CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

MATTHEW SMITH DANNY YAGAN OWEN ZIDAR ERIC ZWICK

How important is human at the top of the U.S. income distribution? A primary source of top income is private “pass-through” profit, which can include entrepreneurial labor income for reasons. This article asks whether top pass-through profit mostly reflects human capital, defined as all inalienable factors embodied in business owners, rather than financial capital. Tax data linking 11 million firms to their owners show that top pass-through profit accrues to working- age owners of closely held mid-market firms in skill-intensive industries. Pass- through profit falls by three-quarters after owner retirement or premature death. Classifying three-quarters of pass-through profit as human capital income, we find that the typical top earner derives most of her income from human capital, not financial capital. Growth in pass-through profit is explained by both rising productivity and a rising of added accruing to owners. JEL Codes: D31, E01, H2, J3, L26.

[The human capital hypothesis] is far less consequential than one might imagine. ...“non-human” capital seems almost as indis- pensable in the twenty-first century as it was in the eighteenth or nineteenth, and there is no reason why it may not become even more so. —THOMAS PIKETTY (2014)

∗ This work does not necessarily reflect the views of the U.S. Treasury Depart- ment. We thank Alan Auerbach, Tom Brennan, Jediphi Cabal, Curtis Carlson, Raj Chetty, Steve Cicala, Michael Cooper, Roger Gordon, John Guyton, Bob Hall, Barry Johnson, Greg Kaplan, Steve Kaplan, Henrik Kleven, Pat Kline, Adam Looney, James Mackie, John McClelland, Kevin Murphy, Neale Mahoney, James Pearce, Jim Poterba, Rich Prisinzano, Emmanuel Saez, Jesse Shapiro, David Splinter, Larry Summers, Mike Weber, Matt Weinzierl, Gabriel Zucman, and anonymous referees as well as seminar and conference participants for helpful conversa- tions. We thank Tom Cui, Katie Donnelly Moran, Clancy Green, Sam Karlin, Stephanie Kestelman, Carl McPherson, Francesco Ruggieri, Karthik Srinivasan, John Wieselthier, and Caleb Wroblewski for excellent research assistance. Zidar and Zwick gratefully acknowledge financial support from Chicago Booth’s Initia- tive on Global Markets (IGM), the Kauffman Foundation, and Chicago Booth. Zidar also gratefully acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation under grant number 1752431, and Zwick gratefully acknowledges financial sup- port from the Neubauer Family Foundation, the Polsky Center, and the Hultquist Faculty Research Endowment at Chicago Booth.

C The Author(s) 2019. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the President and Fellows of Harvard College. All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email: [email protected] The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2019), 1–72. doi:10.1093/qje/qjz020.

1 2 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 I. INTRODUCTION In the last few decades of the twentieth century, the primary driver of rising top incomes was wage income growth (Piketty and Saez 2003). Since then, rising capital income has shifted focus to the role of capital and financial wealth (Piketty, Saez, and Zucman 2018).1 Understanding the nature of top incomes is essential for explaining their evolution and assessing policy implications. Are America’s top earners financial-capital rich—those who derive most of their income from nonhuman capital—or are they human-capital rich—entrepreneurs and wage earners who derive most of their income from their human capital? This article uses deidentified administrative tax data to char- acterize top incomes and their rise in the twenty-first century. Throughout, we measure income using directly observed fiscal in- come from tax returns following Piketty and Saez (2003) and im- puted national income following Piketty, Saez, and Zucman (2018) (PSZ).2 We first establish how much top earners make from three broad sources: wage income, business income, and other capital income such as and rent payments. In 2014, most income at the very top is nonwage income, the primary source of which is business income. Most top business income comes from private “pass-through” that are not taxed at the entity level; instead, income passes through to the owners who pay on their share of the firm’s income. This feature allows us to build a new data set linking pass-through firms (S- and partnerships, de- fined below) to their owners for 11 million firms between 2001 and 2014. This data set enables us to ask whether top pass-through income should primarily be thought of as human capital income accruing to entrepreneurs or as financial capital income accru- ing to . We define human capital broadly to refer to all

1. Piketty (2014) analyzes how can lead to increasing inequality. Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014) document rising capital shares. Saez and Zucman (2016) use capitalized income flows to show that wealth con- centration in the United States has been increasing, in contrast to the flat path of wealth concentration based on estate tax returns in Kopczuk and Saez (2004). Piketty and Zucman (2014) document rising capital-output ratios. Rognlie (2016) and Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas (2017) discuss interpretations. 2. Fiscal income equals total tax return income minus realized capital gains and is measured at the household level. Imputed national income (“Distributional National Accounts”) includes additional imputed components of national income and is measured at the individual level. Section II contains more detail. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 3 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 inalienable factors embodied in business owners, including labor supply, networks, reputation, and rent-extraction ability. Over- all, we find that top earners are predominantly human-capital rich rather than financial-capital rich, and that 52% of top 1% income accrues to the human capital of these wage earners and entrepreneurs. The first part of the article describes who earns business in- come and the salient features of their firms. The data reveal a striking world of business owners who prevail at the top of the income distribution. Most top earners are pass-through business owners. In 2014, over 69% of the top 1% and over 84% of the top 0.1% earn some pass-through business income. In absolute terms, that amounts to over 1.1M pass-through owners with fis- cal income over $390K and 140,000 pass-through owners with fiscal income over $1.6M. In both number and aggregate income, these groups far surpass that of top public executives, who have been the focus of much inequality commentary (see Edmans and Gabaix 2016 for a survey). Typical firms owned by the top 1–0.1% are single-establishment firms in professional ser- vices (e.g., consultants, lawyers, specialty tradespeople) or health services (e.g., physicians, dentists). A typical firm owned by the top 0.1% is a regional business with $20M in sales and 100 em- ployees, such as an auto dealer, beverage distributor, or a large law firm. Most pass-through business income accrues to undiversified, working-age owners of mid-market firms in skill-intensive indus- tries. Specifically, an individual’s pass-through income typically derives from one firm with one to three owners and amounts to a large share of her total income. The age distribution of these owners closely mirrors that of high-income wage earners; in con- trast, the owners of more passive forms of capital skew much older. Most pass-through business income derives from firms with $5M to $500M in sales operating across diverse geographies and sec- tors. Despite this diversity, most profits are earned in relatively labor-intensive industries, especially in those that demand skilled labor. In contrast, non-pass-through businesses (C-corporations) are more prevalent in manufacturing and capital-intensive in- dustries, with profits concentrated among firms with more than $500M in sales. Together, these facts support the notion that most top pass-through earners are human-capital rich. The second part of the article uses quasi-experimental event studies to quantify the extent to which pass-through profits reflect 4 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 returns to owner human capital rather than to nonhuman finan- cial capital. The ideal experiment would be to measure the profit impact of exogenously forcing pass-through owners to withdraw their human capital from their firms. We approximate this ideal with two natural experiments: one measures the profit impact of owner deaths and another measures the profit impact of owner retirements. In the first natural experiment, we identify nonelderly own- ers who died 2005–2010 and who earned over $1 million in the year before their death. We then match their firms to similar coun- terfactual firms that did not experience an owner death. Profits at owner-death firms track counterfactual firms closely in the prepe- riod and then fall immediately and persistently upon owner death. The effect is an 82% decline in firm profits. In the second natural experiment, we study the event of owner retirement, inferred when the firm transitions from four straight years of paying at least one owner W-2 wages to two years of paying no owner wages. The presumption is that these owners replace themselves with nonowner managers whose compensa- tion is entirely reported as wages and bonuses, not profits. Profits at owner-retirement firms track counterfactual firms closely in the preperiod then fall immediately and persistently upon owner retirement. The effect is an 83% decline in firm profits. Our base- line specification is equal weighted. Dollar-weighted approaches deliver similar estimates, although the standard errors increase with dollar-weighting. Averaging our estimates across top 1%, million-dollar-earner, and top 0.1% groups, we conclude that ap- proximately three-quarters of top pass-through profits are returns to owner human capital. Pass-through owners have a tax incentive to receive their compensation as profits rather than wages and bonuses, whereas owners of traditional C-corporations do not. We find that firms that switch from C- form to pass-through form reduce wage bills and increase profits. This result provides evidence con- sistent with a tax explanation of pass-through profits reflecting returns to owner human capital. We use our three-quarters estimate for the labor (human cap- ital) share of pass-through income to conduct a person-level ana- lysis of top earners. Is the typical top earner a human capitalist or a financial capitalist? That is, if you run into a very high earner on the street, does she likely earn most of her income from labor or CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 5 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 from capital? When ignoring pass-through income, a minority of top earners are human-capital rich. However, when defining labor income as wages plus three-quarters of pass-through income, this assessment reverses: most top earners are human-capital rich, not financial-capital rich. For example, among million-dollar earners in imputed national income, 67% derive most of their income from labor income, but only 35% derive most of their income from wages alone. Hence, the human capital component of pass-through in- come transforms one’s view of the typical top earner. Some individuals with wage and pass-through income may provide little human capital services, perhaps drawing a salary or ownership share from a family firm as a way to avoid estate taxes. To address this consideration, we use the parent-child links of Chetty et al. (2019) to classify whether individuals aged 32–34 are “self-made,” which we conservatively define as top earners whose parents were not in the top 1%. These individuals are unlikely to receive large financial inheritances or inter vivos gifts. We find that more than 75% of top earners in the parent-linked sample are self-made. We also use our three-quarters estimate to conduct a novel ag- gregate analysis of top income. How much is labor income? How much is entrepreneurial income (pass-through income plus W-2 wages paid to owners)? How do these amounts compare with other income components? While dollar-level aggregates are more un- certain, two findings stand out. First, holding other assumptions constant, our classification of three-quarters of pass-through in- come as labor income reduces the top capital share in imputed national income by 7 percentage points from 55% to 48%.3 Sec- ond, top entrepreneurial income and its human capital compo- nent are large. In every top income group and income definition, entrepreneurial income rivals or exceeds both nonowner wage in- come and non-pass-through capital income. The human capital component of entrepreneurial income itself exceeds top public equity income. To complement our cross-sectional analysis of top incomes, we conclude by investigating the evolution of top entrepreneurial

3. PSZ’s top 1% capital share is 55% in their Figure VIII, Panel B (based on data in Online Appendix Table TB2f, which they use to discuss our article in their Online Appendix C.2). PSZ also report an alternative top 1% capital share of 59% in their Figure VIII, Panel A which draws on data in their Online Appendix Table TB2d that allocates more pension income to capital for top earners. 6 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 income, which has risen substantially over time. We use our linked firm-owner-worker data to decompose the growth of top en- trepreneurial income and shed light on how it has increased since 2001. Approximately 30% of the growth in entrepreneurial in- come reflects businesses reorganizing from C-corporation to pass- through form. Adjusting for this fact, we find no role for a larger workforce in driving higher entrepreneurial income. Instead, both labor productivity and a rising share of value added accruing to owners account for the growth of top entrepreneurial income. Thus, explaining the rise of top entrepreneurial income requires both a growing pie and an expanding owner-manager slice. This study’s main contribution is to the income inequality lit- erature. Piketty and Saez (2003) use fiscal income to show that labor drove the rise in top incomes in the second half of the twenti- eth century. PSZ use imputed national income to find that capital has been driving the rise since 2000 in top income and now ex- ceeds labor income at the top. An innovation of our article relative to past work is that we use microdata to ask person-level and dollar-level questions. PSZ’s focus is a dollar-level analysis of top incomes, but their findings raise the possibility that the financial- capital rich have displaced the human-capital rich as the typical top earner.4 However, we find that the typical top earner is human- capital rich. This finding depends crucially on how one treats top pass-through income—a large component of top “capital” income and 30% to 40% of top 1% income. We classify 75% of pass-through income as human capital income. In contrast, PSZ assume a labor share of 0% for one type of pass-through income (S-corporation) and 70% for the rest (partnership and other pass-through). Our approach also affects conclusions about the composition of top incomes (i.e., for dollar-level questions). Under our ap- proach, the top 1% labor share of imputed national income in 2014 increases from 45.4% in PSZ to 52.1%. Of the 6.8 percentage point change, the S-corporation adjustment contributes 4.9 percent- age points, the partnership and other pass-through adjustment contributes 1.1 percentage points, and correcting an inaccurate

4. PSZ occasionally provide person-level interpretations of their results: “[In] the post-World War II decades, most top earners derived their income from . From the 1970s and 1990s, the fraction of top earners deriving their income from work grew. This process culminated in 2000. . . Since then, the capital share has bounced back” (Piketty, Saez, and Zucman 2018, 595–597, emphasis added). CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 7 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 extrapolation in PSZ contributes 0.9 percentage points.5 Applied to the time series, our classification yields qualitatively similar re- sults to PSZ: the top 1% labor share rose from the 1960s, peaked in 2000, and then returned to 1990 levels. Our findings draw attention to a class of entrepreneurs hid- den from public view who prevail among top earners and whose human capital income is key for understanding top incomes. An important role for human capital is consistent with the view that the demand for top human capital has outpaced its supply, with the returns to top human capital increasingly taking the form of business income.6 However, we stress that returns to top owner- managers need not be socially optimal and can include returns to unproductive behavior like rent-seeking (Krueger 1974; Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny 1991) or returns to elite connections (Fisman 2001; Khwaja and Mian 2005; Zimmerman 2019). For the literature on rising firm profitability, we provide ev- idence on the relative impact of productivity growth and the distribution of surplus between workers, managers, and own- ers. Our finding that productivity explains an important part of entrepreneurial income growth aligns with recent work empha- sizing the role of efficiency improvements in driving firm prof- itability (Autor et al. 2017; De Loecker and Eeckhout 2017). En- trepreneurial income is also increasing due to a rising share of value added accruing to owners. In our data, the owners appear to be managers and key workers, which contrasts with the sep- aration of ownership and control in governance. Thus, our results point to channels other than zero-sum bargain- ing between executives and corporate boards for rising owner pay.7 Our results inform three other literatures. First, a long- standing literature debates the relative importance of inherited wealth versus self-made wealth (Kotlikoff and Summers 1981;

