<<

Daniel L. Thornton

Dan/el L. Thornton is an assistant vice president at the Federal Resence Bank of St. Louis. Lynn D. Dietrich provided research assistance.

Do Government Deficits Matter?

nfl S it, HERE HAS BEEN considerable concern and result in renewed infla- about the size of the federal deficit and the tionary pressures. rather modest success of the Gramm-Rudman- Hollings Act to reduce it. The traditional, that is, An alternative view, called Ricardian equiva- Keynesian, view of in macro- lence, however, sees deficit spending as a har- economics was that it could smooth out fluctua- binger of neither good nor ill. According to this tions in economic activity due to gaps between view, deficit spending cannot offset fluctuations saving and that were primarily the in economic activity due to exogenous shifts in result of exogenous shifts in investment. From either private saving or investment; nor, can it this perspective, deficit spending was seen as be blamed for high real interest rates or the both desirable and necessary to offset cyclical large trade deficit. Moreover, it has no influence fluctuations in economic activity that were char- on the outlook for economic growth or infla- acteristic of capitalist, free-market . tion. Macroeconomic tests of the effects of deficits on the using U.S. time-series data have generally favored the Ricardian view.’ Recent discussions of government deficits, however, have focused on their alleged adverse The purpose of this article is to review both effects. It is now common to blame deficit views of deficit spending to determine which spending for high real rates of interest and the view of the relationships between deficit spen- large and persistent trade deficit. Moreover, ding and various associated macroeconomic var- there is widespread concern that large and per- iables is supported by evidence from 16 OECD sistent federal deficits will produce stagnant countries over the period 1975.86.2

‘Recently, there have been three excellent surveys of the reasons. First, strictly speaking, Ricardian equivalence is a empirical investigations of Ricardian equivalence. See proposition about what happens when deficit spending is Barro (1987), Bernheim (1987) and Aschauer (1988). Also, substituted for at an unchanged expenditure level. see Evans (1988), Koray and Hill (1988) and Leiderman Second, in a rational expectations framework, only unan- and Razin (1988) for more recent work that is not sum- ticipated changes in deficits should affect macroeconomic marized in the three surveys. For some very recent work variables, and there is no plausible way to isolate the on this issue, see Feldstein and Elmendorf (1990), unanticipated component of deficits from these annual Modigliani and Sterling (1990) and Kormendi and Meguire data. Third, the deficit measures used here are not (1990). Most of the empirical evidence against the Ricar- cyclically adjusted. Hence, they are endogenous, at least dian view is at the microeconomic level using cross- in part. sectional or panel data. 2 The reader is cautioned that the evidence presented here can be considered suggestive for only a couple of is the price of credit, it is deter- I)J:tIH:1(lJflFSt)JF;i%T1)t. mined by the supply and demand for credit. Ac- cording to the traditional view, an increase in Total saving has two components: public and the deficit increases the demand for credit private saving. Public saving measures the relative to the supply and, consequently, in- government’s surplus or deficit position: sur- creases the interest rate.7 pluses represent positive public saving, while deficits represent public dissaving. In the Keynes- IlPe:JicIis tDId th.e Tracts iJeiic~ii ian view, deficits can be used to offset gaps between saving and investment, thereby stabiliz- The effect of deficits on credit demand can ing output around its potential (full-employment) also affect the relationship between government level. For example, if private saving is too high deficits and the trade deficit. The effect of relative to investment to achieve potential out- deficit changes on interest rates depends on the put, a government deficit will reduce the amount slope of the credit supply curve—the steeper of total saving and close the gap between saving the slope, the larger the effect on interest rates. and investment. Conversely, if private saving is Among other things, the slope of the credit too low relative to investment, a government supply curve depends on the degree of open- surplus can increase total saving. Hence, cyclical ness of the nation’s money and capital markets swings in economic activity arising from move- to the rest of the world- In general, the more ments in the saving/investment gap can be open these markets are, the flatter is the supply shortened by changing public saving appropri- of credit. ately to maintain total saving at a level consis- tent with potential output. To see this more easily, let’s recast the discus- sion in terms of the demand for securities. In •L~~t~:f/.(5anti .i’n’vateSavi.ng this framework, the price of bonds and, hence, the interest rate are determined by the supply The above analysis is based on the assumption and demand for bonds. The bond and credit that public and private saving are separate and markets are related inversely: those who supply distinct activities.’ In the extreme, they are credit are demanding bonds while those who viewed as totally independent: changes in public demand credit are supplying bonds. If financial saving have no direct effect on private saving 4 markets are open and competitive, the demand and vice versa. In this case, total saving will curve for bonds seen by individual bond sup- change one-for-one with changes in public sav- pliers, including the government, is flat at the ing. In the less extreme case, total saving is market price of securities. In other words, no simply positively correlated with public saving.’ matter how many bonds that individuals, firms or the government may supply, individually, Lktti/ICttS ~SFt/%4:n,iEflt’SL .Hatat; they see no effect on the market price of bonds In the conventional view, increases in the and, hence, on the interest rate. All market par- deficit cause the interest rate to rise.° Since the ticipants, including the federal government, are

