The Rigidity of Wages and the Persistence of Unemployment

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Rigidity of Wages and the Persistence of Unemployment ROBERT E. HALL Massachusetts Institute of Technology The Rigidity of Wages and the Persistence of Unemployment IN THE MODERN American economy, fluctuations in unemployment usu- ally persist from one year to the next. Past decades have seen two lengthy deviations from equilibrium in the labor market: 1958 through 1963, when the market was slack for six straight years, and 1964 through 1970, when it was tight for seven straight years. Virtually all forecasters agree today that the sharp recession of 1974-75 will mark the beginning of another extended period of slack, with the official unemployment rate above 6 percent per- haps until the end of the decade. These forecasts are fully consistent with the behavior of the economy after the only comparable postwar recession, in 1957-58. Explanation of the persistence of unemployment has been a major focus of macroeconomic theory since the Great Depression. Though his predecessors had begun to think seriously about the challenge to classi- cal economic theory raised by successive years of high unemployment, John Maynard Keynes was the great pioneer in creating a theory that came to grips with the facts of persistent unemployment, and he remains the dominant figure today. This paper presents a detailed critique of modern explanations of the be- havior of unemployment, both within the Keynesian tradition and outside it. The critique begins with a close look at the modern theory of disequi- librium, which claims to provide a microeconomic foundation for the the- ory of unemployment and wage adjustment. This theory attributes both the Note: This researchwas supportedby the National ScienceFoundation. I am grateful to David Lilien and WynettaMcNeill for assistance,and to membersof the Brookings panel for useful comments. 301 302 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1975 rigidityof wagesand the persistenceof unemploymentto the slow diffusion of informationwithin the labormarket. The evidencepresented here, how- ever,suggests that unemploymentin the modernAmerican economy per- sists farlonger than is remotelyplausible if this factoris the maincause of the lag in marketclearing. This hypothesisis stronglyconfirmed by a study of the dataunder the assumptionthat threemonths is long enoughfor both workersand employersto find out what is happeningin the labormarket. The paperthen turnsto a group of theoriesthat are more traditionally Keynesianin flavor.First is the beliefthat laborunions are responsiblefor the rigidity of wages. Keynes' theory of effectivedemand showed con- vincinglythat rigid wages can permit persistent unemployment, and Keynes himself,as well as his successors,appeared to hold laborunions primarily responsiblefor the nonclassicalbehavior of wages. Closelyrelated is the theoryof wagedetermination based on "idiosyncraticexchange." This the- ory emphasizesthe bilateralmonopoly betweenindividual workers and employers,which biases against the adjustmentof wagesin the short run and makesequity an importantelement in wage determination.These two theoriesshare an essentialdefect: however successful they arein explaining wagerigidity in a particularsector, they do not seemcapable of explaining economy-widerigidity. As long as a competitiveresidual sector with a flexiblewage exists,workers who are unableto findjobs in the rigid-wage sectorwill find it in the residualsector and its wage will be depressedas a result. Overall,the labor marketwill clear even if one sector has rigid wages.If unions and other sourcesof rigidityin particularsectors have a role in persistentunemployment, it is more subtle than the traditional Keynesianview supposes. Empiricalevidence on the behaviorof wages, presentednext, suggests that the modernAmerican economy contains an importantsector with rigid wages. Though unionismand idiosyncraticexchange are presentin this sector,its definingcharacteristic is different.The sectorwith inflexible wagesconsists of government,regulated industries, and nonprofitinstitu- tions. These industriesmake up what I will call the "nonentrepreneurial" sector,in whichemployers do not facethe usualincentive to minimizelabor cost. The empiricalresults suggest that the nonentrepreneurialsector is muchthe most importantsource of wage rigidityin today'seconomy. After isolatingthe major source of wage rigidityin the contemporary U.S. economy,the papergoes on to presenta theoryof the transmission, or spillover,of this rigidityto the competitivesector. The moderntheory of RobertE. Hall 303 the supplyside of unemploymentis shownto implythat competitivewages will not fall far enoughto clearthe labormarket at low frictionallevels of unemploymentwhen aggregatedemand falls. Rather,the durationof un- employmentwill rise as the unemployedsearch longer for the high-paying jobsin the rigid-wagesector. During a contraction,the payoffto job search rises because the wage premiumfor these good jobs rises. Conversely, searchis less usefulto the unemployedwhen the labormarket is unusually tight, as competitivewages rise close to rigid wages. The existenceof the rigid-wagesector lessens the