5. In 2014, top 1% total income amounts to $3T in imputed national income, so these three adjustments amount to $149B, $33B, and $27B, respectively. See Section II and Online Appendix D for additional discussion. 6. See Katz and Murphy (1992), Autor, Katz, and Kearney (2008), Goldin and Katz (2009),andMurphy and Topel (2016) for some prominent articulations of this view. Kaplan and Rauh (2013) argue that the broad-based rise in top incomes reflects market-driven forces, such as an increased return to skill. 7. Gabaix and Landier (2008), Piketty, Saez, and Stantcheva (2014),and Piketty (2014) highlight the role of bargaining for the growth of top executive pay among public and other with delegated management. See Edmans and Gabaix (2016) for a survey of executive pay trends. 8 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Modigliani 1986; Piketty 2011; Piketty, Postel-Vinay, and Rosenthal 2014). We use parent income to infer whether individu- als are likely self-made. Second, we find that firm-level variation in profitability amplifies measured top income inequality among firm owners, and much of their human capital returns take the form of profits rather than wages.8 Third, we contribute to a literature on the impact of taxes on economic measurement, the composition of top incomes, and corporate organization, which we discuss in the conclusion.9 Last, we make two methodological contributions that may im- prove distributional income and wealth estimates. First, the On- line Appendix explores alternative methods for imputing retained earnings to individuals. Second, top wealth estimates based on capitalized income flows and a constant returns assumption can be improved by accounting for the higher profitability of top-owned firms. The article is organized as follows. Section II describes the institutional background and data. Section III documents the im- portance of pass-through income for top income inequality, and then presents descriptive statistics on the prevalence of top pass- through ownership and the sizes and industries of those busi- nesses. Section IV presents event studies, which estimate whether and the extent to which pass-through profits reflect the return to owner human capital. Section V uses these estimates to charac- terize top earners as human-capital rich or financial-capital rich, to estimate the share of top earners that are self-made, and to quantify top income shares by income source. Section VI ana- lyzes the evolution of top entreprenuerial income and the contri- butions of changing labor productivity, scale, and factor shares. Section VII concludes.

8. An active literature documents firm- and industry-level variation in prof- itability and links firm performance and wage inequality (Hall 1988; Foster, Haltiwanger, and Syverson 2008; Hsieh and Klenow 2009; Syverson 2011; Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis 1999; Card, Heining, and Kline 2013; Song et al. 2019) as opposed to income inequality, which includes business income. Fagereng et al. (2016) document heterogeneous and persistent returns in Norway, finding a key role for closely held firms at the top of the income distribution. 9. See, for example, Gordon and MacKie-Mason (1994), Slemrod (1996), MacKie-Mason and Gordon (1997), Gordon and Slemrod (2000), Alstadsaeter et al. (2016), Auten and Splinter (2018), DeBacker and Prisinzano (2015), Cooper et al. (2016), Clarke and Kopczuk (2017), Prisinzano and Pearce (2017),andDyrda and Pugsley (2018). CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 9 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 II. INSTITUTIONAL BACKGROUND AND DATA II.A. How U.S. Businesses Are Organized and Taxed There are three major types of formal businesses: C- corporations, S-corporations, and partnerships. All three forms provide limited liability to their owners, but they differ in their ownership rules, tax treatment, and profit measurement. C- corporations and partnerships may be owned by individuals, busi- nesses, nonprofits, and foreigners, whereas S-corporations face ownership restrictions. Firms with more than 100 owners, with owners who are not U.S. individuals, or with more than one class of cannot be S-corporations. These restrictions bar public com- panies and corporations with complex ownership structures (such as venture capital–financed startups) from being S-corporations. Separate restrictions also bar almost all partnerships from be- ing publicly traded. Prominent pass-throughs include the Hobby Lobby Corporation, home improvement retailer Menards, Fidelity , and the U.S. arm of PricewaterhouseCoopers. C-corporations pay the corporate income tax on annual tax- able income, and taxable shareholders pay taxes on div- idends and pay capital gains taxes on gains realized from sell- ing shares. S-corporations and partnerships, collectively known as pass-through businesses, pay no entity-level tax. Instead, tax- able business income “passes through” to shareholders’ tax re- turns where it is taxed as ordinary income in the year it is earned by the firm. When actually distributed to owners, pass- through are untaxed. Since 1986, pass-through income typically has enjoyed a lower tax burden than C-corporation income.10 As a result, most businesses—even those with over $500 million in revenue—are now pass-throughs and most tax- able business income is pass-through income, even though almost no pass-throughs are publicly traded.11 Among pass-throughs, S- corporations generate more business income than partnerships. Finally, organizational forms differ in how owner compensa- tion is reported on tax returns. The wages of S-corporation owners

10. In the pre-2018 period we study, pass-throughs were strongly tax- advantaged. The 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act reduced taxes on both pass-throughs and C-corporations. There remains a clear tax preference for pass-throughs in some industries and an ambiguous one in others. 11. By 2011, 54.2% of U.S. taxable business income was earned by formal pass-throughs and sole proprietorships (informal businesses also taxed at the owner level) and only 45.8% by C-corporations (Cooper et al. 2016). 10 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 are legally required to be “reasonable” and to reflect the market value of labor services, while profit is supposed to reflect residual earnings. However, in practice, owner-managers enjoy consider- able discretion in how their compensation is categorized as wages or profits. Owner-managers of C-corporations enjoy a lower tax burden when paid in wages, but owner-managers of pass-throughs enjoy a lower burden when paid in profit.12 See Online Appendix A for additional institutional detail.

II.B. Data on Top Incomes We use two data series on the U.S. income distribution 1962– 2014. PSZ assembled these data based on stratified random sam- ples of personal tax returns. Fiscal income is directly observed income on personal tax re- turns. We use the main fiscal income definition of Piketty and Saez (2003) (PS), which measures fiscal income at the level of the tax unit (typically a single adult or a married couple) and equals Form 1040 total income minus realized capital gains, un- employment compensation, and taxable Social benefits. The series includes synthetic records for individuals who do not file income tax returns, thereby reflecting the full U.S. adult population. Imputed national income (“Distributional National Income” in PSZ, sometimes INI) imputes components of national income not observed in personal tax data such as employer-provided health insurance, rent from owner-occupied housing, and C- corporation retained earnings (i.e., earnings not distributed to owners as dividends). We use PSZ’s main definition, which mea- sures pre-tax-and-transfer imputed national income at the level of the individual adult and equally splits each income component between spouses. Imputed national income aggregates across indi- viduals to equal national income (GDP minus capital depreciation plus net income received from abroad) in the National Income and Product Accounts. See Online Appendix C for a comparison of our top pass-through statistics with PSZ’s Online Appendix C.2, and Online Appendix D for a quantitively important correction that

12. Legal rules mandate that most partnership owner compensation be reported as profits even when compensation for labor supply. Owners of C- corporations avoid dividend taxation when paid in wages. Owners of pass-throughs face no and may avoid payroll taxation when paid in profits. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 11 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 we make to the published PSZ data.13 Note that national income includes unrealized capital gains in the form of corporate retained earnings but not in the form of expectations-induced price growth. Integrating such asset price effects into an analysis of inequality is a useful direction for future research. Our analysis considers top 1% earners and several interesting subgroups, including million-dollar earners and the top 0.1%. In 2014, the top 1% and top 0.1% thresholds in the fiscal income series are $390K and $1.58M, respectively and in the imputed national income series are $420K and $1.88M. We add the million- dollar-earner group as a salient midpoint between the top 1% and top 0.1% groups. For each data series, we follow PS and PSZ in defining in- come sources. Within each series, wages plus business income plus other capital income equals total income. For fiscal income, wage income (sometimes “wages”) includes Form 1040 wages, salaries, and tips; pension distributions; and annuities. Pass-through in- come includes S-corporation income, partnership income, and sole proprietor’s income. Entrepreneurial income equals pass-through income plus owner wages, defined in the next subsection.14 Busi- ness income equals pass-through income plus C-corporation div- idends. Other capital income includes interest, rents, royalties, and estate and trust income. For imputed national income, wages includes Form 1040 wages, salaries, and tips; imputed unreported wage compensa- tion; payroll taxes; imputed nontaxable employee benefits like employer-provided health insurance; a portion of sales and ex- cise taxes; and a portion of pension income. Pass-through income includes S-corporation income, partnership income, sole propri- etor’s income, imputed unreported income from unincorporated

13. Some exhibits and numbers in the published version of PSZ, including those described in their Online Appendix C.2 that discusses our article, used an extrapolation for 2011 through 2014 that materially underestimated top pass- through income. We have updated their series based on actual, unextrapolated data. 14. We follow earlier work (e.g., Piketty and Saez 2003) in including all pass-through income as entrepreneurial income, even though some pass-through income accrues to nonfounders. Note that hedge fund and private equity pass- throughs earn much income in the form of dividends, retained earnings, interest, and rental income. Such income retains its character as it flows through pass- through firms and is classified as either C-corporation income or other capital income, not pass-through income, which is exclusively an operating profit concept. 12 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 businesses, a portion of sales and excise taxes, and a portion of cor- porate taxes. Business income equals pass-through income plus C- corporation dividends, imputed C-corporation retained earnings, a portion of sales and excise taxes, and a portion of corporate taxes. Entrepreneurial income equals pass-through income plus owner wages, defined in the next subsection. Other capital income in- cludes interest, imputed underreported interest income, rents, im- puted rental income (including imputed rent from owner-occupied housing), a portion of sales and excise taxes, and a portion of pen- sion income.15 We and PSZ classify wages as labor income (i.e., a return to human capital) and classify other capital income as capital income (i.e., a return to financial or physical capital). An important contribution of our article is an estimate of the share of pass- through income that is in fact labor income rather than capital income. PSZ assume that 0% of S-corporation income is labor income and that 70% of the remainder of pass-through income is labor income. We estimate below that 75% is labor income.16 We present our income distribution findings in both fiscal income and imputed national income. Fiscal income has the advantage of being directly observed on personal income tax returns, but has the disadvantage of understating top capital income because some components do not appear on personal tax returns. Imputed national income has the advantage that it sums to national income, but has the disadvantage of relying on impu- tation assumptions. PSZ employ several assumptions to impute missing national income to individual adults—a path-breaking prototype to which they encourage ongoing refinement. Relevant

15. With reference to PSZ’s top incomes decomposition (their Online Appendix Table TB2f), wages equals compensation of employees plus the labor component of pension income. Pass-through income equals S-corporation dividends plus the cap- ital and labor components of mixed income. Business income equals pass-through income plus C-corporation dividends plus C-corporation retained earnings. Other capital income equals interest and rents plus the capital component of pension income. Our INI replication matches PSZ’s top income totals but allocates slightly less to C-corporation income and slightly more to interest and rents. 16. More specifically, PSZ assume that 70% of the remainder of pass-through income is labor income, but tax adjustments under the assumption that business capital bears 100% of the nonhousing capital tax yields a final tax-inclusive labor share of approximately 65% in recent years (see their Figure VIIIb and Online Appendix Tables TB2b and TB2f). Following their assumptions but using a 75% pretax labor share yields a tax-inclusive labor share of 70% in our imputed national income analysis. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 13 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 to our analysis, we believe the available evidence suggests that imputed national income may overstate top capital income. These competing considerations motivate the presentation of our findings in both series, likely (in our view) bounding the truth. Our qualitative results hold in both series. Top capital income in imputed national income may be overstated because of the following consideration regarding C- corporation retained earnings. When a C-corporation distributes less in dividends than it makes in after-tax income, it retains earn- ings within the firm.17 Those retained earnings ($649B in 2014) are a substantial part of national income but do not appear on per- sonal tax returns and thus are not in fiscal income. PSZ allocate the household share of aggregate retained earnings to individuals in proportion to the sum of the individual’s observed dividends and realized capital gains. The rationale is that when C-corporation income does appear on personal tax returns, it appears as either dividends or realized capital gains. However, published IRS re- ports indicate that at least 25% and as much as 75% of realized capital gains are not from the sale of C-corporate stock and are instead gains from real estate and other asset sales or carried interest. This fact can explain how total realized capital gains ($732B in 2014) vastly exceeds the total household share of re- tained earnings ($306B in 2014). Realized capital gains are much larger than dividends and much more concentrated among top earners. Hence, imputing retained earnings in proportion to each individual’s sum of dividends and 100% of realized capital gains may allocate too much retained earnings to top earners and not enough to lower earners.18 See Online Appendix E forafulldis- cussion and Online Appendix F for retained earnings imputations under alternative assumptions.19