‘The following discussion is based on the standard lS/LM °Thediscussion here abstracts from the possible effects of -aggregate supply model of the deficits on the rate of inflation, so the hypothesized effect macroeconomy, where deficit spending is treated as in this section is on the real interest rate. exogenous. 4 ‘Most standard IS/LM aggregate demand-aggregate supply Also, deficits can have an indirect effect on saving if the models assume that there is no direct effect of the in- increase in the deficit spending raises real and, crease in the deficit on private savings; however, this hence, saving. Likewise, if a shift in the saving or invest- assumption is not necessary to obtain the usual implica- ment functions cause a change in income, the deficit will tions. All that is required is that the direct effect on private respond endogenously because both expenditures and savings (if the effect is to increase it) be less than the in- taxes are related to the level of income. Hence, the crease in the deficit. Also, the effect on the interest rate assumption that the series are independent applies to their would be small if the monetized debt to autonomous components. keep real interest rates low. While this is a controversial 5 Strictly speaking, the above conclusion holds as long as issue, the evidence for the U.S. suggests that the Federal public and private savings are not perfect substitutes. Reserve has not monetized the debt. See Thornton (1984). Note, however, is used to offset changes in This discussion abstracts from the effect of the deficit on private savings, there may be a negative correlation bet- interest rates via a deficit-induced increase in the rate of ween public and private savings even, if at a more inflation. abstract level, the series are unrelated. That is, there may be a policy reaction function where deficits respond, presumably with a lag, to changes in private savings. open, there may be no (zero) correlation be- tween government deficits and interest rates, but there may be a positive correlation between Figure 1 Price Level and Output Determination the government and trade deficits. Price The strength of this correlation depends on Level the degree of openness of financial markets. If financial markets are only partially open or ap- proximated by the competitive model, the government deficit will be positively correlated p 2 with both the interest rate and the trade deficit.

p

Pt The effect of deficits on economic activity can be illustrated in terms of the aggregate de- mandiaggregate supply model. The traditional view asserts that increases in the deficit will in- crease the demand for goods and services, as il- lustrated in figure 1. The extent to which the increase in aggregate demand affects output or prices is determined (among other things) by the slope of the aggregate supply curve. The Output steeper the slope of the aggregate supply curve, the larger the effect on the price level and the smaller the effect on output. If the aggregate supply curve were vertical, the deficit would af- “small” relative to the total market, that is, each fect only the price level. is a price-taker.”~Thus, if the economy is suffi- Economic theory and empirical evidence sug- ciently open, the money and capital markets are gest that the aggregate supply curve is upward- competitive and the government is a price-taker, sloping in the short run.°If this is true, there changes in deficit spending will have no effect should be a positive correlation between deficits on the interest rate. Increases or decreases in and both prices and output. the supply of bonds will be fully absorbed at the current market price. This does not mean, however, that deficit spending has no effect on the economy. In the In addition to the positive effects of deficits above case, the deficit will be matched by on output, it is often suggested that deficits can foreign claims on U.S. assets. That is, there will affect output adversely because of their impact be a capital inflow which, given the balance-of- on interest rates. In a closed economy, some payments identity, must be matched by a trade argue, the deficits raise the real interest rate deficit. Hence, if the economy is “sufficiently” and, thereby, “crowd out” private investment.bo

