The Specie Standard As a Contingent Rule: Some Evidence for Core and Peripheral Countries, 1880-90

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Specie Standard As a Contingent Rule: Some Evidence for Core and Peripheral Countries, 1880-90 A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Bordo, Michael D.; Schwartz, Anna J. Working Paper The Specie Standard As A Contingent Rule: Some Evidence for Core and Peripheral Countries, 1880-90. Working Paper, No. 1994-11 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Rutgers University Suggested Citation: Bordo, Michael D.; Schwartz, Anna J. (1994) : The Specie Standard As A Contingent Rule: Some Evidence for Core and Peripheral Countries, 1880-90., Working Paper, No. 1994-11, Rutgers University, Department of Economics, New Brunswick, NJ This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/94338 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu THE SPECIE STANDARD AS A CONTINGENT RULE: SOME EVIDENCE FOR CORE AND PERIPHERAL COUNTRIES, 1880-1990 Michael D. Bordo Anna J. Schwartz Department of Economics National Bureau of Economic Research Rutgers University 269 Mercer Street, 8th Floor New Brunswick, New Jersey 08903 New York, New York 10003 and N.B.E.R Paper prepared for: Historical Perspectives on the Gold Standard: Portugal and the World. Editors: Barry Eichengreen, Jorge Braga de Macedo and Jaime Reis. Draft: August 1994 1. Introduction The classical gold standard era from 1880 to 1914, when most countries of the world defined their currencies in terms of a fixed weight (which is equivalent to a fixed price) of gold and hence adhered to a fixed exchange rate standard, has been regarded by many observers as a most admirable monetary regime. They find that its benefits include long-run price level stability and predictability, stable and low long-run interest rates, stable exchange rates (McKinnon, 1988), and hence that it facilitated a massive flow of capital from the advanced countries of Europe to the world's developing countries. Others have taken a less favorable view of the gold standard's performance. Some criticize the record of relatively high real output and short-term price variability (Bordo, 1981; Cooper, 1982; Meltzer and Robinson, 1989), and some have faulted it for subordinating domestic stability to the maintenance of external convertibility (Keynes, 1930). A persistent critique of the gold standard is that it provided a favorable experience for the core countries (England, France, Germany, and the United States), but a less favorable experience for the peripheral countries of the developing world (De Cecco, 1974). For the core countries the balance of payments adjustment mechanism was stable, so few crises occurred; the peripheral countries, by contrast, were subject to shocks imported under fixed exchange rates from abroad and frequently suffered exchange rate crises and a destabilized growth pattern. An alternative approach to these issues of gold standard history posits that adherence to the fixed price of specie, which characterized all convertible metallic regimes including the gold standard, served as a credible commitment mechanism to monetary and fiscal policies that otherwise would be time inconsistent (Bordo and Kydland, 1992; Giovannini, 1993). On this basis, adherence to the specie standard rule enabled many countries to avoid the problems of high inflation and stagflation that troubled the late twentieth century. The specie standard that prevailed before 1914 was a contingent rule, or a rule with escape clauses. Under the rule specie 1 convertibility could be suspended in the event of a well understood, exogenously produced emergency, such as a war, on the understanding that after the emergency had safely passed convertibility would be restored at the original parity. Market agents would regard successful adherence as evidence of a credible commitment and would allow the authorities access to seigniorage and bond finance at favorable terms. On this view, the core countries were good players of the classical gold standard game - - they adhered strictly to the rule, whereas many peripheral countries were not. Some never adhered to the rule. Others joined it when conditions were favorable to them ostensibly to obtain access to capital from the core countries, but they quickly abandoned it when economic conditions deteriorated. The interwar gold standard can be regarded as an extension of the pre-1914 system because it was based on gold convertibility. However, it was less successful because the commitment to convertibility was often subordinated to other politically induced objectives. The Bretton Woods international monetary system can be regarded as a distant relative of the classical gold standard in that the center country, the United States, maintained gold convertibility. It was also based on a rule with an escape clause -- parities could be changed in the event of a fundamental disequilibrium. However, it differed from the basic specie standard rule in that a credible commitment to the fixed parity was not of such primary importance. This paper surveys the history of the specie standard as a contingent rule from the early nineteenth century when most countries were still on a bimetallic or silver standard until the gold standard's final collapse in the late 1930s. As a comparison we also briefly consider the Bretton Woods system and the recent managed floating regime. We then present some evidence on the economic performance of the core and a number of peripheral countries under the various regimes. 