17. Pass-throughs are measured as having no retained earnings, with effec- tively 100% dividends. 18. Saez and Zucman (2016) conduct a related analysis and report wealth estimates using dividends only. Relative to using dividends alone, their Tables B35 and B37 imply that imputing wealth using dividends and 100% of realized capital gains increases 2012 top 0.1% equity wealth by 28%. This adjustment modestly increases total top 0.1% wealth, which is the primary focus of Saez and Zucman (2016), by 9.2% (page 535). 19. It is valuable to note that all imputations have imperfections. For example, imputations of retained earnings based on observed dividends and realized capital gains allocate too little to concentrated owners of C-corporation stock that pay no dividends and are not sold and therefore too much to other owners. Direct links of C-corporations to their owners would improve measurement, as in Norway (Alstadsaeter et al. 2016). 14 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 II.C. Data on Firms Linked to Owners and Workers We construct a novel data set on the universe of S- corporations and partnerships linked to owners and workers using deidentified data from income tax records spanning 2001–2014. Unlike the top incomes data, these data are available on the full population. We construct these linked firm-owner-worker data as follows. We first merge the population of firm-level S-corporation busi- ness income tax returns (Form 1120S) to the population of S- corporation information returns (Form 1120S, Schedule K-1) that link the firms to their owners.20 We merge the 1120S records onto the K-1 records by masked EIN to yield linked firm-owner data. We follow similar steps to construct the partnership link- age to owners. Specifically, we merge the population of firm-level partnership business income tax returns (Form 1065) to the pop- ulation of partnership information returns (Form 1065, Sched- ule K-1). Unlike S-corporations, partnerships can be owned by business entities and by non-U.S. individuals. We focus on direct partnership-owner links in which the partner is a U.S. individual. Then, for both S-corporations and partnerships, we further merge on information about the owners and workers. We use Form 1040 to merge on each owner’s fiscal income. We use data from W-2 forms to measure owner wages—W-2 wage payments from S- corporations and partnerships to individual owners—and to cal- culate firm-level aggregates of the total number of employees. We merge owner wages onto our top incomes data as mentioned in the previous subsection.21 The full sample comprises 158.8M firm-owner-year observa- tions (71.8M S-corporation-owner-year observations and 87.0M

20. These information returns list each owner’s share of the corporation’s income. S-corporations are required to submit to the IRS a K-1 on behalf of each owner of the S-corporation when the corporation submits its Form 1120S business income tax return. Each owner receives a copy of her K-1, which she uses to report S-corporation income on her Form 1040, Schedule E, and compute her tax liability. Each 1120S includes the firm’s masked Employer Identification Number (EIN), and each K-1 includes the firm’s masked EIN as well as the owner’s masked Social Security Number (SSN). 21. Some firms deduct wages from their business tax returns but cannot be linked to any W-2s, for example because they use a different EIN to file taxes and pay workers. We therefore impute missing owner wages using the owner wages share of individual wages of similar firms’ owners. This imputation is minor and used only for Figure VIII below. See Online Appendix B for details. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 15 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 partnership-owner-year observations) on 11.1M firms with posi- tive sales (7.3M S-corporations and 3.9M partnerships) and with 22.6M owners (9.8M S-corporation owners and 12.8M partnership owners). In 2014, the sample comprises 10.3M firm-owner-year ob- servations (4.9M S-corporation-owner-year observations and 5.4M partnership-owner-year observations) on 5.0M firms with posi- tive sales (3.7M S-corporations and 1.4M partnerships) and with 10.3M owners (4.9M S-corporation owners and 5.4M partnership owners). No data source systematically links C-corporations to their owners. To compare pass-through activity to C-corporation activ- ity, we supplement the linked data with the Statistics of Income (SOI) sample of corporate income tax returns from 1980 to 2014.22 Together, these data provide a comprehensive account of the major forms of business activity in the United States. Online Appendix B provides further variable definitions.

III. BUSINESS INCOME AND TOP INCOME INEQUALITY This section shows that business income is the most impor- tant source of income at the top of the income distribution. Most top business income is pass-through income. We then describe who earns pass-through income and the salient features of their firms: most pass-through income accrues to working-age owners of mid-market firms in relatively skill-intensive industries. These descriptive facts are consistent with pass-through income reflect- ing the returns to human capital.

III.A. The Sources of Top Income How much do top earners make from wage income, business income, and other capital income? Figure I, Panel A plots the share of top earners in each income bin who earn the majority of their income from each source. Figure I, Panel B plots the share of aggregate income from each source. Three patterns emerge. First, from the 90th to the 99th percentile of the income distribution, wage income dominates business and other capital income. At the 90th percentile of the income distribution, over four out of five people earn mostly wage income. Wage income represents over 75 cents of every dollar earned by those at the 90th percentile of

22. See Yagan (2015) and Zwick and Mahon (2017) for detail on these weighted, stratified random samples. 16 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Share of People by Majority Income Source

Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 100 100 80 80 60 60 40 40 Share of People (%) Share of People (%) 20 20 0 0 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P99-99.9 P99-99.9 P99.9-100 P99.9-100 Fiscal Income Bin Imputed National Income Bin

Other capital income: interest, Other capital income: interest, Wages Business rents, royalties, estates, trusts Wages Business rents, royalties, estates, trusts

(B) Share of Income by Source

Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 100 100 80 80 60 60 40 40 Share of Bin's INI (%) 20 20 Share of Bin's Fiscal Income (%) 0 0 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P99-99.9 P99-99.9 P99.9-100 P99.9-100 Fiscal Income Bin Imputed National Income Bin

Wages Business Other capital income: interest, Wages Business Other capital income: interest, rents, royalties, estates, trusts rents, royalties, estates, trusts

(C) Share of Income by Business Income Source

Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 Share of Bin's INI (%) 10 Share of Bin's Fiscal Income (%) 0 0 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P99-99.9 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P99.9-100 P99-99.9 P99.9-100 Imputed National Income Bin Fiscal Income Bin Business income from private pass-through firms Business income from private pass-through firms Business income from other firms (C-corporation dividends Business income from other firms (C-corporation dividends) + retained earnings)

FIGURE I Income Sources of Top Earners in 2014 CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 17 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

FIGURE I(Continued). This figure uses our 2014 top-incomes data to show the relative importance of different income sources for top earners using fiscal income (i.e., directly observed tax data) and imputed national income. Panel A plots the share of tax units (fiscal income) or adult individuals (imputed national income) in each income bin who earned the majority of their income in 2014 from wages, business income, or other capital income. For fiscal income, wages includes wages- salaries-and-tips, pension distributions, and annuities, as in Piketty and Saez (2003); business income includes pass-through income (S-corporation income, part- nership income, and sole proprietor’s income) and C-corporation dividends; other capital income includes all other income sources (interest, rents, royalties, and es- tate and trust income). For imputed national income, we use analogous definitions from Piketty, Saez, and Zucman (2018), which includes imputed employer-provided health insurance (included in wages), imputed rents from owner-occupied housing (included in other capital income), and imputed C-corporation retained earnings (included in business income) among other components of national income that do not appear on tax returns. Panel B plots the share of total top income in the form of wages, business, and other capital income for each income bin. Panel C sepa- rates the business income series into contributions from pass-through business and C-corporation income. the income distribution. Second, business income is much more prevalent higher up in the income distribution. At the very top of the income distribution, wage income falls to 40% of fiscal income (19% of INI) and business income accounts for 48% of fiscal income (56% of INI). Third, other capital income is less important and amounts to 12% to 25% of income at the very top. Fewer than one in six people in the 99.9th percentile derive most of their income from interest, rents, and other capital income. Thus, at both the person-level and dollar-level and regardless of income definition, the main source of income at the very top of the income distribution is business income. Figure I, Panel C decomposes the business income series into contributions from pass-through businesses and C-corporation income. Both components’ share of income rises with income rank, however pass-through income is more important than C- corporation income throughout the distribution. At the top, pass- through income alone represents nearly 40% of total income and rivals or exceeds the size of wage income. The importance of business income from C-corporations dif- fers between fiscal income, which only measures C-corporation dividends, and imputed national income, which includes both divi- dends and PSZ’s imputation of retained earnings. In fiscal income, 9.1% of top income comes from C-corporation dividends, whereas in imputed national income, 22.6% comes from C-corporation div- idends and retained earnings. We show that all key results below hold under both income measures. 18 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Pass-Through Income in Top 1% is Large (B) Millionaire Pass-through Owners are Working Age Number of People (K) 40 250 Execs in Execucomp 10.7 Owners in P99-99.9 1,004.3 Owners in P99.9-99.99 123.5 200 Owners in P99.99-100 14.9 30

$100.5 150 20

$61.6 Income (B)

100 $41.6 10 Share of million-dollar earners

$110.8 with majority income of this source (%) 50 $86.9 $74.4 0

$32.7 20-29 30-39 40-49 50-59 60-69 70-79 80-89 90+ Age Group 0 Execucomp P99-99.9 P99.9-99.99 P99.99-100 Wages Pass-through Salary + Options S-corporation Partnership Other capital C-corporation dividends

FIGURE II Working-Age Pass-Through Owners Prevail at the Top of the Income Distribution Panel A uses our 2014 top incomes data to plot the aggregate pass-through income within the top 1% by fiscal income bin and compares that quantity to aggregate salary plus options compensation for all executives in the Execucomp database in 2014. Panel B uses our 2014 top incomes data to plot the share of tax units with over $1 million in fiscal income who earn the majority of their fiscal income in 2014 from either wages, pass-through income, C-corporation dividends, or other capital income by age (i.e., the age of the single tax filer or the mean age of married spouses filing jointly).

Quantifying top retained earnings inherently presents con- siderable uncertainty as direct ownership data for C-corporations is unavailable and estimates are sensitive to imputation assump- tions. Online Appendix F explores PSZ’s method and alternative assumptions for allocating retained earnings. Regardless of the in- come measure, these facts indicate that understanding the nature of business income—and especially the pass-through sector—is imperative for understanding top incomes.

III.B. The Prevalence and Nature of Top Pass-through Ownership Figure II, Panel A demonstrates that pass-through income is prevalent within the top 1% in 2014. For example, among the top 0.1%, 84% earn pass-through income. That is 139,000 taxpayers, with aggregate pass-through income of $264B.23 For comparison, in Execucomp in 2014, the top 10,700 executives working at the S&P 1500 earned a combined $33B. The scale of top pass-through

23. Among the top 1%, 69% earn pass-through income. That is 1,140,000 taxpayers, with aggregate pass-through income of $476B. Among the top 0.01%, 90% earn pass-through income. That is 15,000 taxpayers, with aggregate pass- through income of $116B. Pass-through prevalence is even higher in imputed national income, not shown in Figure II. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 19 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 income far surpasses that of top CEOs, who have been the focus of much inequality commentary. Figure II, Panel B compares the age distributions of million- dollar earners who differ in the majority source of their income. Most top earners whose primary income source is wage income are between 40 and 59 and very few top workers are older than 70. This distribution contrasts with the much older distribution of top earners whose primary income source is other capital in- come. Fifty-six percent of the latter group are older than 60, and nearly 30% are older than 70. The age distribution of pass-through owners is much younger—28% are older than 60 and only 7% are older than 70—and is nearly identical to the distribution of top laborers. The population of pass-through owners does not in- clude very many old people or children, whom one might asso- ciate with estates and inherited wealth. C-corporation dividends skew much older, distributed more similarly to the other capital earners. Overall, pass-through owners resemble workers, while C-corporation owners resemble other capital earners.24 The age distributions are consistent with top pass-through earners being human-capital rich.