eThis argument also applies to the Federal Reserve’s con- results from a full-employment assumption. The only way trol over real interest rates in an open economy, and may that the government can spend more is for the private sec- have implications for the Fed’s control over interest rates tor to spend less. That is, interest rates must rise to in- in a closed” economy as well. crease private savings by the amount of the decrease in 9 public savings. The much-hypothesized adverse effects of The “long run” tends to mean different things in government deficits in the neoclassical view come either macroeconomics depending on the context in which it is used. In the present ISILM aggregate demand-aggregate through current government consumption replacing private supply framework, it means the period of time for all investment or the assumed lower marginal productivity of wages and prices to adjust to exogenous shocks. If all public capital (see footnote ii). In any event, no explicit wages and prices adjust instantaneously, the aggregate distinction between the conventional and neoclassical supply curve would be vertical for all time periods. Hence, views is made in the text because they are comparable in the positively sloped aggregate supply curve in this model their implications (though certainly not with the full- employment assumptions). results from some imperfections” which keep wages and prices from adjusting instantaneously to shocks. ‘°Bernheim(1989) and others call this the neoclassical view. In the neoclassical framework, crowding out necessarily Other things the same, the degree of crowding For deficits to really be considered infla- out will be larger, the more responsive interest tionary, they must generate continuing in- rates are to deficit spending and the more creases in the price level. In terms of the ag- responsive investment spending is to changes in gregate demand and supply curves, deficits the interest rate. Thus, the larger the effect of would have to cause the aggregate demand deficits on interest rates, the smaller should be curve to keep shifting to the right at a faster the effect on current output. Even with this rate than the aggregate supply curve. This crowding out effect, however, deficits and out- could happen only if deficits become persistent- put are still expected to be positively corre- ly larger over time, or if they are being mone- lated—at least in the short run.” tized (producing increases in the rate of money growth). The dynamic aspect of inflation, how- — >“ <. ever, requires a permanent rise in the rate To be confused about the effect of deficits on of money growth in response to the larger inflation and the price level is easy; therefore, it deficit.” is important to understand and recognize the distinction between these effects. The fun- damental distinction can best be seen by noting ~ >.trl,.flLc.t’ that the price level is measured at a specific 11it11:ttFtDI/tN 511 T~flT5!TYi5 point in time, while inflation is measured over An alternative view of the effects of deficit an interval. According to the conventional view, an increase in the deficit increases aggregate de- spending is called Ricardian equivalence. Unllke the Keynesian view, which sees public and mand and, hence, the price level. Because ad- private saving as essentially unrelated, the justments in the price level take place over Ricardian view sees them as perfect substitutes.” time, such changes are reflected in the mea- According to this view, changes in public saving sured rate of inflation during the period of price adjustment. Other things the same, however, are matched by an equal but opposite change in private saving. This fundamental difference prices eventually will adjust to their new higher manifests itself in the answer to the question: Is level after which no further price changes will part of society’s net wealth? be forthcoming. Consequently, while deficit spending may affect the price level permanent- In the Keynesian view, the answer is “Yes,” ly, it has only a temporary affect on the rate of while the Ricardian alternative would answer inflation. “No.” According to the Keynesian view, when

1 2 ‘ Some people fear that deficits could have some longer- ‘ Deficits can sustain inflation if the monetary authority at- term adverse effects due to crowding out. They argue that, tempts to peg the nominal interest rate [see Friedman if deficits lead to higher interest rates and lower invest- (1968)J or if deficits become explosive. In the latter case, ment, society will be left with a smaller capital stock, the ratio of interest-bearing government debt to output in- which, in turn, means that future output will be smaller creases without limit forcing the monetary authority to than it would have been in the absence of deficit-financed monetize the debt. See Sargent and Wallace (1981) and expenditures. Consequently, in the short run, deficits and Miller and Sargent (1984) for a discussion of these points output are expected to be positively correlated. In the long and McCallum (1984) for a qualification. run, however, they may be negatively correlated, or at “This is merely a convenient, equivalent characterization. least negatively correlated with output growth. There is an Ricardian equivalence stems directly from an intertemporal implicit assumption in this argument about the nature of resource constraint. That is, for a given path of expen- public expenditures or the relative productivity of “public” ditures, a cut in present taxes necessarily implies an in- and “private” capital. To see this, note that the supply of crease in future taxes of equal present value. If an in- output, Y,, is a function of labor, L,, and the capital stock, dividual’s demand for goods and services depends on his K,, i.e., Y, f(L,, K,). ‘after ” net worth—the present value of assets, the Output rises with both labor and the stock of capital. present value of liabilities and the present value of Consequently, if a deficit-induced rise in interest rates taxes—a fall in current taxes would necessarily be match- causes investment to fall in this period, the next period’s ed by an increase in the present value of future taxes. capital stock will be smaller, as will the next period’s out- Since a budget deficit merely rearranges the timing of the put. This assumes that all of the rise in the deficit was us- tax liability, it cannot affect aggregate demand. The ed for current consumption. Alternatively, aggregate output decrease in public saving (the deficit) must be matched by could be expressed as a function of labor and the public an increase in private saving. and private capital stocks, K”, and K”,, respectively, i.e., Strictly speaking, however, Ricardian equivalence holds V = h(L., K”,, K”,). If the rise in the deficit is used to ac- only for a given path of government expenditures. There quire public capital, the immediate effect on output is in- can be real effects associated with changing the level or determinant even in the case of complete crowding out, timing of real government expenditures. i.e., the decline in private capital from what it would have otherwise been is equal to the increase in public capital. See Aschauer (1989a, 1989b). 29