2 Section 2 defines the contingent specie standard rule and discusses how the commitment to convertibility was maintained. Section 3 presents and discusses a chronology of adherence to the rule by 21 countries under variants of the specie standard prevailing before World War II. A similar chronology is included for the Bretton Woods system. Section 4 offers some graphical evidence on capital flows 1865 to 1914 from England to two countries of recent settlement -- Argentina and the United States -- during episodes of both suspension and adherence to convertibility. It suggests that adherence to the rule may have had some influence on the decision by England to invest abroad. Section 5 presents evidence on economic performance for 21 countries (both core and peripheral) across several regimes. Such evidence may shed light on whether differing economic performance can explain why some countries successfully adhered to the rule and others did not, or whether adherence/nonadherence may have influenced performance. We examine the stability of both nominal and real macro variables across four regimes (pre-1914 gold standard; interwar gold standard; Bretton Woods; the subsequent managed exchange rate float). We then present measures of both demand shocks (reflecting policy actions specific to the regime) and supply shocks (reflecting shocks to the environment independent of the regime). These measures allow us to determine whether adherents to the rule consistently pursued different policy actions from nonadherents, and whether persistent adverse shocks to the environment may, for some countries, have precluded adherence to the rule. The paper concludes with answers to the questions: how successful was the specie standard rule as a contingent rule; why it was successful when it was; and why some countries adhered while others did not. 2. The Specie Standard as a Contingent Rule 2.1 The Domestic Gold Standard A specie standard has been traditionally viewed as a form of monetary rule or constraint over monetary policy actions. Following a rule, such as adherence to the specie standard, which 3 would cause the money supply to vary automatically with the balance of payments, was viewed as superior to entrusting policy to the discretion of well-meaning and possibly well-informed monetary authorities (Simons, 1951).1 In contrast to the traditional view, which stresses both impersonality and automaticity, the recent literature on the time inconsistency of optimal government policy regards a rule as a credible commitment mechanism binding policy actions over time. The absence of a credible commitment mechanism leads governments, in pursuing stabilization policies, to produce an inflationary outcome (Kydland and Prescott, (1977); Barro and Gordon, (1983). In a closed economy environment, once the monetary authority has announced a given rate of monetary growth, which the public expects it to validate, the authority then has an incentive to create a monetary surprise to either reduce unemployment or capture seigniorage revenue. The public, with rational expectations, will come to anticipate
Recommended publications
  • Gold As a Store of Value
    WORLD GOLD COUNCIL GOLD AS A STORE OF VALUE By Stephen Harmston Research Study No. 22 GOLD AS A STORE OF VALUE Research Study No. 22 November 1998 WORLD GOLD COUNCIL CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ..............................................................................3 THE AUTHOR ..............................................................................................4 INTRODUCTION..........................................................................................5 1 FIVE COUNTRIES, ONE TALE ..............................................................9 1.1 UNITED STATES: 1796 – 1997 ..................................................10 1.2 BRITAIN: 1596 – 1997 ................................................................14 1.3 FRANCE: 1820 – 1997 ................................................................18 1.4 GERMANY: 1873 – 1997 ............................................................21 1.5 JAPAN: 1880 – 1997....................................................................24 2 THE RECENT GOLD PRICE IN RELATION TO HISTORIC LEVELS....28 2.1 THE AVERAGE PURCHASING POWER OF GOLD OVER TIME ................................................................................28 2.2 DEMAND AND SUPPLY FUNDAMENTALS ............................31 3 TOTAL RETURNS ON ASSETS ..........................................................35 3.1 CUMULATIVE WEALTH INDICES: BONDS, STOCKS AND GOLD IN THE US 1896-1996 ....................................................35 3.2 COMPARISONS WITH BRITAIN ..............................................38
    [Show full text]
  • China Economic Issues
    China Economic Issues Number 7/07, November 2007 The Potential of the Renminbi as an International Currency Hongyi Chen and Wensheng Peng This paper assesses the potential significance of the renminbi as an international currency by drawing on the experiences of the other major currencies. We estimate an empirical model relating currency shares of reserve holdings to economic determinants such as the size of the economy and financial market, stability of the currency value and network externalities. A counter-factual simulation of the model using China’s data suggests that the renminbi’s potential as a reserve currency could be comparable to that of the British pound and Japanese yen if the currency were to become fully convertible today. An international currency is ultimately a market choice, but government policies on currency convertibility can facilitate or inhibit the process. In this respect, the authorities need to weigh the benefits and risks associated with an international role of the renminbi in policy formulation and implementation. As the size of the economy and financial market increases and the monetary policy framework including exchange rate flexibility becomes more firmly established, the benefits should increasingly dominate costs. The potential international role of the renminbi and associated benefits and costs should be part of policy considerations on the pace and form of financial liberalisation and capital account opening. Hong Kong, being an international financial centre of China, can play an important role in the development and opening up of the Mainland financial market. The renminbi business in Hong Kong provides a testing ground for the use of the renminbi outside Mainland China.