III.C. Firm Size and Ownership Varies by Organizational Form Table I provides summary statistics from our linked firm- owner-worker data, restricted to firms with positive sales and nonzero profits. Panel A presents statistics on distinct firm-year observations, and Panel B presents statistics on distinct owner- year observations. In the 2001–2014 pooled sample of all pass-throughs, the av- erage firm earned $31K in profits on sales of $1.8M in 2014 dol- lars, employed 13 workers, and had 2.3 owners. Pass-throughs that have at least one top 0.1% owner are much larger and more profitable—these firms earned $1.6M in profits on $17.5M in sales with 74 employees—yet they typically remain closely held, with the median firm having 2 owners. The average num- ber of owners is skewed by a few partnerships (e.g., a large law firm or consultancy) with many owners: when restricting focus to S-corporations, the average number of owners of top 0.1%-owned firms is 3.4.25

24. Online Appendix Figure I.2 shows similar results for the top 1% and top 0.1%. 25. Online Appendix Tables J.1 and J.2 show summary statistics separately for S-corporations and partnerships. 20 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 96 143 . 6.0 13.9 246.6 145 127 3,302 0.16 0.09 0.71 10.748.7 8.8 41.2 177.5 1,623.0 31.2 45.7 1,813.0 0.36 0.10 0.87 − − − − − − − − (2001–2014) WNERS O 40 83 717 1,602 23 162 943 . 3.5 9.8 113.2 122.0 0.7 21.5 187.3 155.6 0.12 0.08 0.59 0.13 18.5 42.0 428.2 620.2 10.2 79.9 569.8 634.2 0.18 0.15 0.78 0.15 − − HEIR − − − − − − T B. Firms with Top C. Firms with Top TABLE I THROUGHS AND - ASS P 30 12 194 237 19 28 291 338 6.3 3.9 49.1 39.5 2.2 11.8 82.2 65.9 0.29 0.05 0.48 0.12 19.3 8.0 127.3 131.8 11.9 18.7 192.3 190.0 0.31 0.11 0.64 0.18 − − − − A. All Firms 1–0.1% Owners 0.1% Owners − − − − TATISTICS ON S 27.6 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 − UMMARY S 0 21.9 1.0 5.0 40.1 43.3 1.5 13.0 90.1 140.0 2.5 32.9 249.3 > Employees | SalesProfits 1,809 31 13 229 2,487 3,660 20 946 8,309 17,496 19 1,772 34,668 Profit margin 0.05 AssetsEmployeesEmployees Number of ownersNumber of owners, S-corp onlyNumber of owners, Pship onlySales per 1.6 workerProfits per worker 4.4 1.0 2.3 12.9 1.0 1,347 1.0 2.0 0.0 1.0 2.4 0 196.1 4.0 1.0 16.1 1.5 2.2 20.6 51 23.6 3.0 4.0 86.5 1,119 1.0 27.7 363.3 1,997 2.8 1.0 314.0 1.2 0.0 4 26.5 1.0 2.0 4.0 3.7 134.1 291 2.0 7.1 625.4 60.7 3.4 3,852 761.8 5.0 27.8 17,696 74.3 22.9 1.0 20 14.2 1.0 164.9 0.0 2.0 1,094.0 1,223 1.0 3.0 1.6 21,314 6.1 2.0 21.2 141.3 12.0 Profits per owner Entrepreneurial income 144 Entrep. income per owner 77.5 Entrep. income per worker 33.8 Entrep. income / profitEntrep. income / sales 1.50 0.12 0.43 1 3.22 1.68 0.57 1 3.01 1.24 0.40 1 1.60 Number of firm-years 58,933,472 7,379,599 2,464,603 Panel A: Firm summary statistics CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 21 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 15 162 2,638 11 258 . 0.01 0 0.87 − − − 6 51 530 1,074 3 108 667 . 0.01 0.19 0.97 0.32 0 0.09 0.96 0.01 0.01 0.90 0.18 − − − − ONTINUED TABLE I C 8 8 181 231 12 3 113 166 0.08 0.12 0.99 0.35 0.08 0.39 1.01 0.50 0 0.51 1 0.48 0 0.49 0.98 0.08 0.01 0.79 0.21 − − − − − A. All Owners B. Top 1–0.1% Owners C. Top 0.1% Owners Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 S-corp owners only Pship owners only IncomeAgeNumber of firms ownedWage incomePass-through income 1.3 1.0 51 235 1.0 76 51.1 13 2.0 0 34.3 98 1.5 50.7 476 21 69.6 1.0 655 165 52.4 1.0 203 393 38.9 2.8 51.9 571 0 2.2 1,089 67.4 4,687 123 54.5 1.0 1,559 537 40.6 2,430 1.0 932 7,879 53.9 4.5 70.4 0 226 2,256 Entrepreneurial income 75 Pthru income / entrep. incomeWage income / incomeEntrep. income 0.81 / incomeEntrep.inc./inc., 0.19 0.73 0.63 1 2.07 0 1 0.20 0.85 0.95 0.35 0.32 1 0 1 0.21 0.89 0.91 0.24 0.70 0 1 0.08 1 0.89 Entrep.inc./inc., 3.85 Panel B: Owner summary statistics 22 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 in thousands of ass-through income s the quantity divided fit margin equals profits servations. Panel B pools 40, Schedule E income. An nual distributions: Entrep. 1–0.1% owner or a top 0.1% omeandisthemainincome passive otherwise. For these ly earned income (e.g., interest s. Year refers to calendar year, which 1 and above at 1: Profit margin, Entrep. income/sales, and Entrep. income/value added. Assets ONTINUED TABLE I − C 0.13 0.10 0.92 0.37 0 0.35 0.91 0.47 0 0.57 0.94 − A. All Owners B. Top 1–0.1% Owners C. Top 0.1% Owners Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 and equals Form 1040 total income minus Form 1040 capital gains minus Form 1040 unemployment compensation minus Form 1040 taxable Piketty and Saez (2003) This table presents summary statistics for our linked firm-owner data, comprising pass-through firms linked to owners in 2001–2014. Dollar values are Business income / income 0.22 Only earns passive incomeNumber of owner-years 0.11 0 108,575,625 0 1 0.11 0 11,793,249 0 0.87 0.07 0 2,329,024 0 0 Notes. 2014 dollars. The maindistinct sample owner-year observations. comprises All 109M statisticsby firm-owner-year are law observations unweighted, is unless with also otherwise positive eachon specified. sales pass-through’s All bank fiscal and variables year. deposits) are nonzero Sales is annual isdivided profits. and excluded. the by Panel are firm’s Profits sales. A available operating Employees is pools in revenue andby the all (gross distinct number the year sales firm’s firm-year of number minus ordinary workers of ob returns) workers. equals businessconcept as Entrepreneurial the income, used listed income number in on equal equals of the pass-through to individuals income firmsocial who operating plus tax security received revenue W-2 return. benefits. wages a Passive minus Age paid W-2 is to from costsowner age pass-through the as if owners. as firm listed Income her of that is December on year. fiscal shortequals A 31, the income for the quantity based fiscal firm lies per owner’s on inc tax share worker year in of equal ofowner’s return. the birth the pass-through Pro top from profits income 1% Social from is Security butsummary all active records not pass-throughs statistics, housed if she the two alongside the owns. variables tax top owner Businessincome/profit, records. are 0.1%, income and An reports winsorized or owner is Business she in the is total income/income. materially the ais top pass-through Two participates top underlying set business variables 0.1% in to data income are of the missing and at winsorized all for operations equals below the tax the total of at unweighted very units Form any 1st few 10 in of observations percentile the in her and year, which pass-through the respectively. assets businesses unweighted Wage are income and 99th over equals is percentile one trillion. W-2 of income. the P an CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 23 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Pass-through businesses are not only closely held but also undiversified: most top owners own just one firm. If pass-through owners were only contributing financial capital, one might ex- pect them to hold portfolios with shares of many firms. However, the data suggest this strategy is uncommon. Moreover, nearly all owners report being active, that is, materially participating in the business. For example, the share of top 0.1% owners who report earning only from their pass-throughs is 7%.26 Most top-owned pass-through businesses are mid-market in size. Figure III, Panel A explores the firm size distribution among top-owned pass-throughs and compares it to the distribution for all C-corporations. The profit distributions are markedly different across corporate forms. Eighty percent of the pass-through income for million-dollar earners derives from firms with between $1M and $500M in sales. Moreover, 72% of top-1% owned pass-through profits come from firms with less than $50M in profits. In contrast, the distribution of C-corporations has substantially more concen- tration in the right tail. Ninety-six percent of C-corporation profits in 2014 come from firms with more than $500M in sales. Only 19% of millionaire-owned pass-through profits come from firms in this size bin. The characteristics of pass-throughs—closely held, undiver- sified in ownership, and mid-market in size—supports a narra- tive of top pass-through income that differs from those for C- corporation income. The C-corporation profit distribution is so skewed that diffuse ownership can nevertheless yield significant income to individual owners. In contrast, pass-through owners tend to earn high incomes via concentrated ownership of one mid- market firm. The pass-through narrative is consistent with active owner-management. An alternative narrative of top incomes emphasizes how man- agers set their pay by bargaining with a corporate board that represents diffuse shareholders. This story also does not resonate for explaining pass-through income. Pass-throughs have concen- trated ownership, which minimizes principal-agent failures— especially if the CEO is a majority owner. Agency explanations may account for more of the growth in CEO and top manager com- pensation for public companies, which have thousands of owners.

26. However, as we describe in Online Appendix B, there is a tax incentive to report oneself as being active rather than passive. 24 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Profit Distribution by Firm Size 100 80 60 40 this organizational form (%) Share of profits generated by 20 0

$500k-$1m $1m-$5m $5m-$10m $10m-$50m $50m-$500m $500m+ Sales in 2014 C-corporations Millionaire-owned pass-throughs

(B) Distribution of Profits Across Industries 50 40 30 20 Share of total (%) 10 0 Agriculture & ForestryConstruction &Manufacturing Mining Retail & WholesaleFin, Insur Trade & RealInfo Estate & ProfessionalHealth Svcs Care Entertnmt, FoodOther & Hotels Svcs

C-corporation profits Millionaire-owned pass-through firms Number of workers

FIGURE III Top-Owned Firms Are Mid-Market and Broad-Based across Industries This figure uses our 2014 linked firm-owner data and our SOI C-corporation data to plot the distribution of profits by firm size and industry in 2014 by orga- nizational form. Panel A plots the distribution of aggregate profits by firm sales for C-corporations, and separately for pass-throughs owned by tax units with at least $1 million in fiscal income. Panel B plots the distribution of profits generated by each organizational form across one-digit NAICS sectors. We split NAICS 5 into two subcategories: Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate (FIRE), which en- compasses NAICS codes 52 and 53; and Information and Professional Services, CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 25 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

FIGURE III (Continued). which includes NAICS 51, 54, and 56. Since NAICS 55 (Management of Companies and Enterprises, i.e., holding companies) includes activity from several industries, we exclude it here. See Online Appendix Figure I.3 for versions with top 1% and top 0.1% pass-through owners.

III.D. The Industry Composition of Business Income Figure III, Panel B compares the distributions of total profits across one-digit NAICS sectors for pass-through firms owned by million-dollar earners to the distributions of C-corporation prof- its and of all workers from the Current Population Survey.27 Top pass-through profits are earned broadly across sectors and are similarly distributed as the overall distribution of workers, rela- tive to C-corporations.28 Compared to C-corporation profits, pass- through profits are underrepresented in manufacturing and over- represented in information, professional services, and health care. Less than 20% of top pass-through profits are earned in finance. Table II presents a more granular analysis of the industry composition of business income at the four-digit NAICS level. The left panel lists the top 30 industries in aggregate profits earned by million-dollar-owned pass-through firms, along with the aggre- gate flow of 2014 profits apportioned pro rata to owners. For each industry, we compare the top pass-through flow to the flow of C- corporation profits and the industry-level profits rank within the C-corporation sector. The right panel repeats this exercise for the top 30 industries in aggregate profits earned by C-corporations. White-collar, skilled service industries dominate the pass- through sector, whereas more capital-intensive industries, es- pecially manufacturing, dominate the C-corporation sector. The five largest industries for millionaire-owned pass-through prof- its are legal services ($28.6B), other financial activ- ity ($28.2B), other professional and technical services ($8.2B),