Figure 2 The Trade Deficit and the Government Deficit

Trade Delicil

15

10 10

0

—5

—10 —15 —It —9 —5 —3 0 3 5 Governmenl Delicil the government issues debt, the holder of the from a rise in deficit spending will be offset by debt views it as an asset; but taxpayers do not a decrease in aggregate demand due to the fall view it as their liability. That is, they do not in private spending—that is, there is no net believe that they will have to pay current or change in aggregate demand. future taxes to service or retire the debt. Conse- Because the Ricardian view holds that changes quently, their saving behavior is unaffected by in deficit have no net effect on the excess de- the debt issuance. mand for credit or aggregate demand, deficits The Ricardian view, on the other hand, as- should be uncorrelated with interest rates, the serts that individuals believe that they, or their trade deficit, the price level, output or total sav- heirs, will have to pay taxes to service and re- ing. Deficits and private saving, however, should tire the increased debt. Because they perceive be perfectly, positively correlated. an increase in the present value of their taxes that just offsets deficit-financed expenditures, the stock of government debt is not part of so- Ehl/II3.IIIICAL EVIIJIENCE ciety’s net wealth. Hence, a rise in the deficit (a fall in public saving) will be matched by a rise The evidence presented here consists of sim- in private saving in anticipation of future taxes. ple scatter plots between the government deficit and the trade deficit, personal saving, real out- If public and private saving are perfect sub- put growth, the price level, the inflation rate stitutes, a decline in public saving—the increase and the nominal interest rate for 16 OECD in the deficit—is offset by an increase in private countries.’4 (A more detailed statistical analysis saving, with no effect on the gap between sav- consistent with these scatter plots is presented ing and investment. According to this view, in the appendix). The currency-denominated then, deficit spending cannot be used to smooth variables are expressed as a percent of the out cyclical variations in economic activity due country’s gross domestic product, GDP, to put to exogenous swings in the gap between saving them in common units, and all variables are ad- and investment. Moreover, the increased de- justed for their mean values.’~ mand for credit due to deficit spending will be matched by an increase in the supply of Figure 2 shows the relationship between the credit due to an increase in private saving. Also, so-called twin deficits: the trade and the govern- the increase in aggregate demand that results ment deficits. The scatter plots show that there

4 15 ‘ The countries are: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, These are pooled time-series cross-sectional data, where Finland, France, Greece, Great Britain, West Germany, the average level is allowed to vary each year. See the ap- Ireland, Japan, Norway, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland pendix for details. and the United States. The interest rate was not available for Austria, Canada, Finland or Greece. is a weak (but statistically significant) positive there is no statistically significant relationship association between the two deficits. This between the deficit and these variables.’~Conse- association is consistent with both the conven- quently, the cross-sectional data provides little tional view and U.S. time-series data.’6 Barro or no support for the conventional view. On the (1987), however, finds that the positive associa- other hand, support for the Ricardian alternative tion exists for U.S. time-series data only when is not overwhelming. While the lack of signifi- data for the 1980s are included- This instability cant relationships between the deficit and in- is evident for these cross-sectional data as well. terest rates, the trade deficit, output, prices, When the sample includes only observations for inflation and economic growth is consistent with the earlier period, 1975-80, there is no signifi- the Ricardian view, the lack of a statistically cant positive relationship between the twin significant positive relationship between the deficits. These data are presented in figures 3, government deficit and private saving is not. In- while data for the later period, 1981-86, are deed, if deficits and private saving are perfectly, presented in figure 4. Moreover, further analy- positively correlated because public and private sis suggests that the statistically significant posi- saving are perfect substitutes, a positive rela- tive relationship does not hold up if other factors tionship between these variables should have are considered (see the appendix). been apparent. Thus, at best, the evidence pre- sented here should be interpreted as cautiously Figure 5 shows the relationship between per- favoring the Ricardian view. sonal saving and the government deficit. The strictest form of the conventional view argues that these series should be unrelated, while the Ricardian alternative argues that they should be Whether the evidence presented here is taken perfectly, positively correlated. Neither view is to support, however cautiously, the Ricardian supported by these cross-sectional data. Instead, alternative, the most interesting result is the there is a statistically significant negative rela- lack of evidence to support the conventional tionship between these variables. This anomalous view. In particular, the evidence suggests that result may stem from the response of both the countries with large government deficits do not deficit and personal saving relative to GDP to have higher interest rates or larger trade defi- cyclical movements in output. For example, it is cits despite the widespread opinion to the con- well-known that deficits typically rise relative to trary. Of course, these puzzling results could be GDP as output falls and vice versa. If consumers an artifact of the simple measures of deficit attempt to maintain their living standard in the spending used here. If the relationships between face of a temporary decline in output, personal government deficits and either interest rates or saving would fall relative to output. Consequent- the trade deficit were as strong as many com- ly, personal saving and government deficits rela- mentators suggest, however, it is odd that they tive to GDP should be negatively correlated over do not emerge in these annual data across coun- the business cycle. In any event, the statistically tries. These results, coupled with the fact that significant negative relationship supports neither more sophisticated empirical studies using U.S. hypothesis.’~ time-series data have also failed to uncover the conventional relationships, should perhaps lead Figures 6-9 show the relationship between the advocates of the conventional view either to re- government deficits and inflation, output growth, think their position or present some evidence to the price level and interest rates. In all cases, support their claims. 15 5ee Barro (1987) and Dewald and Ulan (1990). Dewald ventional view—contradicts the Ricardian equivalence and Ulan argue that the observed positive association bet- paradigm. Such an extreme view is unwarranted. ween the twin deficits in U.S. time-series data results from 18 failing to account for inflation or changes in the market There are two exceptions when first-differences are used. The one of some importance for the conventional wisdom value of the U.S. federal debt or other major elements of is the positive and statistically significant relationship be- the U.S. net external wealth position. This argument, however, requires a different definition of the deficit than tween the deficit and output growth, suggesting that larger the one used in the conventional stories of the effects of government deficits have at least some initial positive ef- deficits on economic variables. fect on real output. Of course, if the rise in the deficit is 17 due to an increase in , there is a Recently, Swamy, Kolluri and Singamsetti (1990) have sug- positive relationship between the deficit and GDP by gested that finding any statistically significant relationship definition. See the appendix for details. between the deficit and interest rates—although the sign of the coefficient is opposite that hypothesized by the con- 111’ I 91 (91 .919 .441:1 I 1944 1491 .1’ ‘44 44i4~ 44 14 4)4 4$) 444 dl I II $9 P3 94 N 44 WI IN 1. -11i444 —I:ii 1411 CD~ 194 0 ,0 :r~~ 4*4: 944 (DC 49 a o C 4141 944 g~3 • -l~ —Is 444: ~L°’ I’ ~ 4j: u~ I 49 0 e o 49 P it 49 CD $~ ~. 941 .~ 44 C’ 444 Z 944 C’ 9 441, ; 44 ~I 444 0’ 44. ~ 44’4 a 4’ ~ 441 — ‘4 ‘0 ~. Ill’ ~ 44,4 o 111 CD 4144 C) P o ‘4 o $~‘ 0 ~in CD $4 ~Ir — is — 414 P31 11444 o~ 3: CD 441 9. 9! 4114 ~ — 141 oh’ o o 1: o 41dl:~ CD ‘144 Vt 2.~ 4% 9, — .44 0