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Policy in the Bretton Woods Era I
    54 I Allan H. Meltzer Allan H. Meltzer is a professor of political economy and public policy at Carnegie Mellon University and is a visiting scholar at the American Enterprise Institute. This paper; the fifth annual Homer Jones Memorial Lecture, was delivered at Washington University in St. Louis on April 8, 1991. Jeffrey Liang provided assistance in preparing this paper The views expressed in this paper are those of Mr Meltzer and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. U.S. Policy in the Bretton Woods Era I T IS A SPECIAL PLEASURE for me to give world now rely on when they want to know the Homer Jones lecture before this distinguish- what has happened to monetary growth and ed audience, many of them Homer’s friends. the growth of other non-monetary aggregates. 1 am persuaded that the publication and wide I I first met Homer in 1964 when he invited me dissemination of these facts in the 1960s and to give a seminar at the Bank. At the time, I was 1970s did much more to get the monetarist case a visiting professor at the University of Chicago, accepted than we usually recognize. 1 don’t think I on leave from Carnegie-Mellon. Karl Brunner Homer was surprised at that outcome. He be- and I had just completed a study of the Federal lieved in the power of ideas, but he believed Reserve’s monetary policy operations for Con- that ideas were made powerful by their cor- gressman Patman’s House Banking Committee.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tax-Foundation Theory of Fiat Money
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Goldberg, Dror Working Paper The tax-foundation theory of fiat money Working Paper, No. 2009-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University Suggested Citation: Goldberg, Dror (2009) : The tax-foundation theory of fiat money, Working Paper, No. 2009-05, Bar-Ilan University, Department of Economics, Ramat-Gan This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/96068 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Tax-Foundation Theory of Fiat Money Dror Goldberg Department of Economics Bar Ilan University Abstract A government can promote the use of an object as the general medium of exchange by accepting it in tax payments.
    [Show full text]
  • Internationalisation of the Renminbi
    Internationalisation of the renminbi Haihong Gao and Yongding Yu1 Introduction Over the past three decades, China’s fast economic growth and its increasing economic integration with the world have led to a significant increase in its influence in the world economy. During the Asian financial crisis of 1997–98, China was praised as a responsible country, because of its efforts in maintaining the stability of the renminbi while many other countries in the region had devaluated their currencies. It was the first time that China itself, as well its Asian neighbours, started realising China’s emerging influence. Like it or not, China is no longer an outsider in global financial events. This is not only because China is now the world’s third largest economy and second largest trading nation, but also because it holds the largest amount of foreign reserves in the world. Since the Asian financial crisis, China has been faced with three major tasks with regard to its international financial policies. The first is the reform of the global financial architecture. The second is the promotion of regional financial cooperation, which consists of two components: the creation of a regional financial architecture and the coordination of regional exchange rate arrangements. The last is internationalisation of the renminbi. It is fair to say that, over the past 10 years or so, the most discussed issue in China has been regional financial cooperation. Although the result is still highly unsatisfactory, together with its East Asian neighbours China has achieved some tangible results, built on the basis of the Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI).
    [Show full text]
  • The Emergence of Fiat Money: a Reconsideration
    THE EMERGENCE OF FIAT MONEY: ARECONSIDERATION Kevin Dowd One of the fundamental questions in monetary economics is why fiat money has value: Why do rational agents trade real resources for intrinsically worthless pieces of paper? Monetary economists have long understood that part of the explanation relates to the superiority of a monetary equilibrium over a barter one. However, it is one thing to explain why fiat money is better than barter, and quite another to explain how fiat money actually emerges. Recognizing this point, a number of recent studies (e.g., Kiyotaki and Wright 1991, 1992, 1993; Ritter 1995; and Williamson and Wright 1995)1 have sought to explain the emergence of fiat money by means of a hypothetical direct jump from barter to a fiat money equilibrium.2 This paper suggests that these attempts are fundamentally miscon- ceived. They suffer from three main problems. The first is the “start problem”3—that is, the difficulty of ensuring an initial demand for fiat money balances. If fiat money is ever to emerge from barter, someone must be the first to exchange real goods for pieces of paper money that, by definition, do not provide any direct consumption Cato Journal, Vol. 20, No. 3 (Winter 2001). © Cato Institute. All rights reserved. Kevin Dowd is Professor of Financial Risk Management at Nottingham University Business School. He thanks Charles Goodhart and George Selgin for very helpful correspondence on the issues discussed in this paper. The usual caveat applies. 1Some of the issues raised in this literature are also discussed by Goodhart (1997) and Selgin (1993, 1994, 1997).