ability of the competitivesector to push the wage down to its market-clearinglevel duringa contraction.The paper does not containdirect evidence of this mechanism,but does show that the observedrelation between unemployment and relativewages in the two sectorsaccords roughly with the predictionsof the theory. All of the theoriesdiscussed here are Keynesianin the sense that they explainwhy the mechanismof effectivedemand can operatewithout the immediatecorrective force of market-clearingwage adjustments.They agree that the basic cause of an increasein unemploymentis contrac- tionaryaggregate policy or othershocks in the economy,and similarlythat expansionarypolicy can eliminateexcessive unemployment. With the pos- sible exceptionof some versionsof the theory of disequilibrium,none of these theoriescan fairlybe accusedof makingpersistent unemployment a voluntaryphenomenon arising from the supply side of the labor market. Rather,all of the theoriesthat appearto have any explanatorypower con- cur that unemploymentis the resultof inadequatedemand for labor. The interactionof demandand supplyis describedin greaterdetail in the next section. Theoriesof Unemployment A simple two-equationstructural model of the economy capturesthe theoreticalrelationships that are importantfor the issuesaddressed by this paperand can encompassthe alternativetheories considered here. (1) effective demand: ut = f(wt, xt); (2) wage adjustment: wt - wt- = g(ut) + t - wt-. Hereut is the unemploymentrate and the functionfembodiesthe effective- demandmechanism for the determinationof real gross nationalproduct 304 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1975 and Okun'slaw for translatingit into the unemploymentrate. Effective aggregatedemand depends negatively on the nominalwage, wt, throughthe Keynes and Pigou effects, and depends on various policy variables,xt (monetaristsand Keynesiansdisagree about the presenceof fiscalvariables in xt, but that does not matterhere). In the wage-adjustmentequation, g(ut) is the disequilibrium component and w-t- Wti is the expected or equilibriumcomponent.' Monetarists usually write the equationin a pre- ciselyequivalent form, (3) Ut = g(wt- , and call it "aggregatesupply."2 A convenientalgebraic specification of the systemis (4) effective demand: ut = - i/i(mt - wt) + nt; (5) wage adjustment: wt - wti = -k1(ut - u*) + Wt - Wt-i + Et, whereu* is the equilibriumvalue. H-ereI have switchedto takingw as the log of the nominalwage, m as the log of the moneysupply, and u as the log of the unemploymentrate. I assume,for simplicity,that otherpolicy vari- ables, representedby x in the previousform of the equation,do not enter in determiningeffective demand. The equationsalso containrandom shifts, 77and e. In a structuralmodel, the fundamentalexplanation of the behavior of the endogenousvariables resides in the reducedform, which gives the impact of the predeterminedvariables on the endogenousvariables after takingaccount of the interdependenceof the endogenousvariables in the equations.Statements dealing with causal relationsbetween endogenous variables-such as "high wages cause excessive unemployment"-are meaninglessor contradictoryin a structuralmodel. High wages are asso- ciated with high unemploymentin the aggregate-demandequation, but with low unemploymentin the wage-adjustmentequation. The reduced- formequation for unemploymentsorts out the interactionof the two vari- ables in both equations: - t (6) Ut = u* + -o -1/(mt - Et) + 77t 1. More generally, wi - Wt embodies the inertia that is widely believed to be presentin wage determination.The evidencesuggests that expectationsare only a part of the explanationof inertia,but the use of the term is so widespreadthat I will adopt it here. 2. Thomas J. Sargent studied exactly this two-equationsystem in monetaristform in "Rational Expectations,the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unem- ployment,"BPEA, 2:1973, pp. 429-72. RobertE. Hall 305 The majorissues of the theoryof unemploymentthat areconsidered in this paperconcern the valuesof the parametersin this equation,the specifica- tion of the expectedwage, and the behaviorof the randomshifts. First is the role of the nominalwage in determiningreal aggregatedemand, con- trolledby the parameter01. In the crudeKeynesian model with the liquidity trapand no Pigoueffect, aip = 0, wageadjustment is irrelevant,and unem- ploymentremains at a level determinedby the effective-demandprocess: (7) crudeKeynesian reduced
Recommended publications
  • The Principles of Economics Textbook