- 44 0(0 dl

~ .— 4$a I (0 44. i’ll 94 0 44° 0 91

144

(4. 99 4,

II, a ‘1

4%’ ‘cdi

.1 441

ii 4444

444 I 14~ $14’ 4’44

till 414%

44 $141’ •4444

‘94

:41, Figure 6 The Rate of Inflation and the Government Deficit Rote of notation Rate of Inflation

It It

to ID

o 5

o 0

5 5

— v “‘ 10 —It —42 —9 —6 —2 036 Government Deficit

Figure 7 The Growth Rate of Real GDP and the Government Deficit

—It —52 —9 —6 —3 Government Deficit

Figure 8 The Price Level and the Government Deficit

Pnce Level Price Level

it LI

10 1.0

05 0.5

00 0.0

-0.5 —it —14 —11 —It —t —6 4 —2 0 2466 It Goterilment Deficit 3-3

Figure 9 The Interest Rate and the Government Deficit ittereot Rete inferett itetet

is to

5 0

0 0

—Ia ‘ if —15 42 —9 6303 9 Government Detc,t

144)’ FEB EN{1~ES

Aschauer, David. “The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal Revisited: Comment,’ American Economic Review (June Policy,” Journal of Money Credit and Banking (February 1990), pp. 589-99. 1988), pp. 41-62. Friedman, Milton. “The Role of :’ American ______“Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private Capital?” Economic Review (March 1968), pp. 1-17. Journal of Monetary Economics (September 1989a), PP Koray, Faik, and R. Carter Hill. “Money, Debt and Economic 171-88. Activity:’ Journal of Macroeconomics (Summer 1988), pp.

______- “Is Public Expenditure Productive?” Journal of 351-70. Monetary Economics (March 1989b), 177-200. Kormendi, Roger, and Philip Meguire. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and Private Sector Behavior: Reply Barro, Robert J. The Ricardian Approach to Budget and Update[ American Economic Review (June 1990), pp. Deficits, Henry Thornton Lecture, City University Business 604-17 School, London, November 1987. Laumas, Gurcharan S. “Anticipated Federal Budget Deficits, Bernheim, B. Douglas. “Ricardian Equivalence: An Evalua- Monetary Policy and the Rate of Interest:’ Southern tion of Theory and Evidence:’ NBER Working Paper No. Economic Journal (October 1989), pp. 375-82. 2330 (July 1987). ‘ Leiderman, Leonardo, and Assaf Razin. Testing Ricardian ______- “A Neoclassical Perspective on Budget Deficits,” Neutrality with an Intertemporal Stochastic Model” Journal Journal of Economic Perspectives (Spring 1989), pp. 55-72. of Money, Credit and Banking (February 1988), pp. 1-21. Chrystal, K. Alec, and Daniel L. Thornton. “The McCallum, Bennett T. “Are Bond-Financed Deficits Infla- Macroeconomic Effects of Deficit Spending: A Review,” this tionary? A Ricardian Analysis:’ Journal of Political Economy Review (November/December 1988), pp. 48-60. (February 1984), pp. 123-35. Darrat, Au F. “Fiscal Deficits and Long-Term Interest Rates: Miller; Presten J., and Thomas J. Sargent. ‘A Reply to Dar: Further Evidence from Annual Data:’ Southern Economic by, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Journal (October 1969), pp. 363-74. (Spring 1984), pp. 21-26. Modigliani, Franco, and Arlie G. Sterling. “Government Dewald, William G., and Michael Ulan. “The Twin-Deficit Illu- Debt, Government Spending, and Private Sector Behavior: sion[ Working Paper No. 90-17, U.S. Department of State, A Further Comment:’ American Economic Review (June Bureau of Economic and Business Affairs (February 1990). 1990), ~. 600-03. Evans, Paul. “Are Consumers Ricardian? Evidence for the Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. “Some Unpleasant United States,” Journal of Political Economy (October 1988), Monetarist Arithmetic:’ Federal Reserve Bank of Mm- pp. 983-1004. neapolis Quarterly Review (Fall 1981), pp. 1-17.