    [Show full text]
  • Shanghai Pilot Free Trade Zone: a Test for Renminbi Internationalization?
    Journal of Governance and Regulation / Volume 6, Issue 3, 2017 SHANGHAI PILOT FREE TRADE ZONE: A TEST FOR RENMINBI INTERNATIONALIZATION? Han Long * * Law School, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, Wuhan, Hubei, China Abstract How to cite this paper: Long, H. (2017). China(Shanghai)Pilot Free Trade Zone (“SHFTZ”) as well as other Shanghai Pilot Free Trade Zone: A Test For Renminbi Internationalization? Pilot Free Trade Zones established in China carries on the mission Journal of Governance & Regulation, 6(3), to make the test for, inter alia, China’s strategic financial reforms 55-66. doi: 10.22495/jgr_v6_i3_p6 and for Renminbi(“RMB”) internationalization in particular. How to access this paper online: However, the financial reforms in SHFTZ according to its design and http://dx.doi.org/10.22495/jgr_v6_i3_p6 relevant provisions can only provide very limited rather than fully effective test for the reforms of free convertibility, international Copyright © 2017 The Author capital transactions as well as risk hedging needed by RMB This work is licensed under the Creative internationalization. The aim of the paper is to investigate the test Commons Attribution-NonCommercial effect that SHFTZ have on the above capital account reforms. It 4.0 International License (CC BY-NC 4.0) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/b argues that the main reason for the test failure lies in “outward free y-nc/4.0/ and inward control” mode designed for SHFTZ which makes it an insulated customs territory, a situation which differs from the ISSN Online: 2220-9352 ISSN Print: 2306-6784 circumstances in which a currency gets internationalized.
    [Show full text]
  • Credibility, Currency Convertibility and the Stabilisation of the Rouble
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Hofmann, Volker; Sell, Friedrich L. Article — Digitized Version Credibility, currency convertibility and the stabilisation of the rouble Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Hofmann, Volker; Sell, Friedrich L. (1993) : Credibility, currency convertibility and the stabilisation of the rouble, Intereconomics, ISSN 0020-5346, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, Baden-Baden, Vol. 28, Iss. 1, pp. 11-16, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02928096 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/140380 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu SYSTEM TRANSFORMATION Volker Hofmann and Friedrich L. Sell* Credibility, Currency Convertibility and the Stabilisation of the Rouble The measures taken so far to move towards currency convertibility and combat inflation in Russia and the other CIS countries are based largely on a three-stage programme formulated by the IMF.
    [Show full text]
  • Cryptocurrencies and Monetary Policy
    IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS Requested by the ECON committee Cryptocurrencies and monetary policy Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Authors: Grégory Claeys, Maria Demertzis, Konstantinos Efstathiou (Bruegel) Directorate-General for Internal Policies EN PE 619.011 PE 619.0181 - June 2018 Cryptocurrencies and monetary policy Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Abstract Decentralised ledger technology has enabled cryptocurrencies to become a new form of money that is privately-issued, digital and that permits peer-to-peer transactions. However, the current volume of transactions in such cryptocurrencies is still too small to make them serious contenders to replace official currencies. Underlying this are two factors. First, cryptocurrencies do not perform the role of money well, because their value is very volatile and they are thus not very good stores of value. Second, cryptocurrencies are managed in ways that are very primitive compared to what modern currencies require. These shortcomings might be corrected in the future to increase the popularity and reach of cryptocurrencies. However, those that manage currencies, in other words monetary policymakers, cannot be outside any societal system of checks and balances. For cryptocurrencies to replace official money, they would have to conform to the institutional set up that monitors and evaluates those who have the power to manage money. This document was provided by Policy Department A at the request of the Economic and Monetary Affairs Committee. ` This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. AUTHORS Grégory CLAEYS, Bruegel Maria DEMERTZIS, Bruegel Konstantinos EFSTATHIOU, Bruegel ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Dario PATERNOSTER EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees and other parliamentary bodies in shaping legislation and exercising democratic scrutiny over EU internal policies.
