus those in national accounts, as well as between volume movements and changes in real values. There are also conceptual flaws in official measures of fixed- asset investment and biases in the prices of the investment. Alternative adjustments for these problems are the basis for the construction of a new set of data for the aggregate economy and its five major sectors in 1949-2012. I find that the impact of external shocks is more pronounced using my alternative GDP estimates than with official estimates. Under the most reasonable scenarios, my estimates show that China’s annual TFP growth is -0.5 percent for the planning period and 1.1 percent for the post-reform period, much slower than the results based on unadjusted official data which is 0.1 and 3.2 percent respectively.
    [Show full text]
  • Purchasing Power Disparity Before 1914
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PURCHASING POWER DISPARITY BEFORE 1914 Peter H. Lindert Working Paper 22896 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22896 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2016 For comments on earlier versions, and for help with data, the author thanks Robert Allen, Leticia Arroyo Abad, John Devereux, Kyoji Fukao, Alfonso Herranz Loncán, Philip T. Hoffman, Branko Milanovic, Chiaki Moriguchi, Leandro Prados de la Escosura, Osamu Saito, Masanori Takashima, Jeffrey G. Williamson, and seminar participants at Hitotsubashi University and the University of Tampere. Excel files showing the underlying estimation process are available in the relevant country folders in the “Main Data Sets” folder at http://gpih.ucdavis.edu. Earlier data- gathering stages of this research were funded by the US National Science Foundation, as detailed on the gpih website. An earlier version of this working paper appeared as Hitotsubashi Institute for Advanced Study Discussion Paper HIAS-E-35 (October 2016). The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2016 by Peter H. Lindert. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Purchasing Power Disparity before 1914 Peter H. Lindert NBER Working Paper No. 22896 December 2016 JEL No.
    [Show full text]
  • The Industrialization and Economic Development of Russia Through the Lens of a Neoclassical Growth Model∗
    The Industrialization and Economic Development of Russia through the Lens of a Neoclassical Growth Model∗ Anton Cheremukhin, Mikhail Golosov, Sergei Guriev, Aleh Tsyvinski November 2015 Abstract This paper studies the structural transformation of Russia in 1885-1940 from an agrarian to an industrial economy through the lens of a two-sector neoclassical growth model. We construct a dataset that covers Tsarist Russia during 1885-1913 and Soviet Union during 1928-1940. We develop a methodology that allows us to identify the types of frictions and economic mech- anisms that had the largest quantitative impact on Russian economic development. We find that entry barriers and monopoly power in the non-agricultural sector were the most impor- tant reason for Tsarist Russia’s failure to industrialize before World War I. Soviet industrial transformation after 1928 was achieved primarily by reducing such frictions, albeit coinciding with a significantly lower performance of productivity in both agricultural and non-agricultural sectors. We find no evidence that Tsarist agricultural institutions were a significant barrier to labor reallocation to manufacturing, or that “Big Push” mechanisms were a major driver of Soviet growth. ∗Cheremukhin: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; Golosov: Princeton; Guriev: Sciences Po, Paris, and CEPR; Tsyvinski: Yale. The authors thank Mark Aguiar, Paco Buera, V.V. Chari, Hal Cole, Raquel Fernandez, Joseph Kaboski, Andrei Markevich, Joel Mokyr, Lee Ohanian, Richard Rogerson, and four anonymous referees for useful comments. We also thank participants at Berkeley, Brown, Duke, EIEF, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Harvard, HEC, NBER EFJK Growth, Development Economics, and Income Distribution and Macroeconomics, New Economic School, Northwestern, Ohio State, Paris School of Economics, Princeton, Sciences Po, University of Zurich.