______- “Interest Rates and Expected Future Budget Swamy, Paravastur A. V. B., Bharat R. Kolluri and Rao N. Deficits in the United States:’ Journal of Political Economy Singamsetti. “What Do Regressions of Interest Rates on (February 1987), pp. 34-58. Deficits Imply?” Southern Economic Journal (April 1990),

______- “Is the Dollar High Because of Large Budget pp. 1010-28. Deficits?” Journal of Monetary Economics (November Tatom, John A. “U.S. Investment in the 1980s: The Real 19B6), pp. 227-49. Story,” this Review (March/April 1989), pp. 3-15. Feldstein, Martin. and Douglas W. Elmendorf. “Government Thornton, Daniel L. “Monetizing the Debt,” this Review Debt, Government Spending, and Private Sector Behavior (December 1984), pp. 30-43. 34

4/ 44 -‘ - /4 1/

/ 4/ ~/4 /-

- ‘V , ‘,~ - ~/V ~

The purpose of this appendix is to see if there tions a,, = a and /3,, = /3 for all i and t, to is a statistical association between government obtain deficits and some important macroeconomic variables as hypothesized by both the conven- (A.4) DV,, = a + /3DEF,, + tional view and the Ricardian alternative. (This is equivalent to imposing the restrictions The analysis begins with the following general a, = a and /3, = /3 for all i on the time-series equation: model or a, = a and /3, = /3 for all t on the cross-sectional model).

(A1) DV, a,, + j3 DEF,, + E~,, i=1,..., K, and 5 Equations A.2-A,4 were estimated with annual observations on the government deficits, nomi- t=1,..., T, nal interest rate, the trade deficit, the price level (1980 = 100), the inflation rate, real output where DV,, and DEF,, denote the t” observation growth and private saving for 16 OECD coun- for the P” country of the dependent variable tries (K=16) for which the relevant annual data and the deficit measure, respectively, a,,, and /3,, are available.1 The period is from 1975 to 1986 denote fixed parameters and s,, denotes a ran- (T= 12). Because the currency-denominated dom error. variables are expressed in the respective coun- Equation A.1 cannot be estimated because the try’s currency, it is necessary to put these data number of parameters exceeds the number of in common units. This was done by measuring observations. This problem can be circumvented these variables as a percent of gross domestic 2 by obtaining time-series and/or cross-section product, GDP. representations of equation Al. The time-series representation is obtained by imposing the The equations were estimated both in levels and first-differences. The latter form was restrictions a5 = a, and /3,, /3, for all t. The cross-sectional representation is obtained by im- estimated because some of the data showed a tendency to trend with time. The sample was posing the restrictions a,, = a0 and /3,, = /3, for all i. These specifications are: too small, however, to perform the usual tests for stationarity. Estimates of first-order autocor- relation from equation A,2 suggest that first- (A.2) DV,, = a, + /3,DEF,I + ~,0 differencing may result in over-differencing in and many cases. Because some of these data ap-

(A.3) Dy, = a + J3,DEF,, + E,~. peared to have trends, the pooled time-series! 0 0 cross-section equation, A.4, was estimated by A pooled time-series/cross-section representa- allowing the intercept term to vary with time.3 tion can be obtained by imposing the restric- Because the estimates of equations A.2 and A.3

4 The interest rate is the three-month money market rate. ~Thereported intercepts in tables A.1 and A.2 are for 1986. 2This was also done by measuring these variables relative The equations were also estimated using a time trend. The results with this variable were not qualitatively different to their mean value for the period and indexing them to from those that allowed for a time-varying intercept. Con- 1975. When the variables were normalized in this way, a sequently, they are not reported here. Also, the equations measure of the level of GDP was also used as a depen- were estimated using the alternative dependent variables dent variable. In nearly all cases, estimates of equations as regressors. Except for the interest rate, however, the A.2 and A.3 resulted in insignificant coefficients on the qualitative results were unaffected, so these results are deficit measure, so the results are not reported here. not presented here. Also, the OECD data are based on the system of na- tional accounts which differs in a number of respects from our system of national income and product accounts. One of these is that capital expenditures by government are not treated as current expenditures, so that the deficit is current expenditures plus consumption of fixed capital less revenue. are qualitatively the same as those of equation U.S. external wealth position. When adjustments A.4, only estimates of equation A.4 are for these factors are made, they find no statisti- presented. cally significant relationship between the two deficits. Because this argument might apply to