    [Show full text]
  • The Euro As an International Currency Agnès Bénassy-Quéré
    The euro as an international currency Agnès Bénassy-Quéré To cite this version: Agnès Bénassy-Quéré. The euro as an international currency. 2015. halshs-01144371 HAL Id: halshs-01144371 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01144371 Preprint submitted on 21 Apr 2015 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. The euro as an international currency Agnès BENASSY-QUERE Paris School of Economics University Paris 1 April 2015 G-MonD Working Paper n°41 For sustainable and inclusive world development The euro as an international currency Agnès Bénassy-Quéré1 March 2015 Abstract. The euro, in spite of having many of the required attributes put forward by the theoretical literature and past experience, has failed to fulfill all the criteria that would enable it to rival the dollar as an international currency. This does not mean that the euro cannot achieve a status similar to that of the dollar; however, the window of opportunity may not last much more than a decade before the renminbi overtakes the euro. European monetary unification has never explicitly sought for its currency to gain an international status. This makes sense insofar as the key elements required for the euro to expand internationally are also those to be pursued internally: GDP growth; a fiscal backing to the single currency; a deep, liquid and resilient capital market; and a unified external representation of the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • The Digitalization of Money∗
    The Digitalization of Money∗ Markus K. Brunnermeier Harold James Princeton University Princeton University Jean-Pierre Landau Sciences Po August 2019 Abstract The ongoing digital revolution may lead to a radical departure from the tradi- tional model of monetary exchange. We may see an unbundling of the separate roles of money, creating fiercer competition among specialized currencies. On the other hand, digital currencies associated with large platform ecosystems may lead to a re-bundling of money in which payment services are packaged with an array of data services, encouraging differentiation but discouraging interoperability between platforms. Digital currencies may also cause an upheaval of the international mon- etary system: countries that are socially or digitally integrated with their neighbors may face digital dollarization, and the prevalence of systemically important platforms could lead to the emergence of digital currency areas that transcend national borders. Central bank digital currency (CBDC) ensures that public money remains a relevant unit of account. Keywords: Digital Money, Digital Currency Area, Digital Dollarization ∗Contact: [email protected]. We are grateful to Joseph Abadi for his numerous contributions to this project. 1 1 Introduction Digitalization has revolutionized money and payments systems. Although digital money itself is not new to modern economies, digital currencies now facilitate instantaneous peer-to-peer transfers of value in a way that was previously impossible. New currencies will emerge as the central lynchpins of large, systemically important social and economic platforms that transcend national borders, redefining the ways in which payments and users’ data interact. The advent of these new monies could reshape the nature of cur- rency competition, the architecture of the international monetary system, and the role of government-issued public money.
    [Show full text]
  • Bank'of'england'and'the'banque'de' France'during'the'napoleonic'wars Jagjit's
    UNIVERSITY OF CAMBRIDGE Cambridge Working Papers in Economics ’Midas,transmutingall,intopaper’:the BankofEnglandandtheBanquede FranceduringtheNapoleonicWars JagjitS.ChadhaandElisaNewby CWPE 1330 ‘Midas, transmuting all, into paper’: the Bank of England and the Banque de France during the Napoleonic Wars Jagjit S. Chadhay Elisa Newbyz September 2013 Abstract This paper assesses Revolutionary and Napoleonic wartime economic policy. Suspension of gold convertibility in 1797 allowed the Bank of England to nurture British monetary orthodoxy. The Order of the Privy Council suspended gold payments on Bank of England notes and afforded simultaneous protection to the government and the Bank in pursuit of the conflicting goals of price stability and war finance. The government, the Bank of England and the commercial banks formed a loose alliance drawing on due political and legal processes and also paid close attention to public opinion. We suggest that the ongoing solvency of the Bank of England was facilitated by suspension and allowed the Bank to continue to make substantial profits throughout the Wars. It became acceptable for merchants to continue to trade with non-convertible Bank of England notes and for the government to finance the war effort, even with significant recourse to unfunded debt. These aspects combined to create a suspension of convertibility that did not undermine the currency. By contrast, the Assignats debacle had cost the French monetary system its reputation in the last decade of the 18th century and so Napoleonic finance had to evolve within a more rigid and limiting framework. JEL Classification: C61, E31, E4, E5, N13 Keywords: Monetary Orthodoxy, Suspension of Convertibility, War Finance Acknowledgements: Jagjit Chadha is grateful to Morris Perlman (In Memoriam) for his many insights on the Bullionist Controversy.
    [Show full text]