27. We divide the service sector 5 into two subsectors: finance, insurance, and real estate (FIRE); and information and professional services. In this section, we exclude firms in the residual category NAICS 5511 (Management of Companies and Enterprises). The category refers to firms that often own related but formally distinct nonfinancial firms. Among public companies for example, General Electric classifies its industry as a holding company (based on public 10-K financial filings). 28. Online Appendix Figure I.5 compares the distribution of state population to the distributions across states of total profits of top-owned pass-throughs and all C-corporations. Pass-through profits are broadly distributed and comparable to the population distribution. 26 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (2014) 98,696 10963,295 112 441 403 46,573 26 1,957 35,288 254 2 33,250 106 448 27,027 139 283 25,191 94 497 22,997 136 290 21,460 69 709 20,326 163 189 ROFITS P CORPORATION C- LL A (3241) (3254) intermediation (5222) (5179) mfg. (3341) stores (4529) wholesalers (4242) (3364) component mfg. (3344) toiletry mfg. (3256) THROUGH AND - ASS P TABLE II 727 4 Other telecommunications 480 3 Nondepository credit 5,446 9 Semiconductor/electronic − − OWNED − - DOLLAR - ILLION M 8,196 248 5,940 56 4,388 7 Druggists’ goods merchant 5,209 110 1,012 8 Aerospace product/parts mfg. 4,771 253 4,730 123 769 10 Motor vehicle mfg. (3361) 20,521 179 152 3,853 98 1,419 11 Soap, cleaning compound/ 28,207 13 17,712 2 Pharmaceutical/medicine mfg. Top passthru C-corp C-corp Top passthru OMPOSITION OF C NDUSTRIAL I activity (5239) services (5419) services (5416) (5313) services (5415) (2389) wholesalers (4239) Industry (NAICS) Profit ($M) Rank Profit ($M) Industry (NAICS) Profit ($M) Rank Profit ($M) 1 Legal services (5411) 28,643 144 477 1 Petroleum/coal products mfg. 2 Other financial investment 3 Other professional/technical 4 Offices of physicians (6211) 8,018 250 5 Automobile dealers (4411) 6,712 64 3,121 5 Computer/peripheral equipment 6 Oil/gas extraction (2111) 6,290 12 18,375 6 Other general merchandise 7 Management/techncl consulting 8 Activities related to real estate 9 Computer sys design/related 10 Other specialty trade contractor 11 Misc. durable goods merchant CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 27 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 17,712 215,945 35 28,207 1,519 14,814 10514,684 452 7014,503 142 707 266 13,448 33 1,594 activity (5239) wholesalers (4244) mfg. (3331) (5191) intermediation (5223) (4461) ONTINUED TABLE II C 109 21 Health/personal care stores − 3,754 37 7,636 12 Oil/gas extraction (2111) 18,375 6 6,290 3,1292,934 592,933 3,741 44 14 Grocery/related2,899 product 6,167 70 15 Software2,891 140 publishers 2,802 (5112) 16 Ag.,2,742 555 constr/mining 97 machinery 15,010 17 Other 1,442 55 information services 99 18 Activities related 4,489 to credit 472 19 Restaurants (7225) 14,137 20 2,690 2,440 54 4,494 22 Traveler accommodation (7211) 12,761 45 1,229 Top passthru C-corp C-corp Top passthru mfg. (3329) services (5412) (5242) services (5413) construction (2362) (2382) construction (2361) merchant wholesalers (4249) Industry (NAICS) Profit ($M) Rank Profit ($M) Industry (NAICS) Profit ($M) Rank Profit ($M) 12 Other fabricated metal prod 13 Other miscellaneous mfg. (3399) 3,328 76 2,300 13 Other financial investment 14 Accounting/bookkeeping 15 Insurance agencies/brokerages 16 Architectural/engineering 17 Nonresidential building 18 Building equipment contractors 19 Residential building 20 Restaurants (7225)21 Other heavy construction (2379) 2,669 240 2,690 19 14,137 20 Basic chemical mfg. (3251) 14,136 86 550 22 Misc. nondurable goods 28 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 try. The rows are sorted by ers and then aggregate those mns indicate the level of profits 12,758 61 902 11,287 90 523 11,253 92 507 10,948 55 976 10,920 148 253 dealers (4441) (3222) (5121) intermediation (5221) (5151) ONTINUED TABLE II 25 27 Grocery stores (4451) 11,005 53 1,035 C − 1,958 33 9,022 25 Beverage mfg. (3121) 11,274 63 871 1,957 3 46,573 26 Motion picture/video industries 1,915 229 1,854 72 2,509 28 Depository credit 1,820 41 6,480 29 Radio/television broadcasting 1,792 90 1,748 30 Security contracts broker (5231) 10,530 23 2,268 Top passthru C-corp C-corp Top passthru This table presents statistics on the level of million-dollar-owned pass-through profits and total C-corporation profits in 2014 by four-digit indus wholesalers (4238) intermediation (5222) performers (7115) (5259) (2131) (5418) Industry (NAICS) Profit ($M) Rank Profit ($M) Industry (NAICS) Profit ($M) Rank Profit ($M) Notes. the level of topapportioned pass-through profits profits by on four-digit thein industry. Rank left millions columns of and indicate 2014 C-corporation dollars. the profits rank on of the that right. four-digit These industry statistics within apportion a particular pass-through group profits of pro firms. rata Profits to colu own 23 Security contracts broker (5231) 2,268 30 10,530 23 Building material/supplies 24 Plastics product mfg. (3261) 2,140 119 799 24 Converted paper product mfg. 25 Machinery/supply merchant 26 Nondepository credit 27 Indie artists, writers, 28 Other investment pools/funds 29 Support activity for mining 30 Advertising, PR/related services CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 29 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 offices of physicians ($8.0B), and auto dealers ($6.7B). The five largest industries for C-corporation profits are petroleum and coal product manufacturing ($98.7B), pharmaceutical manufac- turing ($63.3B), nondepository credit intermediation ($46.6B), other telecommunications ($35.3B), and computer and peripheral equipment manufacturing ($33.3B).29 The C-corporation sector includes many well-known listed companies, which are broadly held within the household sector and by pensions, nonprofits, and foreign investors. In some indus- tries, such as restaurants, retailers, and wholesalers, firms oper- ate in both pass-through and C-corporation form (e.g., Menards versus Home Depot; Yagan 2015). Remarkably, certain industries that are prevalent and large for pass-through profits, such as law firms, doctors, and consultants, have negative or nearly zero ag- gregate profits in the C-corporation sector. Table III presents a disaggregated analysis of pass-through profits for the top industries in the S-corporation and partner- ship sectors. We define top industries by the 2014 level of profits flowing to either top 1–0.1% or top 0.1% owners. This focus on the industries of top-owned firms complements Bakija, Cole, and Heim (2012), who study the occupations of top earners using per- sonal income tax returns and find a large role for professional services, finance, and closely held businesses. Top pass-through profits comprise human-capital-intensive service professions and to a lesser extent nonmanufacturing in- dustries that depend on financial and physical capital, such as real estate and oil and gas. Typical firms owned by the top 1–0.1% are single-establishment firms in professional services (e.g., consultants, lawyers, specialty tradespeople) or health ser- vices (e.g., physicians, dentists). For example, in the top 1–0.1%, the largest S-corporation industry is offices of physicians ($9.1B) and the largest partnership industry is legal services ($21.3B). A typical firm owned by the top 0.1% might be a regional business with $20M in sales and 100 employees, such as an auto dealer, beverage distributor, or a large law firm. There is significant

29. In recent years, the aggregate composition of business income is roughly evenly split between the pass-through and C-corporation sectors (Cooper et al. 2016). Adjusting the C-corporation profit figures for the share of C-corporation wealth owned by the household sector (equal to $11T/$23.4T = 47%) and the top 1% share of C-corporation dividends (49% in 2014), top 1% pass-through profits are roughly double the size of top 1% C-corporation profits. 30 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 0.1%, 2014) OP T VERSUS 1–0.1% OP (T ROFITS P TABLE III THROUGH - Top 1–0.1% Top 0.1% ASS P OMPOSITION OF C NDUSTRIAL I S-corporation industry (NAICS) profit ($M) S-corporation industry (NAICS) profit ($M) 12 Offices3 of physicians (6211) Other4 professional/technical services (5419) Offices5 of dentists (6212) Other6 specialty trade contractors (2389) Legal7 services 4,778 (5411) Insurance8 agencies/brokerages (5242) Computer9 sys design/related services (5415) Architectural/engineering 210 services (5413) 3,893 Building11 equipment contractors Restaurants (2382) (7225) Automobile12 dealers (4411) 9,063 2,662 Management/techncl consulting svc13 (5416) 2,678 Nonresidential 4 building constr 2,64214 (2362) Offices of other15 1 7 health 4,317 practitioners Other Misc. (6213) professional/technical durable services goods 6 (5419) merch 2,595 2,196 whlsl Other (4239) 8 fabricated metal Other Management/techncl financial prod consulting mfg. investment svc (3329) activity (5416) (5239) Computer 3 sys design/related 3,485 services Other 4,186 (5415) specialty 1,886 9 11 trade 1,906 contractors (2389) Oil/gas extraction (2111) Other fabricated 3,185 Legal metal 1,684 services 5,786 prod 5 (5411) 3,206 mfg. 5,176 13 (3329) 1,670 12 Activities Offices related of Other to 3,086 physicians 2,421 miscellaneous 14 real (6211) mfg. estate (3399) (5313) 15 Other heavy construction 2,727 (2379) Nonresidential building 10 construction (2362) Misc. durable goods merch whlsl (4239) 2,286 1,940 4,820 2,477 2,847 3,621 2,248 2,836 CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 31 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 ctively. These tics for two groups of firms: try. Profits columns indicate ONTINUED TABLE III C Top 1–0.1% Top 0.1% Partnership industry (NAICS) profit ($M) Partnership industry (NAICS) profit ($M) This table presents statistics on the level of S-corporation and partnership profits for top earners in 2014 by four-digit industry. We present statis Notes. 12 Legal3 services (5411) Offices4 of physicians (6211) Accounting/bookkeeping5 services (5412) Other6 financial investment activity (5239) Other7 professional/technical services (5419) Outpatient8 care centers (6214) Activities9 related to 5,316 real estate Management/techncl10 (5313) consulting 3,395 svc 1,641 (5416) Oil/gas11 extraction (2111) Restaurants (7225)12 3 Offices of 4 other13 5 health practitioners 5,923 Offices (6213) of 1,263 dentists14 (6212) Activities 21,320 related Insurance to agencies/brokerages Other real (5242) Oil/gas15 1,357 professional/technical estate extraction services (5313) (2111) (5419) Computer sys design/related 2 services 1,449 (5415) 8 Architectural/engineering 1 services (5413) 670 7 2,254 Legal services Other (5411) investment Other pools/funds 6 financial (5259) investment activity 563 (5239) Security contracts 2,534 broker 11 (5231) 573 Management/techncl 550 consulting 1,139 svc (5416) Automobile dealers (4411) 14 20,220 13 9 Computer 694 15 sys 1,372 574 design/related 1,637 svc (5415) Lessors 2,035 of real estate Fruit/tree nut (5311) Accounting/bookkeeping farming services (1113) (5412) 10 1,485 12 Offices of Residential physicians building (6211) 18,200 585 construction (2361) 1,166 693 689 482 685 1,026 firms owned by the topstatistics 1–0.1% apportion and profits firms pro ownedthe rata by level to the of owners top profits in in 0.1%. either millions The the of rows top 2014 are 0.1% dollars. sorted or by the the level top of 1–0.1% firm and profits then for aggregate firms those owned apportioned by profits the by top four-digit 0.1% indus and top 1–0.1%, respe 32 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 overlap between top S-corporations and top partnerships. How- ever, partnership profits are more concentrated and skew more toward certain high-skilled services, especially legal services and other financial investment activity, which includes private eq- uity, venture capital, and hedge funds.30 Overall, most top pass- through businesses do not operate in finance and instead actively produce goods or services across diverse industries.31

III.E. Pass-through Profitability Is Higher for Top Owners This section explores how profitability of pass-through firms varies with an owner’s position in the income distribution. While other explanations of heterogeneous returns exist, showing that top owners generate excess profitability provides evidence that is consistent with profits reflecting in part the returns to human rather than physical and financial capital. A scale-limiting fac- tor, like the time or personal relationships of a skilled owner- manager, may lead higher demand to manifest itself through higher prices (profits per worker), rather than higher quantities (more workers). To test whether top-owned firms generate especially high profitability, we begin by binning year-2014 owners in the linked firm-owner-worker data by their fiscal income. We confine atten- tion to the top fiscal income decile, where the vast majority of pass-through income accrues. The bins are 1 percentile wide, ex- cept in the top 1%, where we consider bins between the 99th percentile and 99.5th percentile, the 99.5th percentile and 99.9th percentile, and the top 0.1%. We then compute mean profitability—measured as profits per worker—across firms owned by individuals within each personal income bin, with and without controls, as follows. When not us- ing controls, we compute the mean profitability across owner-firm

30. These tables only include ordinary business income, not dividends, inter- est, or capital gains, which we separately account for in the top incomes data. Online Appendix Table J.3 presents statistics on the number of firms and owners for both S-corporations and partnerships in each industry in Table III. 31. Online Appendix Table J.4 formalizes this observation by presenting a set of correlations at the NAICS four-digit level, which relate aggregate profits by corporate form to industry-level measures of human capital and nonhuman capital (e.g., physical capital) intensity. Top pass-through profits are most strongly correlated with measures of human capital intensity,whereas C-corporation profits are less correlated with human capital and most correlated with physical capital intensity at the industry level. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 33 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 observations within each bin weighting by firm scale (the number of workers). Our main specification controls for industry (four- digit NAICS), removing profitability variation across owner in- come bins that is correlated with industry fixed effects (see the figure note). Figure IV, Panel A plots the results. Firms owned by top 0.1% earners enjoy profitability ($14K per worker) that is over twice as large as the profitability ($5K per worker) of firms owned by individuals in the bottom half of the top decile. The graph displays similar patterns without controls and when also controlling for firm size. Figure IV, Panel B demonstrates that high firm profitability is a persistent and systematic characteristic of high earners. It replicates Panel A in the subsample of pass-through startups, plotting the profitability-income gradient using owner income ranks from the year before the owner founded the startup. A firm qualifies as a startup in year t if it filed an income tax return in year t and did not file an income tax return of any kind before year t. We find all such owner-startup observations in years 2001–2010 and define the owner’s income rank using her fiscal income in the year before she founded the startup. Then for each startup year, we produce a profitability-income gradient net of industry fixed effects, using profitability from the startup’s fifth year of existence and conditioning on startups that survive for at least five years. We then average those gradients evenly across years and plot the mean gradient in circles in Figure IV, Panel B. Startups founded by top earners go on to be much more profitable in their fifth year than those started by other lower earners.32 The panel also shows that we find similar results when including all startups regardless of how long they survive, computing each startup’s profitability as total profits in the startup’s first five years divided by total annual workers in the startup’s first five years. Hence, superior firm profitability is a persistent and systematic characteristic of high earners.33

32. Note that these firms have existed for only five years, so the magnitude of performance advantages may differ relative to the full sample of top-owned firms for firm life-cycle reasons. 33. Online Appendix H.1 addresses the question of whether high profitability at top-owned firms reflects payment for higher undiversifiable risk. Based on ex post survival probabilities and Sharpe ratio–like risk adjustments, higher risk does not explain higher profitability among top-owned firms. 34 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

FIGURE IV Profitability Rises with Owner Income Rank Panel A plots firm profitability (profits per worker) by owner fiscal income across owner-firm observations in the 2014 linked firm-owner data. The bins are 1 per- centile point wide in fiscal income, except in the top 1% where we consider bins of ranks between the 99th percentile and 99.5th percentile, the 99.5th percentile and 99.9th percentile, and the top 0.1%. Means are weighted by scale (the firm’s number of workers). Industry fixed effects denote four-digit NAICS indicators. Sales fixed effects denote ventile indicators (i.e., 5-percentile point bins in the firm sales distribution). Panel B plots the equivalent of Panel A’s within-industry se- ries using the population of pass-through startups 2001–2010. It ranks owners by their fiscal income in the year before founding a new pass-through. It plots in blue circles (color version available online) profits per worker in the firm’s fifth year of existence, conditional on the firm surviving five years. It plots in red squares CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 35 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

FIGURE IV (Continued). the startup’s sum of its first five years of annual profits divided by the startup’s sum of its first five years of annual number of workers, imputing zeros for profits and workers in years after a startup exits. We focus on firms with positive workers. We winsorize profitability at the 1st and 99th per- centiles across the year’s top-decile owner-firm observations. We apportion profits and workers to owners according to ownership shares. To take out fixed effects, we compute profitability at the owner-firm level for all owners in the top personal in- come decile, regress profitability on industry fixed effects weighted by the number of workers, compute residuals, add a constant to the residuals such that the sum of the product of the residuals and the number of workers equals total profits, and then compute the employment-weighted mean of each bin’s residuals. The addition of the constant ensures that the overall employment-weighted mean profitability is constant across specifications.