    The Principles of Economics Textbook: An Analysis of Its Past, Present & Future by Vitali Bourchtein An honors thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Bachelor of Science Undergraduate College Leonard N. Stern School of Business New York University May 2011 Professor Marti G. Subrahmanyam Professor Simon Bowmaker Faculty Advisor Thesis Advisor Bourchtein 1 Table of Contents Abstract ............................................................................................................................................4 Thank You .......................................................................................................................................4 Introduction ......................................................................................................................................5 Summary ..........................................................................................................................................5 Part I: Literature Review ..................................................................................................................6 David Colander – What Economists Do and What Economists Teach .......................................6 David Colander – The Art of Teaching Economics .....................................................................8 David Colander – What We Taught and What We Did: The Evolution of US Economic Textbooks (1830-1930) ..............................................................................................................10
    [Show full text]
  • Institutions, History and Wage Bargaining Outcomes: International Evidence from the Post-World War Two Era
    Chris Minns and Marian Rizov Institutions, history and wage bargaining outcomes: international evidence from the post-World War Two era Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Minns, Chris and Rizov, Marian (2015) Institutions, history and wage bargaining outcomes: international evidence from the post-World War Two era. Business History, 57 (3). pp. 358-375. ISSN 0007-6791 DOI: 10.1080/00076791.2014.983480 © 2015 Taylor & Francis This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/88847/ Available in LSE Research Online: June 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Institutions, History and Wage Bargaining Outcomes: International Evidence from the Post-World War Two Era Chris Minnsa and Marian Rizovb aDepartment of Economic History, London School of Economics, London, United Kingdom; bDepartment of Economics, Middlesex University Business School, London, United Kingdom (Submitted 29th September 2013; accepted 16 July 2014) Abstract This paper uses international evidence to assess the impact of tripartism and other forms of government involvement in bargaining on wage moderation and wage dispersion.
    [Show full text]
  • Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited
    Seattle Journal for Social Justice Volume 5 Issue 2 Article 28 May 2007 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj Recommended Citation Nadal, Alejandro (2007) "Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited," Seattle Journal for Social Justice: Vol. 5 : Iss. 2 , Article 28. Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj/vol5/iss2/28 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Publications and Programs at Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Seattle Journal for Social Justice by an authorized editor of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 569 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal1 After the 1960s, a strong academic movement developed in the United States around the idea that the study of the law, as well as legal practice, could be strengthened through economic analysis.2 This trend was started through the works of R.H. Coase and Guido Calabresi, and grew with later developments introduced by Richard Posner and Robert D. Cooter, as well as Gary Becker.3 Law and Economics (L&E) is the name given to the application of modern economics to legal analysis and practice. Proponents of L&E have portrayed the movement as improving clarity and logic in legal analysis, and even as a tool to modify the conceptual categories used by lawyers and courts to think about
    [Show full text]
  • Flat Tax: an Overview of the Hall-Rabushka Proposal
    . Flat Tax: An Overview of the Hall-Rabushka Proposal James M. Bickley Specialist in Public Finance November 29, 2011 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov 98-529 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress c11173008 . Flat Tax: An Overview of the Hall-Rabushka Proposal Summary The President and leading Members of Congress have stated that fundamental tax reform is a major policy objective for the 112th Congress. The concept of replacing individual and corporate income taxes and estate and gift taxes with a flat rate consumption tax is one option to reform the U.S. tax system. The term “flat tax” is often associated with a proposal formulated by Robert E. Hall and Alvin Rabushka (H-R), two senior fellows at the Hoover Institution. In the 112th Congress, two bills have been introduced that included a flat tax based on the concepts of Hall- Rabushka: the Freedom Flat Tax Act (H.R. 1040) and the Simplified, Manageable, and Responsible Tax Act (S. 820). In addition, Republican presidential candidate Herman Cain has proposed a tax reform plan that includes a modified H-R flat tax. This report analyzes the Hall- Rabushka flat tax concept. Although the current tax structure is referred to as an income tax, it actually contains elements of both an income and a consumption-based tax. A consumption base is neither inherently superior nor inherently inferior to an income base. The combined individual and business taxes proposed by H-R can be viewed as a modified value- added tax (VAT). The individual wage tax would be imposed on wages (and salaries) and pension receipts.