.44444 fl.44-$-/U44-~ cross-sectional data as well, caution should be used in interpreting these results as evidence of Estimates of equation A.4 for both levels and 4 the conventional wisdom on the twin deficits. first-differences are reported in table Al. The This is especially true because the estimated only coefficients that are statistically significant coefficient on the deficit is not large: a 1 in both the level and first-difference specifica- percentage-point rise in the government deficit tions occur when the trade deficit or private relative to GDP would result in only about a .20 saving is the dependent variable. In the latter percentage point rise in the trade deficit relative case, however, the coefficient was negative, to GDP. Moreover, as shown later, the result is which suggests that increases in deficit spending not robust. are associated with decreases in personal sav- ing: when public saving decreases, so does The statistical significance of the coefficient private saving. This result is not consistent with on the deficit when inflation or the price level the Ricardian view that public and private sav- is the dependent variable depends on whether ing are substitutes; however, it might reflect an the equation is estimated in levels or first- endogenous response of both government differences, being insignificant in the former deficits and personal saving to cyclical variations case and significant in the latter. In either case, in output. It is well-known that deficits tend to however, the coefficient has a sign opposite that rise relative to GDP when output falls. Likewise of the conventional story. Consequently, these it might be that personal saving also rises when results are not evidence for or against either of output falls, as individuals try to maintain their these views. level of consumption in the wake of declining income levels. In this case, personal saving The same result occurs when the growth rate would decline relative to GDP. The simultaneous of GDP is the dependent variable. In this case, response of both government deficits and per- however, the conventional wisdom does not sonal saving to cyclical variation in income state the direction of the expected change. From could account for the statistically significant a short-run perspective, output growth should negative coefficient on the deficit when per- be positively related to deficits. From a long-run sonal saving is the dependent variable. perspective, they should be negatively related. The results in table A.1 suggest a positive rela- Barro (1987) also found a positive and statisti- tionship if first differences are used, with a 1 cally significant relationship between the two percentage-point increase in the deficit being deficits using U.S. data, but stated that this re- associated with a quarter of a percent increase lationship emerges only when data for the 1980s in the rate of growth of GUP. Of course, if the were included. When the sample was partitioned increase in the deficit is due to an increase in into 1975-80 and 1981-86 periods, a positive government spending, there is a positive rela- relationship emerged between the twin deficits tionship between deficits and GDP by definition, during both periods; however, consistent with if crowding out is not complete. the findings of Barro, the relationship was not Estimates of the effect of the deficit on in- statistically significant during the first period.~ terest rates also are sensitive to the specification Dewald and Ulan (1990) argue that the posi- of the equation. When levels are used, there is tive relationship between the twin deficits in a negative, but statistically insignificant, relation- the U.S. results from failing to account for infla- ship between interest rates and the deficit. tion or changes in the market value of the net When first-differences are used, however, there U.S. federal debt or other major elements of the is a positive and statistically significant (a one-

~ltwas assumed that variance was constant over time, but statistic of 1.42. The comparable statistics for the second differed over cross-sections, that is, E(r./)= c’, for i=j period are .307 and 3.52, respectively. The same statistics and t=s and 0 otherwise. Estimates of equation A.2 in- for the two periods for the first-difference specification are dicated considerable cross-sectional heteroskedasticity. .094 and 1.37 and .226 and 3.01, respectively. 5 The estimated coefficient on the deficit variable during the first period for the level specification was .181, with at- Table A.1 Pooled Time-Series, Cross-Sectional Estimates of Equation A.4 Levels First difference Dependent Deficit Deficit

variab constant - measure .9?~!!,nt - measure

Trade deficit — 1.396’ 0.195’ -0.453 0127’ (2.43) (2.42) (1.43) (2.26) Personal saving 9.163’ —0.44V 0.197 —0.170’ (14 25) (6.59) (0.77) (3.43) Output growth 2.34r —0.060 —1.206’ 0.244 ~5.67~ ft34~ ~287~ ~3.73~ Inflation 4.444’ —0.061 0.327 —0.154’ (5.76) (0.77) (1.70) (4.40)

Price level 1 517’ —0.002 0.07 —0.004’ (75.44) (1.17) (12.11) (3.58)

Interest rate 8.120 —0.020 —0.886 0.246’ (10.89) (0.28) (1.96) (1.95)

- Indicates statistical significance at the 5 percent level.