III.F. Summary of Descriptive Evidence Together, this section’s descriptive statistics show that a large share of top earners are owners of mid-market firms in skill-intensive industries in the pass-through sector. Pass- through participation is pervasive among top earners who are working age and own undiversified positions in closely held firms. Statistics by industry show that many pass-through firms operate in industries that rely more on human capital than on financial capital. That pass-through activity is in many sectors and in firms that are not especially large is at odds with passive capital stories implying that most profitable activity may be concentrated among a few firms.

IV. THE HUMAN CAPITAL SHARE OF PASS-THROUGH INCOME This section presents three event studies: two to quantify the extent to which pass-through income reflects the return to owners’ human capital, and a third to test a candidate mechanism. We use the term “human capital” to refer to all factors embodied in the owner, as opposed to nonhuman factors, such as physical capital, intangible transferable assets (such as patents or brands), or mar- ket position. The return to human capital includes the return to la- bor supply, the owner’s network, her retention and recruiting skill, her reputation, and her ability to extract rents. This distinction between labor income—the flow return to human capital—and capital income—the flow return to nonhuman capital—accords with the definitions in PSZ and elsewhere in the literature. Empirically, the flow return to an owner’s human capital 36 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 includes wages, which are directly observable, and the share of profits deriving from human capital, which must be estimated.

IV.A. The Profit Impact of Owner Deaths To estimate human capital’s share of pass-through profits, an experimental ideal would be to measure the profit impact of exogenously forcing pass-through owners to withdraw their hu- man capital from their firms. We approximate this ideal with a natural experiment in which we measure the profit impact of pre- mature owner deaths. We find that the average premature death of a million-dollar-earning owner causes an 82% decline in firm profits.

1. Analysis Sample and Variable Definitions. We construct an owner deaths analysis sample—comprising firms with owner deaths matched to firms without owner deaths—as follows. We obtain owner year of death from Social Security Administration files housed alongside tax records. We refer to a firm-owner-year observation in the linked-firm-owner data as experiencing a year-t owner death when (i) the owner was aged 64 or younger at the end of year t, owned at least 20% of the firm in t − 1, and had over $1 million in t − 1 fiscal income; (ii) the owner died in year t ∈ [2005, 2010]; (iii) the firm had no other owners 2001–2014 who died; and (iv) the firm had $100,000 in sales in t − 1, the firm had positive sales in all years [t − 4, t − 1], and the firm had positive employment in some year [t − 4, t − 1].34 We then match each such owner-death firm-owner-t observa- tion to all “counterfactual” firm-owner-t observations that satisfy the following criteria: (i) the firm never had an owner die in the year of or immediately after being an owner; (ii) the firm had at least $100,000 in sales in t − 1, the firm had positive sales in all years [t − 4, t − 1], and the firm had positive employment in some year [t − 4, t − 1]; and (iii) the observation matches the owner- death observation along five dimensions. Those five dimensions are: (i) the owners were in the same five-year age bin in year t, (ii) the owners were in the same fiscal income bin (99th to 99.5th per- centile, 99.5th to 99.9th percentile, or top 0.1%) in t − 1, (iii) the firm had the same three-digit NAICS industry code, (iv) the firm

34. Most dying owners have a firm-owner observation in the year of death. We also include owner deaths that occur one year after the last year the owner appears in our data. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 37 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 had the same sales decile (defined after applying all other sample restrictions) in t − 1; and (v) the firm had the same organizational form (i.e., S-corporation versus partnership). The sample restrictions and matching procedure serve the following purposes. Restricting to ages below 65 ensures that we examine owner deaths representative of typical owners (who are working-age) rather than typical dying owners (who skew older). Restricting attention to deaths in 2005–2010 allows us to con- struct a balanced panel of firm observations between four years before and four years after the death using our 2001–2014 data. Restricting to firms with substantial preperiod sales and positive employment focuses our analysis on economically active firms. Re- stricting to owners who own at least 20% of the firm helps exclude firms with many owners that typically replace departing owner- managers with new owner-managers, such as large law firms. Such replacement would bias toward 0 our estimates of the dying owner’s human-capital contribution to firm profits, as her human capital supply is simply replaced by a new owner’s.35 Matching on the various dimensions assists in identifying counterfactual firms that would plausibly exhibit common trends to owner-death firms in the absence of the owner’s death. The matching proce- dure is similar to other death-based event studies (Jager¨ 2016; Jaravel, Petkova, and Bell 2018) except that it uses all matched counterfactual observations rather than selecting one at random. After conducting the matches, we construct a balanced panel of firm outcomes for each owner-death firm j and each counterfac- tual firm j for every year between four years before and four years after the death. If a firm exits (i.e., no longer files a Form 1120S or Form 1065 income tax return), it is coded as having 0 profits and 0 sales in exited years, except for the reorganization correc- tion defined below. Our owner deaths analysis sample comprises 581,508 matched pair-year observations: nine years of observa- tions on each of 765 firms with a dying million-dollar-earning owner and 64,612 counterfactual firms. We also report results in a broader sample of top 1% owner deaths (2,609,973 observations with 2,436 owner-death firms) and a narrower sample of top 0.1% owner deaths (194,787 observations with 435 owner-death firms).

35. This restriction excludes few firms, and the main coefficient estimate is slightly larger in absolute magnitude when including them. Firms with a very large number of owners are excluded by the restriction that only one owner died 2001–2014. 38 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Online Appendix Table J.5 provides a waterfall showing how sam- ple restrictions yield our analysis sample size. Our main outcome is profits per preperiod worker. This quan- tity in a year s equals firm profits in s divided by the firm’s mean annual workers across years [t − 4, t − 1] where t denotes the owner death year. Scaling profits by the average annual number of preperiod workers permits comparison across firms of differ- ent predeath size. Because the denominator is defined using only predeath observations, postdeath changes in the number of work- ers do not directly affect the outcome. For example, a firm with constant profits that happens to replace employees with equally compensated independent contractors would exhibit zero change in profits per preperiod worker. We also analyze firm survival, equal in a year s to an indicator for whether the firm has positive sales in s. Forty-one percent of the owner-death firms and 17% of coun- terfactual firms exit the sample between t and t + 4. Some of these exits do not represent firm shutdowns and instead represent firm reorganizations under a different employer identification num- ber either through bankruptcy or sale. We do not directly observe firm reorganizations. However, we can infer reorganizations by whether most of the exiting firm’s workers subsequently appear as coworkers at another firm. Specifically, for every firm that had 0 sales in year t + 4 and denoting its first year of zero sales (i.e., its first fully exited year) by r, we identify the largest single employer other than the exiting firm across years r and r + 1 of the firm’s r − 1 workers excluding the dying owner.36 We find that 22% of exiting owner-death firms and 28% of exiting counterfactual firms with at least two r − 1 workers were reorganizations: the largest single employer following the owner death employed over half of the exiting firm’s r − 1 workers. We account for these reorganiza- tions by simply replacing the firm’s profit in years [r, t + 4] with the firm’s profit in year r − 1.37

36. We measure employer as the EIN listed on the W-2. Because we use W-2 EIN to identify both the owner-death firm’s r − 1 workers and the firms subsequently employing those workers, employer is consistently measured before and after the owner death. We search for the largest single employer across all of aworker’sr and r + 1 employers, not just the highest-paying one. 37. This correction is analogous to how Chetty and Saez (2005) correct for firms that delist from stock exchanges, thereby exiting their analysis sample. Moreover, we neither observe nor infer division spinoffs, which would reduce measured profits at the surviving owner-death firm despite no real reduction in economic activity. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 39 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 2. Estimates. We use our owner deaths analysis sample of matched owner-death and counterfactual firms to estimate difference-in-differences impacts of owner deaths, as follows. Let j denote an owner-death firm and j denote one of its matched coun- terfactual firms. For each matched pair-year observation, we com- pute the difference in the outcome of interest between the owner- death firm and the counterfactual firm in the given year, that is, Y jjs ≡ Y js − Y js. We then regress that difference on event-time indicators in an event study specification:   = β k + ε , (1) Y jj s kDjs js k∈{−4,−3,−2,0,1,2,3,4}

k where Djs is an indicator for owner-death firm j having experi- enced an owner death k years in the past. The coefficients of inter- est βk provide the time path of mean owner-death firm outcomes relative to the year before the owner death, which is normalized to 0. Note that because there are no controls, the coefficients βk are raw differences-in-differences of the outcome means between owner-death firms and counterfactual firms between year t − 1 and other years. We ensure that each owner-death firm carries equal weight in the regression by weighting each jjs observation by one over the number of counterfactual ( j) firms matched to the owner-death firm ( j). We cluster standard errors by owner-death firm j. Figure V, Panel A plots our main owner-death result: point estimates and 95% confidence intervals from equation (1) for the outcome of profits per preperiod worker. The flat preperiod trend corroborates the common trends assumption underlying our difference-in-differences analysis—that in the absence of the owner death, profits per preperiod worker among owner-death firms and among counterfactual firms would have trended simi- larly. The graph shows that profits per preperiod worker decline immediately and persistently at owner-death firms relative to counterfactual firms on owner death.38 The immediate decline in

However, we believe that spinoffs are likely rare for the medium-sized firms we study. To explain the very large effects we find below, very large shares of most owner-death firms would have to have been spun off. Online Appendix H.2 tests robustness of punchline calculations to potential bias. 38. Although the graph shows a flat time series of dollar estimates, percentage estimates scaled by the outcome of mean of counterfactual firms exhibit a slight downward trend as profits at counterfactual firms secularly decline over time. 40 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

FIGURE V Profit Effects of Owner Deaths and Retirements For Panel A, we identify all 765 “owner-death” firms in our linked-firm-owner- worker data that (i) have an owner in a year t ∈ [2005, 2010] who was under age 65, died in year t, and had over $1 million in t − 1 fiscal income; (ii) had no other owner deaths 2001–2014, at least $100,000 in sales in 2014 dollars in t − 1, positive sales in all years [t − 4, t − 1], and the firm had positive employment in some year [t − 4, t − 1]; and (iii) has at least one “counterfactual” firm of the same organizational form that met the same [t − 4, t − 1] firm requirements, match the owner-death firm on three-digit industry and t − 1 sales decile, and have a year-t owner who matches the dying owner on t − 1 income fractile and five-year age bin. For Panel B, we identify all 5,312 “owner-retirement” firms that satisfy requirements similar to those for owner-death firms except that instead CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 41 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019

FIGURE V(Continued). of death, we measure retirement as the firm having at least one owner receiving W-2 wages in consecutive years [t − 4, t − 1] and no one receiving wages [t, t + 1]. Counterfactual firms had at least one owner receiving W-2 wages [t − 4, t + 1]. Each panel presents simple difference-in-differences estimates of the event (death or retirement) impact on annual firm profits ($K) per mean annual preperiod worker. Displayed 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered at the firm level. See Online Appendix Figures I.6 for analogous graphs for top 1% and top 0.1% owners. profits can derive from a number of mechanisms. The firm could contract (e.g., by closing one of many store fronts) in response to worse managerial inputs. Owner charisma or connections may have kept key employees at the firm until her death. Or a firm could replace its dead owner-manager (compensated in profits) with a hired nonowner manager (compensated in wages), yielding a decline in measured profits. In each case, the withdrawal of the owner’s human capital caused profits to decline. The graph’s rightmost data point, also reported in Table IV, Panel A, column (1), is our main estimate: the average death of a top-earning owner caused a $20,591 decline in profits per preperiod worker four years after the owner death. This esti- mated impact has a t-statistic of 3.5. The bottom rows of the column transform the estimated dollar impact into a percentage impact as follows. The mean profits per preperiod worker at counterfactual firms in t + 4 was $38,401. The average dying owner had an ownership share of 65.7% and thus, on average, may have withdrawn only 65.7% of the firms’ owners’ human capital contributions. Dividing −$20,591 by $38,401 and by 65.7% yields an estimated impact of an effective 100% owner death of −81.6%, our preferred percentage impact. Columns (2) and (3) separate column (1)’s main effect into extensive and intensive margins. Column (2) finds that the mean death of a top-earning owner caused her firm to be 19.8 percent- age points less likely to have survived four years after the owner death, relative to counterfactual firms. This extensive-margin ef- fect size has a t-statistic of 11.6. Column (3) restricts the sample to firms that survive through t + 4, finding an intensive margin effect of −$13,252 that is marginally significant with a t-statistic of 1.9.39 Comparison of bottom-row values of columns (1)–(3)