    [Show full text]
  • CURRICULUM VITAE August, 2015
    CURRICULUM VITAE August, 2015 Robert James Shiller Current Position Sterling Professor of Economics Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics P.O. Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 Delivery Address Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics 30 Hillhouse Avenue, Room 11a New Haven, CT 06520 Home Address 201 Everit Street New Haven, CT 06511 Telephone 203-432-3708 Office 203-432-6167 Fax 203-787-2182 Home [email protected] E-mail http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller Home Page Date of Birth March 29, 1946, Detroit, Michigan Marital Status Married, two grown children Education 1967 B.A. University of Michigan 1968 S.M. Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1972 Ph.D. Massachusetts Institute of Technology Employment Sterling Professor of Economics, Yale University, 2013- Arthur M. Okun Professor of Economics, Yale University 2008-13 Stanley B. Resor Professor of Economics Yale University 1989-2008 Professor of Economics, Yale University, 1982-, with joint appointment with Yale School of Management 2006-, Professor Adjunct of Law in semesters starting 2006 Visiting Professor, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1981-82. Professor of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, and Professor of Finance, The Wharton School, 1981-82. Visitor, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts, and Visiting Scholar, Department of Economics, Harvard University, 1980-81. Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, 1974-81. 1 Research Fellow, National Bureau of Economic Research, Research Center for Economics and Management Science, Cambridge; and Visiting Scholar, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1974-75. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, 1972-74.
    [Show full text]
  • Wage Restraint, Employment, and the Legacy of the General Theory's
    Wage Restraint, Employment, and the Legacy of the General Theory’s Chapter 19 Oliver Landmann University of Freiburg i.Br. 1. Introduction The role of wages in the determination of aggregate employment remains one of the most hotly debated public policy issues in many European countries, and in Germany in particular. This is not surprising in view of the high-profile collective bargaining process in which organized labor and employers negotiate over wages under conditions of persistent high unemployment. Of course, neither side wishes to be seen as merely pursuing its narrow self-interest. Both employers and unions make every effort to argue as convincingly as possible that their respective bargaining positions are conducive to employment growth and macroeconomic stability. Employers invoke neoclassical labor market theory to reject any demands for wage increases in excess of labor productivity growth. Such wage increases, they argue, mean rising labor costs and hence cause job losses. Unions, in contrast, emphasize demand-side repercussions and appeal to the keynesian notion of the circular flow of income. They maintain that any attempt to boost employment through wage restraint is doomed to fail, mainly because this would reduce the purchasing power of consumers and thus domestic demand. Accordingly, they tend to put the blame for high unemployment on misguided fiscal and monetary policies. In contrast, the mainstream consensus regards the longer-term trends of output and employment as supply-determined and, therefore, rejects demand-side explanations of unemployment, except for the very short-run cyclical movements. Keynes (1936) devoted an entire chapter of his General Theory, the famous Chapter 19, to the macroeconomic effects of changes in money-wages.