    [Show full text]
  • Long Run Projections for Climate Change Scenarios*
    = tlohfkd=m^mbop=fk= fkqbok^qflk^i=b`lkljf`p= j~ó=OMMQ=√ =kçK=NKMQ= içåÖ=oìå=mêçàÉÅíáçåë=Ñçê= `äáã~íÉ=`Ü~åÖÉ=pÅÉå~êáçë= t~êïáÅâ=g=j`háÄÄáåI= a~îáÇ=mÉ~êÅÉ=~åÇ= ^äáëçå=píÉÖã~å= fåíÉêå~íáçå~ä=bÅçåçãó=mêçÖê~ã= The Lowy Institute for International Policy is an independent international policy think tank based in Sydney, Australia. Its mandate ranges across all the dimensions of international policy debate in Australia - economic, political and strategic – and it is not limited to a particular geographic region. Its two core tasks are to: • produce distinctive research and fresh policy options for Australia’s international policy and to contribute to the wider international debate. • promote discussion of Australia’s role in the world by providing an accessible and high quality forum for discussion of Australian international relations through debates, seminars, lectures, dialogues and conferences. This Working Paper series presents papers in a preliminary form and serves to stimulate comment and discussion. The views expressed in this paper are entirely the author’s own and not those of the Lowy Institute for International Policy. Long Run Projections for Climate Change Scenarios* Warwick J. McKibbin** The Lowy Institute for International Policy, Sydney Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis, ANU, Canberra The Brookings Institution, Washington David Pearce Centre for International Economics, Canberra And Alison Stegman The Australian National University, Canberra Revised Draft 23 April 2004 * This was prepared for the Stanford Energy Modeling Forum workshop on Purchasing Power Parity versus Market Exchange Rates. It has benefited from discussions with Peter Wilcoxen, Barry Bosworth, Ian Castles, Alan Heston, Neil Ferry and many colleagues at the Stanford meeting.
    [Show full text]
  • CGEH Working Paper Series
    CGEH Working Paper Series A dataset on human capital in the former Soviet Union area Sources, methods, and first results Dmitry Didenko, Vnesheconombank Peter Foldvari, Debrecen University Bas van Leeuwen, Utrecht University August 2012 Working paper no. 35 http://www.cgeh.nl/working-paper-series/ © 2012 by Authors. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. A dataset on human capital in the former Soviet Union area Sources, methods, and first results* Dmitry Didenko1 Péter Földvári2 Bas van Leeuwen3 Abstract To date, the rise and fall of the (former) USSR has triggered a lot of research. Many have focused on the accumulation of physical capital, growth, and consumption. Recently, also the accumulation of human capital has increasingly been incorporated in this picture. However, few datasets exist that cover this crucial variable for this vast area. Therefore, our main objective is to introduce a new dataset that contains human capital related time series for the USSR (and the Newly Independent States (NIS) after its dissolution), constructed mostly on an annual basis. These data were drawn from various primary sources, available datasets and secondary literature where our focus was on constructing a dataset as clear, transparent and consistent as possible. It is our hope that, by supplying these data in electronic format, it will significantly advance quantitative economic history research on Russia and all over the former Soviet Union area (FSU) and will inspire further research in various new fields relating to intellectual production.
    [Show full text]
  • International and Intertemporal Comparisons of Real Product in Oecd Countries a Growth Sensitivity Analysis
    Review of Income and Wealth Series 43, Number 1, March 1997 INTERNATIONAL AND INTERTEMPORAL COMPARISONS OF REAL PRODUCT IN OECD COUNTRIES A GROWTH SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS Miniitry oj Economy and Financc Univcvsity of Vulencia and Ministry oj Economy and Finance AND Ministry of Economy and Finance This paper provides two new data sets for comparisons of real income in OECD countries. The first set provides adjusted real series for GDP and its components from 1960 to 1993 based on OECD 1990 purchasing power parities. The second set uses OECD PPP of different benchmark years, and interpolates these applying national price indices. Comparisons between both alternatives, Penn World Tahle Mark 5 (PWT 5) and its new version (PWT 5.6), in terms of economic growth and convergence, reveal some remarkable differences. Moreover, there are wider differences concerning the relative countries' position in GDP per capita ranking. Estimations of convergence equations based on OECD data yield a better fit than those obtained using PWT data, although there are also some significant differences between PWT 5 and PWT 5.6. Nevertheless, a very positive result is that other parameters of interest in these equations are not affected by the use of these different data sources. Most empirical work in the growth and convergence literature is based on data drawn from the Penn World Table Mark 5 (PWT 5) (see Summers and Heston, 1991) or its new version PWT 5.6. These are the obvious choices when the investigator is interested in obtaining honlogeneous data for the largest sample of countries possible, such as the 152 countries covered by PWT 5.6.