tailed test at the 5 percent significance level) attributable to two countries, Greece and Nor- relationship between the two variables. Even if way. Also, the reported results could be due to one takes the results that are most supportive the failure to account for other factors that af- of the conventional wisdom, however, the effect fect the relevant dependent variable. Both issues of deficits on interest rates is fairly weak: a 1 are investigated in table AZ, which reports the percentage-point rise in the deficit relative to results of estimates of the first-difference speci- GDP is estimated to produce about a25 basis- fication when Greece and Norway are deleted point rise in nominal interest rates. and, alternatively, when all other variables are included as regressors.6 As the table shows, the results are sensitive to both of these changes. - 4~ Deficits are not significantly related to the price While the results for the first-difference specifi- level or interest rates when the two countries cation appear to indicate statistically significant are deleted and no longer have a statistically relationships between the government deficit and significant effect on the trade deficit, the price all of the dependent variables, these relationships level or the interest rate when the other van- are not as strong as the results in table A.1 would ables are included. The only significant effects suggest. Scatter plots of the first-differenced data, that are robust to these changes are those for mean-adjusted, are presented in figures A.1-A.6. the effect of the deficit on private saving, out- These data suggest that much of the reported put growth and inflation. In the first and last statistically significant relationship could be due to case, however, the sign of the coefficient is op- a relatively few outliers. In most cases, these are posite that suggested by the conventional view.

CAll other variables save the interest rate, since the interest rate was unavailable for Austria, Canada, Finland and Greece. Figure Al Change in The Trade Deficit and the Government Deficit

Trade Dei,c,t Trade Def,dt

Ia - -- ‘0

O ----— 0

4- .4- --

a ------0

-4 - 4 4 4 — -4 —04\ ------4 - -- -4---- —5

4 -4 -4 — - 10 4 —- -- —10 —30 —27 —IS —0.2 0.0 21 33 4.5 57 Government Dcccii

-4/4 / /4 - /4 - / ‘V / ~ / 4V/ Figure A2 Change in Personal Saving and the Government Deficit

Pertonti Savine Pertonsi Se,tng

6 a

4/ ~-4/4 -- ~ 1V~-, ‘V’V ~ —-~—~.

4 — — 4- ___/ — — — 4

‘V -~- ~ -4~A-444 / 4-4/- /4/ 2 ‘V - ~-V/4 ~\45 /4 -~- 4-4444 2 V - - - ‘/4- 4- -- - 1~- 0 -- - 4 -- -- - 0 -- 44 — ,, 4-4 ----4 -4- — - 44 - ‘44 --- -4 - -- - -

-- 44 - / / - -4—2 / -4- -\ - 4/-

-4- —4 -- _ / 4/ 4/ -- - —4

—e - --4 - -44- - - — -4 -4 —e 44

—a - -—0 —30 —27 IS —a oe 21 32 45 57 Government Oet’dt

- ~~—‘V/ --4 ~/4 / / - / / -/4/4 / _/// /4/4 Figure AS Change in the Inflation Rate and the Government Deficit Rare of In4tatinn Rate or tnnat’on

O — — 0

o .4- 4, 0

0 * —5

—10 —10

1S

—20 20 —20 —27 —IS —03 09 21 33 4.5 07 Government Deficit

- /4 ~ -4/4/44 -4/4 //~// / — - - / / ---/4 -/44/ - // ( -44 Vi U

:4/44

‘/4 a 4/—

-r N —

/ *

/ / 44 / * 14/ -44 0 0 44 ~// 44440 U 44:4/ — U :4>40 44 0 / N 0 / V-4~V /44/4/44/ 44 — / 0 44/il: C * / 144 E 44/4/C 419 0 N :0 E // C a. -4/ I- 114 0 /44(044 -a > / / / 1444— 0 / 4/; 0 0

U ~ // l~~1 V /* -U

2 1 / / * -4/: It ~ U I -~ / / / / , 4lJs ~- ‘74 0 / * 41, ‘4 .9 /4 141 H 144’ / 44£ 11191 / --4- 0 494- / .4,4- 4 a 1-4/4. 2° lV44~. — / 2 : (119 ‘1944/ — // /4~- 44 C /// a’ E //4 0 /~/ /4- oE a 4 ‘74/ ~/ - / 14/, ~ 44/ 44 C 0 4/19~ ,, -a - -4-4 4, am Lt~ -: 44/-LLO LL0~

11 I

.4/

44-i 4 Table A. 2 Estimates of Two Alternative First-Difference Specifications Greece and All alternative dependent Norway deleted variables included Dependent Deficit Deticit variable constant variable constant variable

Trade deficit —0611 e 0 128’~ 0.072 0.013 (2.03) (222) (0 21j (0.23) Personal savng 0.312 —0.143 0400 —0.213’ (1 28) (2 97) (1 63) (4.55)

Output growth —1 .056~ 0342’ — 0.930’ 0.330 (2.31) (4.01) (226) (4.66)

Inflation 0378 —0126’ 0112 —0093 (1.94) (3 65) (0.54) (2.63)

Price level 0.051 - —0.002 0.062 —0.001 (7.91) (1.73) (6.81) (095)

Interest rate —1.093’ 0 128 — 0.934 0.090 (2.29) (0.78) (1 95) (0.61) indicates statistical significance at the 5 percent level