39. The analogous t-statistic among top 1% owner deaths is 4.6, as the sample is substantially larger (Online Appendix Table J.7). While conditioning on sur- vival entails conditioning on an endogenous outcome, we nevertheless report it for interpretation in combination with columns (1)–(2). 42 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 92.3% 29,543 owners − − Top-0.1% 72.9% 12,920 owners Top-1% − − Profits per preperiod X 89.7% 23,900 − − X ROFITS P X 75.6% 47.2% IRM 25,960 5,205 F − − 95.2% 13,843 − − ETIREMENTS ON Profits per preperiod worker ($/worker) worker ($/worker) R 55.0% 13,252 − − TABLE IV Million-dollar-earning owners EATHS AND D 0.198 (pp) 34.2% Firm − − survival WNER O (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) 81.6% 20,591 0.003 0.072 0.001 0.001 0.006 0.000 0.004 0.004 0.005 MPACT OF (5,886) (0.017) (7,074) (6,763) (9,096) (4,450) (6,896) (1,831) (10,582) − I − ($/worker) Profits per preperiod worker 2 etbfr6 X XXXX XXX Surviving firms onlyMinority ownerMajority owner Deathbefore65 Death after 75 S-corporations only ObservationsOwner deathsR 581,508 765 X 581,508 236,241 208,107 765 373,401 57,060 519,804 390 X 2,609,973 194,787 339 426 725 658 2,436 435 Impact Mean of counterfactual firmsDying owners ownership %Preferred percentage impact 38,401 65.7% 0.881 41,813 65.7% 36,919 57.7% 39,580 39.4% 18,494 86.7% 38,886 59.6% 27,258 68.5% 48,221 65.0% 66.4% Panel A: Owner deaths CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 43 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 71.7% 45,861 owners − − Top-0.1% the owner deaths atched owner-death ched counterfactual 59.6% 17,150 for more details. share of dying owners is cally constructed sample owners Top-1% − − f matched pairs where the Profits per preperiod III.B and X 85.9% 39,774 − − Sections III.A X 72.2% 40,109 − − 29,483 140.4% − − Profits per preperiod worker ($/worker) worker ($/worker) 45.6% 23,192 ONTINUED − − TABLE IV C Million-dollar-earning owners , Panels A and B. See the notes to that figure for details. Column (3) repeats column (2) on the subset of 0.263 (pp) 37.9% Firm − − survival Figure V (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) 82.5% 37,210 0.004 0.107 0.002 0.003 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.003 (4,000) (0.007) (5,003) (7,296) (4,771) (4,051) (1,027) (7,286) − − ($/worker) Profits per preperiod worker This table estimates the impact of an owner “exit,” embodied in an owner death or retirement, on firm performance four years after the event. Panel A uses 2 Surviving firms onlyMinority ownerMajority owner S-corporations only ObservationsOwner retirementsR 5,312 442,566 442,566 5,312 214,722 X 116,064 2,969 326,502 1,449 3,863 422,370 X 1,432,179 255,897 4,974 16,548 3,176 Impact Mean of counterfactual firmsRetiring owners ownership %Preferred percentage impact 59,996 75.2% 0.924 75.2% 67,044 75.8% 52,344 40.1% 62,866 88.3% 60,464 37,780 76.6% 84,573 76.2% 75.6% Notes. matched pairs of owner-death firmsdying and owner counterfactual had firms 50% that or survivedof less four matched ownership years owner-death in after firms the theS-corporations. owner-death owner that The firm; death. is column outcome Column based (5) (4) mean repeats onmeasured repeats of column column in owners counterfactual (2) (2) the who firms on on year died is all the before other subset the at owner pairs. o weighted age death. Column mean Panel 75 (6) B four repeats or repeats years column greater. Panel (2) after Column A in owner (7) for an death the repeats identi subset (see column of the (1) owner-retirement text in and for counterfactual an the firms. identically weight). See constructed The sample ownership of m Panel B: Owner retirements sample to analyze thefirms. Columns impact (1)–(2) of report owner the deaths right-most on coefficients plotted firm in performance four years after owner death relative to one year before owner death, relative to the mat 44 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 suggests that most of the column (1) impact is along the inten- sive margin. Columns (4)–(7) report heterogeneity and placebo results that corroborate the interpretation of owner death impacts as reflect- ing the withdrawal of the owner’s human capital services. One might expect majority owners to be more likely to actively man- age their firms than minority owners, implying that a majority owner death causes a larger decline in firm profits than a minority owner death. Columns (4) and (5) test this prediction by repeating column (1) on the subset of owner-death firms with dying minor- ity owners (those with less than or exactly 50% ownership) and firms with dying majority owners (all others), respectively. Both columns reveal large and statistically significant profit impacts, but the dying-majority-owner impact is nearly twice as large as the dying-minority-owner impact. This pattern is consistent with profit impacts of owner deaths stemming from the withdrawal of human capital services. Recall that our owner deaths analysis sample restricts to own- ers below age 65. Nonelderly owners are more likely to be active managers than elderly owners. We therefore construct a sample of elderly owner deaths—exactly analogous to the main owner deaths analysis sample, except restricting to owners who died at age 75 or greater and to counterfactual firms with similarly aged owners. Column (6) repeats column (1) in the elderly owner deaths sample. We find an insignificant and near-zero impact of an elderly owner death on firm profits. Earlier work has assumed that 0% of S-corporation prof- its is labor income (Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014; PSZ) but that 70% of partnership profits is labor income (PSZ). Although the partnership assumption is close to our main estimate, the S-corporation assumption is not. Column (7) repeats column (1) while restricting the sample to S-corporations. The resulting es- timate is similar to the main estimate, indicating that the main estimate is not simply driven by partnerships.40 Finally, columns (8) and (9) repeat column (1) in our broader and lower-mean-income top 1% sample and our narrower and higher-mean-income top 0.1% sample.41 Effects are ordered

40. Our sample is dominated by dying S-corporation owners, due in large part to the 20% ownership share threshold and to requiring that the firm had positive preperiod workers. 41. The million-dollar-earner sample includes everyone in the top 0.1% sam- ple; the top 1% sample includes everyone in the million-dollar-earner sample. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 45 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 across our three top groups in both dollar and percentage terms. In particular, we find a −72.9% impact of top 1% owner deaths and a noisier −92.3% impact of top 0.1% owner deaths, compared to the −81.6% impact of a million-dollar-earner death.42 See Online Appendix Table J.7 for full top 1% and top 0.1% owner- death results.

IV.B. The Profit Impact of Owner Retirements A natural concern is that because an owner death may be unanticipated, the prior section’s results may primarily reflect a chaotic disruption rather than the withdrawal of the owner’s hu- man capital. We therefore complement our owner-deaths analysis by estimating the impact of inferred orderly transitions of owners out of employment at their owned firms (“retirement”). Specifically, we follow the owner-deaths sample frame and matching procedure detailed in Section IV.A,withfouramend- ments. First, rather than defining an owner-death event, we de- fine an owner-retirement event in year t as the firm transitioning from consecutive years [t − 4, t − 1] with at least one owner re- ceiving W-2 wages (perhaps different owners in different years) to years [t, t + 1] with no owner receiving W-2 wages while still having positive sales. Second, we match owner-retirement firms to counterfactual firms at which at least one owner received W-2 wages in consecutive years [t − 4, t + 1]. Third, we allow owners to be any age because elderly owners working at their firms may nevertheless be representative of typical owners. Fourth, we re- quire owner-retirement and counterfactual firms to have positive sales [t − 4, t + 1] rather than merely [t − 4, t − 1] because exited firms cannot be classified into owner-retirement or counterfac- tual categories. We make no restrictions on owner-retirement or counterfactual firms in years [t + 2, t + 4]. The owner-retirements sample is substantially larger than the owner-deaths sample, with 5,312 owner-retirement firms compared with 765 owner-deaths firms. Online Appendix Table J.6 provides a waterfall showing how sample restrictions yield our analysis sample size. Our owner-retirements research design has strengths and weaknesses relative to our owner-deaths research design. Its primary strength is that it may identify instances where an actively participating owner is replaced by a hired nonowner

42. An earlier draft reported a smaller impact for top 1% owner deaths (see Online Appendix H.4 for details). 46 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 manager, without the disruption of an unanticipated death. Replacement of an actively participating owner by a nonowner manager rather than by another owner is helpful for our analysis. This replacement can induce a change in compensation: profits to the owner manager replaced by the salary of a nonowner manager. In contrast, replacing an active owner with another equally productive active owner could yield no change in profits despite profits entirely reflecting returns to owner human capital. On the other hand, death is measured with almost no error from vital records, whereas retirement is only inferred. In fact, we find suggestive evidence that many inferred retirements are not actual retirements: 13% of retirement firms issued a W-2 in t + 4 to at least one of its owners. Thus, our owner-retirement estimates may understate the true effect of withdrawing owner human capital. We estimate our event study specification equation (1) in our owner retirements sample and report the results in Figure V, Panel B and Table IV, Panel B. Figure V, Panel B’s flat prere- tirement trend corroborates our identifying assumption that in the absence of retirement, owner-retirement firms and counter- factual firms would exhibit common trends in profits per prepe- riod worker. Profits per preperiod worker decline immediately and persistently in the year of retirement. The rightmost estimate in Figure V, Panel B is reported in column (1) of Table IV, Panel B: an estimated causal impact of −$37,210 with a t-statistic of 9.3. The bottom row follows the same calculations used in Panel A to arrive at our preferred owner-retirement percentage impact of −82.5%. This preferred estimate is nearly identical to our owner-deaths estimate of −81.6%. Columns (8) and (9) present analogous estimates for top-1%-owner retirements and top-0.1%-owner retirements: −59.6% and −71.7%, respectively (see Online Appendix Table J.8 for full results).

1. Discussion. Our analysis below requires an estimate of the share of top pass-through income that is a return to owner human capital. Million-dollar earners are the middle of the three top groups on which we focus; both the owner-deaths and owner- retirements specifications for this group suggest an estimate of 82%. The estimated owner-retirement effects are monotonic across top income groups in dollar terms but not in percent- age terms. Motivated by the possibility of specification noise and CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 47 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 effectively weighting high earners the most, the average of the six percentage impacts (top 1%, million-dollar-earners, and top 0.1% across both owner deaths and retirements) is 76.8%. To further explore the robustness of these estimates, Online Appendix Table J.9 compares the equal-weighted estimates in Table IV for the top 1% to alternative specifications that weigh observations using average pre-event profits. Recall that top- owned pass-throughs are much smaller than public companies: 72% of top-1% pass-through profits accrue to firms with less than $50M in profits (see Figure III and Online Appendix Figures I.3 and I.4 for distributions by firm size). Superstar firms such as Amazon are not prominent, even on a dollar-weighted basis, within the pass-through sector. Thus, equal-weighted estimates within the pass-through sector are a priori likely to be close to dollar-weighted estimates. To explore this point, we consider multiple dollar-weighting schemes and subsample analyses to evaluate how sensitive the overall estimates are to how we treat the largest firms. First, weighting by the log of preperiod profits increases the estimated percentage impact in both the owner-death and owner-retirement samples with little loss of precision. Second, we implement a bounding exercise in which we estimate dollar-weighted treat- ment effects for all but the largest firms and bound the over- all effect by assuming the full range of treatment effects from 0% to 100% for the largest firms. For owner deaths, we find a dollar-weighted treatment effect for firms with less than $50M in pre-event profits of 87.1%. Such firms generate 72% of total top 1% pass-through profits, so we bound the overall effect from 62.4% (= 0.72 × 87% + (1 − 0.72) × 0%) to 90.8% (= 0.72 × 87% + (1 − 0.72) × 100%). Owner retirements deliver larger estimates. Overall, dollar-weighted approaches deliver similar if not larger estimates relative to the equal-weighted analysis, although the standard errors do increase with dollar-weighting. For the next section’s analysis, we use 75% as a round number robustly supported by all weighting approaches. We also report analyses using smaller shares in both the person-level and dollar-level calculations.43

43. We use fiscal income in defining the owners’ groups for Table IV.Thetop 1% estimates are smaller than the estimates based on higher earners, so it is likely that the top 1% estimates defined using imputed national income—whose thresholds are higher than fiscal income thresholds—would be larger. 48 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 The findings in this and the previous section contribute to a literature on the effect of managers and CEOs on firm perfor- mance using research designs based on retirements, family suc- cession, and CEO deaths. Johnson et al. (1985), Perez-Gonz´ alez´ (2006),andBennedsen et al. (2007) find that when replacing an outgoing CEO, choosing an external CEO increases firm value and performance relative to choosing a within-family CEO. In Danish administrative data, Bennedsen, Perez-Gonz´ alez,´ and Wolfenzon (forthcoming) use CEO deaths and hospitalizations, respectively, to show that these events cause significant declines in profitability, with larger effects for CEOs who are younger and more likely to be actively involved in the firm’s operations.44 The estimates from our owner death design are considerably larger than estimates from these studies, which find average ef- fects of professional CEOs between 10% and 25% in terms of op- erating profitability. Two factors can naturally explain the dis- crepancy. First, previous work has tended to estimate the effect of one CEO being replaced by another CEO, thereby identifying only the difference in human capital returns between two man- agers. In contrast, our estimates aim to measure the full human capital return of a manager appearing in profits, as a firm re- places an owner manager (whose human capital return may for tax reasons appear in profits) with a hired manager (who would be compensated in wages). Second, previous work has often esti- mated effects among especially large or publicly traded companies that may be more capital intensive than the typical firm in the economy. Capital-intensive firms (like an oil extraction firm) may depend less than other firms on managerial talent. Becker and Hvide (2017) find large effects of entrepreneur deaths on quite small firms in Norway. Relative to their work, our study broadens the scope of analysis to much larger firms with high-income own- ers in a different institutional context that directly informs the character of top U.S. incomes.45