    [Show full text]
  • Russian Industrial Statistics
    ISSN 1883-1656 Центр Российских Исследований RRC Working Paper Series No. 66 Russian Industrial Statistics Manabu SUHARA March 2017 RUSSIAN RESEARCH CENTER INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH HITOTSUBASHI UNIVERSITY Kunitachi, Tokyo, JAPAN Russian Industrial Statistics Manabu Suhara Nihon University Introduction Historical Russian statistics on industry are discussed in this paper. Russia attained impressive economic development in the century from the emancipation of Russian serfs to around 1960, although growth was interrupted by the October Revolution, the Civil War, and World War II. The mainspring of Russia’s advancement was industrial growth. The mainly agrarian economy, in which the rural population accounted for about 80% of the total at the end of the 19th century, underwent a complete change in economic structure. This Russian success, however, came to an end at the end of the 1950s and beginning of the 1960s. The mining and manufacturing industries, which until then had led the economy, lost vigor, and the industrial economy as a whole withered. This deterioration led to the collapse of the Soviet Union by the end of the 20th century and the start of systemic transformation to capitalism. In this paper we look back at the history of Russia from the viewpoint of industrial statistics. In the first section, we adopt a general view of industrial statistics in Russia under the Tsarist regime. Some estimates of production indices for the industry of the Russian Empire are presented and compared. Then in the second section, production, labor, and capital statistics for Russian industry in the Soviet era are discussed, followed by the third section, in which changes in industrial statistics for Russia’s new era are summarized.
    [Show full text]
  • The Soviet Union: the Defeated Victor*
    The Soviet Union: the defeated victor* Mark Harrison** The Soviet experience of World War II has too often been seen as beyond comparison. Official Soviet historiography tended to present the war on the eastern front as incomparably tragic and heroic, and as the only struggle which really counted. In the west, selective memory dwelt mainly on the war in western Europe and the Pacific, and sometimes neglected the eastern front altogether. The opportunity to address the Soviet experience from a truly comparative viewpoint is therefore welcome. Another comparison which the scholar may follow profitably is with the Russian experience in World War I. Mobilization to meet the German threat in 1914 and to fight the first campaigns quickly exhausted the Russian armies and military industries. Imperial Russia was able to remain at war after the first winter only because of Allied aid and because Germany, tied down by trench warfare in the west, was unable to launch a serious attack in the east. Despite this limitation, the German pressure eventually brought Russia to the point of economic and social disintegration and political collapse. In this chapter I ask why the outcome of World War II was so different for Russia’s successor state, the USSR, how the resources were mobilized for the Soviet war effort, what price was paid for victory at the time, and what the long-term consequences of this victory may have been. The economic potential for war The scale of the Soviet effort in World War II was essentially determined by the country's prewar military-economic potential, combined with the measures taken before and during the war to realize and augment it.1 The potential for war depended mainly on basic * This paper appeared as a chapter in The Economics of World War II: Six Great Powers in International Comparison, pp.
    [Show full text]
  • Development in a Time of Globalization
    RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE University of Massachusetts Amherst Development in A Time of Globalization J. Mohan Rao 1998 10th floor Thompson Hall University of Massachusetts Amherst, MA, 01003-7510 Telephone: (413) 545-6355 Facsimile: (413) 545-2921 Email:[email protected] Website: http://www.umass.edu/peri/ WORKINGPAPER SERIES Number 1 Development in the Time of Globalization J. Mohan Rao* University of Massachusetts at Amherst Revised: February 1998 [First Draft: October 1997] Paper prepared for the Workshop on Globalization, Uneven Development and Poverty, UNDP, New York, October 24-25, 1997. * I thank Terry McKinley and the UNDP for providing support and Barsha Khattry of the University of Massachusetts for excellent research assistance. Comments from and discussions with participants at the New York conference on Globalization, Uneven Development and Poverty, October 1997, are gratefully acknowledged. I alone am responsible for the views expressed in this study. ABSTRACT The paper examines grounds on which a `second opinion’ to the Washington Consensus may be constructed using data for a sample of 123 rich and poor nations for the period from 1960 to 1995. The historical record makes abundantly clear that international inequality has increased not only over the long haul of the past two centuries but also in recent decades. Unequal development derives mainly from economic and political-economic forces internal to nations. Unregulated global market forces mostly follow this process rather than countering it. At the same time, the fragile internal development process is vulnerable to the disruptive forces of unrestricted openness. To be sure, access to global markets can be a powerful factor in development.
    [Show full text]