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series David Laidler On
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DAVID LAIDLER ON MONETARISM Michael Bordo Anna J. Schwartz Working Paper 12593 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12593 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2006 This paper has been prepared for the Festschrift in Honor of David Laidler, University of Western Ontario, August 18-20, 2006. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2006 by Michael Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. David Laidler on Monetarism Michael Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz NBER Working Paper No. 12593 October 2006 JEL No. E00,E50 ABSTRACT David Laidler has been a major player in the development of the monetarist tradition. As the monetarist approach lost influence on policy makers he kept defending the importance of many of its principles. In this paper we survey and assess the impact on monetary economics of Laidler's work on the demand for money and the quantity theory of money; the transmission mechanism on the link between money and nominal income; the Phillips Curve; the monetary approach to the balance of payments; and monetary policy. Michael Bordo Faculty of Economics Cambridge University Austin Robinson Building Siegwick Avenue Cambridge ENGLAND CD3, 9DD and NBER [email protected] Anna J. Schwartz NBER 365 Fifth Ave, 5th Floor New York, NY 10016-4309 and NBER [email protected] 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Power, Platforms and the Free Trade Delusion
    Trade and Development Report 2018: Power, Platforms and the Free Trade Delusion Addendum UNDERSTANDING THE GLOBAL ECONOMY ∗ WITH THE UN GLOBAL POLICY MODEL ∗ This UNCTAD Technical Addendum to the Trade and Development Report 2018: Power, Platforms and the Free Trade Delusion was prepared by external consultant Prof. Amitava Dutt (Department of Political Science, University of Notre Dame, USA and FLACSO-Ecuador), with guidance of UNCTAD’s Senior staff members. This paper has not been formally edited. - 1 - 1. Injections and leakages and financing For understanding the growth of an economy, it is useful to start with an accounting identity that shows how final production (net of intermediate goods that are used up in production) of a region, or its Gross Domestic Product (GDP), is purchased by different sectors of the economy, that is, = + + + , where Y is total production, C is consumption, mostly purchased − by households, I is investment, mostly purchases by firms, G is government expenditure on goods and services, E is exports and M imports. This production identity shows that goods and services produced must end up as consumption, investment (which is mostly for adding to the stock of productive capital), government expenditure and exports, with imports subtracted because part of the first three items may represent purchases of what is produced abroad. The value of what is produced is equal to the value of income, and income can be consumed, saved, or taxed. From this we get the income identity = + + , where S is private saving and T is taxes (less transfers), we can use the production identity to get ( ) + ( ) + ( ) = 0, which we will refer to as the identity −.
    [Show full text]
  • Turnover in the Labor Force
    ROBERT E. HALL* MassachusettsInstitute of Technology Turnover in the Labor Force EVERY MONTH, AN IMPORTANT FRACTION of the populationmoves from one economicactivity to another:Some are laid off and mustseek work, or they quit to take newjobs; young people leave school and look for work; workersleave the labor force becauseof disabilityor duties at home. The continualprocess of turnoverseems to be the characteristicof the modern Americaneconomy that distinguishesit from those of other developed countries,where the experienceof individualworkers appears to be much more stableover time. Is high turnoverinevitable in a postindustrialecon- omy?How do the variousdemographic groups in the laborforce differ with respectto turnover?What is the relationbetween turnover and unemploy- ment?What are the social benefitsand costs of turnoverand unemploy- ment?These are some of the criticalquestions that I addressin this paper. Any moderntreatment of turnoverand unemploymentmust distinguish betweenthe role of eventsoutside the controlof the individualand the role of his responseto his economicenvironment. Fluctuations in the demand for labor are the most importantexternal source of disturbancesin an in- dividual'scareer, so it is conventionalto distinguishbetween the demand side of the problemand the supplyside. Turnover among jobs wasthe tradi- tional explanationof the frictionalunemployment that exists to some ex- tent in everyeconomy, but until recently,it receivedlittle discussion.Even ten yearsago, economistsconsidered unemployment a simpleshortage of * I am gratefulto Zvi Body, RichardKasten, Meir Kohn, and Steven Shavellfor able assistance.This researchwas supportedby the National Science Foundation. 709 710 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3:1972 jobs, withoutasking how the distributionof the laborforce among the jobs changesfrom month to month. The federalgovernment's accidental experimentation with a high-pres- sure economy startingin 1965 broughtabout two importantshifts in the thinkingof economistsabout unemployment.
    [Show full text]
  • Mario Crucini
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Jones, Charles I. Article Life and growth NBER Reporter Provided in Cooperation with: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass. Suggested Citation: Jones, Charles I. (2013) : Life and growth, NBER Reporter, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, MA, Iss. 2, pp. 17-19 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/103247 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Life and Growth Charles I. Jones* During the twentieth century, life functions — of the kind that economists After all, some new technologies save expectancy in the United States rose use to study asset pricing, the labor-lei- lives — new vaccines, new surgical tech- from less than 50 years to 77 years, sure tradeoff, and macroeconomic fluc- niques, anti-lock brakes, and pollution while average incomes rose by about tuations — already contain a key ingredi- scrubbers.
    [Show full text]
  • Intermediate Macroeconomics: New Keynesian Model
    Intermediate Macroeconomics: New Keynesian Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2014 1 Introduction Among mainstream academic economists and policymakers, the leading alternative to the real business cycle theory is the New Keynesian model. Whereas the real business cycle model features monetary neutrality and emphasizes that there should be no active stabilization policy by govern- ments, the New Keynesian model builds in a friction that generates monetary non-neutrality and gives rise to a welfare justification for activist economic policies. New Keynesian economics is sometimes caricatured as being radically different than real business cycle theory. This caricature is unfair. The New Keynesian model is built from exactly the same core that our benchmark model is { there are optimizing households and firms, who interact in markets and whose interactions give rise to equilibrium prices and allocations. There is really only one fundamental difference in the New Keynesian model relative to the real business cycle model { nominal prices are assumed to be \sticky." By \sticky" I simply mean that there exists some friction that prevents Pt, the money price of goods, from adjusting quickly to changing conditions. This friction gives rise to monetary non-neutrality and means that the competitive equilibrium outcome of the economy will, in general, be inefficient. By “inefficient" we mean that the equilibrium allocations in the sticky price economy are different than the fictitious social planner would choose. New Keynesian economics is to be differentiated from \old" Keynesian economics. Old Keyne- sian economics arose out of the Great Depression, adopting its name from John Maynard Keynes. Old Keynesian models were typically much more ad hoc than the optimizing models with which we work and did not feature very serious dynamics.
    [Show full text]
  • The Quantity Theory, Inflation, and the Demand for Money
    Quantity Theory, Inflation, and the Demand for Money This lecture examines the link between the quantity theory of money and the demand for money with special emphasis placed on how much the quantity of money demanded is affected by changes in the interest rate. The Classical Quantity Theory of Money A. Velocity of money and the equation of exchange 1. The velocity of money (V) is the average number of times per year that a dollar is spent buying goods and services in the economy , (1) where P×Y is nominal GDP and MS is the nominal money supply. 2. Example: Suppose nominal GDP is $15 trillion and the nominal money supply is $3 trillion, then velocity is $ (2) $ Thus, money turns over an average of five times a year. 3. The equation of exchange relates nominal GDP to the nominal money supply and the velocity of money MS×V = P×Y. (3) 4. The relationship in (3) is nothing more than an identity between money and nominal GDP because it does not tell us whether money or money velocity changes when nominal GDP changes. 5. Determinants of money velocity a. Institutional and technological features of the economy affect money velocity slowly over time. b. Money velocity is reasonably constant in the short run. 6. Money demand (MD) a. Lets divide both sides of (3) by V MS = (1/V)×P×Y. (4) b. In the money market, MS = MD in equilibrium. If we set k = (1/V), then (4) can be rewritten as a money demand equation MD = k×P×Y.
    [Show full text]