44. Consistent with our findings, Jager¨ (2016) uses German data to show that manager deaths cause a decline of average yearly wages among incumbent workers of approximately 1%. However, his article does not estimate effects on firm performance. 45. Among our million-dollar-owner-death firms, the mean number of employ- ees is 172 and the median is 41. Among Becker and Hvide’s owner-death firms, the median number of employees is 4. Becker and Hvide find statistically significant effects of owner deaths on firms in the first four quintiles of firm size but not on firms in the largest quintile (those with more than eight employees). CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 49 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 IV.C. The Profit and Wages Impacts of Corporate-Form Switching We have found that most pass-through profits represent the returns to human capital. We now test a tax-incentive mechanism for these returns being reported on business tax returns (and thereby recorded in National Accounts) as pass-through profits, rather than as wages paid to the owner. As discussed in Section II.A, private firms have considerable leeway in how they pay owners and face differing tax incentives to use that leeway: C-corporations face tax incentives to pay owners in wages, while pass-throughs face tax incentives to pay owners in profits. We investigate the tax-incentive mechanism by testing for a sudden divergence in profit and wage trends after firms transition from C-corporation form to pass-through form. We collect data on the population of businesses that switch from C-corporation to S-corporation form between 2001 and 2014.46 On average, approximately 67,000 C-corporations switch each year, corresponding to between 3% and 5% of all C- corporations. We study total wage payments or profits as a fraction of contemporaneous firm sales in an event study framework:  k (2) Yit = γkD + αi + δt + εit, k∈{−5+,−4,−3,−2,0,1,2,3,4,5+} where γk is the coefficient vector of interest on event time indi- cators, αi are firm fixed effects, and δt are calendar year fixed effects.47 Wage payments equals salaries and wages plus compen- sation of officers as listed on the business income tax return.48 The analysis sample includes 157,272 firms that switched from C-corporation to S-corporation between 2001 and 2010. The sam- ple includes all firms that existed for at least four years prior to and four years following the switch and generated at least $100K in sales in the year prior to the switch.

46. Over this time period, the vast majority of transitions were from C- to S-corporation form, rather than from S- to C- or from C- to partnership. There are few in the former case because of tax preference for the S-corporation form that began in 1986. There are few in the latter case because of rules requiring the firm to unincorporate in the event of these transitions. 47. We cannot directly study changes in owners’ wage payments because C- corporations are not linked to owners. 48. This sum should typically equal total W-2 payments, except for manufac- turing firms, which deduct production-worker wages on a separate form unavail- able to us. 50 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Figure VI, Panel A plots the impacts on profits and wage pay- ments for all firms in the switchers analysis sample. Despite a preperiod trend in profits, the graph shows a sharp divergence be- tween profits and wages in the year of the switch. Wage payments fall sharply in the switching year by 2.29% on average relative to sales, and this decline in wage payments is offset by an aver- age profit margin increase of 1.70%. In words, nearly 2% of sales are suddenly paid as profits instead of wages upon switching to S- corporation form. This pattern is consistent with the tax-incentive mechanism for pass-through owners’ human capital returns being paid as profits. Figure VI plots two heterogeneity analyses that further sup- port the tax-incentive mechanism. S-corporation profits must be distributed pro rata to ownership share. A firm with one active owner-manager supplying human capital and a passive owner supplying none would therefore be relatively unlikely to charac- terize human capital returns as profits. Instead, the active owner- manager would likely insist on being paid in salary or bonus— sacrificing taxes so as not to share her human capital returns with a passive owner. Nonmajority-owned firms are relatively likely to have at least one passive owner, so we would expect such firms to exhibit a smaller change in profits and wage payments after aC-to-Sswitch.Figure VI, Panel A shows that expectation is in- deed the case empirically. When limiting the sample to the 14,600 firms with no owner in the year of the switch having at least a 50% ownership share, the change in profits and wage payments is markedly less pronounced than in the full sample. Human capital is a primary factor of production in high- skilled service-sector firms, such as medical practices and con- sultancies. Owners of such firms may be especially likely to also serve as a manager rather than hiring a nonowner manager, and the labor share of value added tends to be higher at such firms. High-skilled service-sector firms may therefore exhibit especially large changes in profits and wage payments after a C-to-S switch. Figure VI, Panel B shows that that is indeed in the case. When limiting the sample to the 53,220 firms with two-digit NAICS ∈ {51, 52, 54, 56, 61, 62} in the year of the switch, the change in prof- its and wage payments is markedly more pronounced than in the full sample. We conclude that the data support the tax-incentive explanation for human capital returns being recharacterized as pass-through profits. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 51 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) All vs. Non-Majority-Owned Firms 5 2.5 0 -2.5 Outcome as a percentage of sales (%) -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Years Since Switch Wages, All Firms Profits, All Firms Wages, Non-Majority Firms Profits, Non-Majority Firms

(B) All vs. Skilled Service Firms 5 2.5 0 -2.5 Outcome as a percentage of sales (%) -5

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Years Since Switch Wages, All Firms Profits, All Firms Wages, Service Firms Profits, Service Firms

FIGURE VI Impact of Organizational-Form Switch on Profits and Wage Payments This figure uses our linked firm-owner data to display how wage payments and profits change when a firm changes organizational form from C-corporation to S- corporation. The sample includes all 157,272 S-corporations that switched from C-corporate to S-corporate form between 2001–2010; had at least $100K in sales in the year prior to the switch; and were active in the four years before and four years following the switch. The No Majority series plot changes for the 14,600 firms that had only minority owners (i.e., with less than 50% ownership) in the switch year. The Service series plot changes for switch events for the 53,220 firms that were in high-skilled service industries, defined as having two-digit NAICS ∈ {51, 52, 54, 56, 61, 62}. We study two outcomes: annual profits divided by contemporane- ous sales, and annual wage payments (including officer compensation) divided by contemporaneous sales. Each plotted series comprises difference estimates for the outcome of interest relative to t − 1, conditional on firm and calendar year fixed effects. Displayed 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered at the firm level. 52 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 V. C HARACTERIZING TOP EARNERS AND INCOMES V.A. Most Top Earners Are Human-Capital Rich This subsection uses our estimates to characterize top earn- ers as human-capital rich or financial-capital rich. The question is whether a very high earner you might meet likely earns most of her income from her human capital or her financial capital. The answer plays a key role in debates about taxation. Kuziemko et al. (2015) find that survey respondents assess tax policy in part based on how income is earned. Moreover, traditional models of optimal taxation provide rationales for higher tax rates on labor income than on capital income (Atkinson and Stiglitz 1976; Judd 1985; Chamley 1986). To the extent that “capital” income is char- acterized as labor income, higher capital tax rates may be optimal (Piketty and Saez 2013). We classify a top earner as human-capital rich if the majority of her income derives from her human capital, which we refer to as labor income as in PSZ and elsewhere in the literature. We measure labor income as the sum of wage income (as defined in Section II.B) and 75% of pass-through income (based on our owner-death and owner-retirement event studies). We use our two measures of personal income—fiscal income and imputed national income—and report results for three top income groups—the top 1%, million-dollar earners, and the top 0.1%. Recall that the unit of observation in fiscal income is the tax unit and in imputed national income is the individual. Because imputed national income uses imputed C-corporate retained earnings and other passive capital income, labor income is lower when using the imputed national income measure. Figure VII displays the results for 2014. Panel A shows how the results in Figure I, Panel A change when adding the human capital share of pass-through income within the top decile, and Figure VII, Panel B focuses on our three top income groups. As a benchmark, we first plot the share of top earners who earn a majority of their income in wages. If 0% of pass-through in- come is labor income, the wage-earner share would equal the human-capital-rich share. Within the top decile, the share of peo- ple earning most of their income from wages falls dramatically at the top. Across five of the six top income groups, a minority of top earners are wage earners. For example among million-dollar earners, 46.8% are wage earners in the fiscal income definition and only 35.3% are wage earners in the imputed national income CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 53 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Share of People by Majority Income Source Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 100 100 80 80 60 60 40 40 Share of people (%) Share of people (%) 20 20 0 0 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P99-99.9 P99-99.9 P99.9-100 P99.9-100 Fiscal Income Bin Imputed National Income Bin Wages Wages + .75 Pass-through Wages Wages + .75 Pass-through Business Business - .75 Pass-through Business Business - .75 Pass-through Other capital income: interest, Other capital income: interest, rents, royalties, estates, trusts rents, royalties, estates, trusts

(B) Human-Capital Rich and Self-Made Shares of Top Earners Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 100 100 96.1 93.2 93.6 93.2 92.5 91.4 91.9 90.2 89.2 88.0 87.7 87.6 85.1 86.6 86.5 86.6 84.9 82.8 80.9 82.6 81.9 75 75 77.2 73.4 75.3 75.0 74.2 69.8 67.2 62.0 62.4 56.1 50 50 46.8 42.9 40.5 35.3 Share of People (%) Share of People (%) 25 25 23.2 0 0 Top 1% Million-dollar earners Top 0.1% Top 1% Million-dollar earners Top 0.1% Wage earners (i.e. has majority income from wages) Wage earners (i.e. has majority income from wages) Human-capital rich (i.e. has majority income from labor) Human-capital rich (i.e. has majority income from labor) Human-capital rich, parent-linked subset Human-capital rich, parent-linked subset Self-made (i.e. has bottom-99% parent), parent-linked subset Self-made (i.e. has bottom-99% parent), parent-linked subset Self-made, parent-linked workers Self-made, parent-linked workers Self-made, parent-linked entrepreneurs Self-made, parent-linked entrepreneurs

FIGURE VII Are Top Earners Human-Capital Rich? The left figure in Panel B uses our top-incomes data to classify top earners (tax units) in the 2014 fiscal income series. The right figure in Panel B classifies top earners (individual) in the 2014 imputed national income series. Wage earners are those earning a majority of their income from wages. Human-capital rich are those earning a majority of their income from labor income, defined as wages plus 75% of pass-through income (before INI tax allocations that reduce the INI top 1% pass- through labor share to 70%). The parent-linked subset comprises 32–34-year-olds who can be linked to parents. The self-made bars plot the share of top earners in the indicated subset who had a parent earning in the bottom 99% of the income distribution. Entrepreneurs are earners who earned a majority of their income as pass-through entrepreneurial income, defined as pass-through income plus owner wages (i.e., W-2 wages earned from owned pass-throughs). The Panel B legends describe the bars from left to right. definition. Thus, when ignoring pass-through income, a minority of top earners appear to be human-capital rich. That conclusion reverses when classifying 75% of pass- through income as labor income. The share earning most of their income from human capital falls much less within the top decile. The figure’s “human-capital rich” series reveal that most top 54 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 earners are human-capital rich, not financial-capital rich. For example among million-dollar earners, 89.2% are human-capital rich in the fiscal income definition and 67.2% are human-capital rich in the imputed national income definition. Even among the top 0.1% in the imputed national income series, 56.1% are human- capital rich, relative to only 23.2% being primarily wage earners. We conclude that the human capital component of pass-through income transforms one’s view of whether the typical top earner is human-capital rich. Online Appendix H.2 provides two robustness analyses. The first uses the minimum estimate of the labor share of pass-through income by income group in Table IV, rather than the mean of 75%. The second classifies all private C-corporation wages as capital income. In 12 permutations, a majority of top earners are human- capital rich. Finally, we may in fact understate the human-capital- rich share of top owners because pass-through income is not the only form of “capital” income that includes recharacter- ized wages. In particular, there are prominent tax-advantaged ways to use C-corporation retained earnings to compensate entrepreneurs, hired managers, private equity, and angel in- vestors for their human capital services.49 Estimating the human capital content of C-corporation income is a priority for future work.

V.B. Most Top Earners in the 1980–1982 Cohort Are Self-Made A potential concern with the preceding analysis is that some people with high wages may in fact be providing little human capital services, even when not earning wages from a private C- corporation. In particular, drawing a salary from a family pass- through can be an effective way for a rich family to avoid estate

49. First, private equity managers often receive compensation for their man- agement services via high retained earnings of portfolio companies. Second, entrepreneurs like Bill Gates are often compensated in “sweat equity” (Bhandari and McGrattan 2018), thereby earning a much larger share of C- corporation income than nonmanager investors who contributed identical financial inputs. Third, hired executives at midstage startups can be compensated with spe- cial underpriced shares such that the executive receives a large capital gain if not fired. Fourth, startups permit angel investors and other venture capitalists to in- vest at discounts as compensation for the investors’ human capital services, such as operating advice and business connections. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 55 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 taxes. In such cases, an individual could be erroneously labeled as human-capital rich. We therefore analyze the concept of being self-made, as op- posed to being a financial heir. Analogous to Piketty, Postel-Vinay, and Rosenthal (2014), we define an individual as self-made if she earns most of her income from her human capital or from savings out of her previous human capital returns, rather than from in- herited financial capital. U.S. tax data lack detailed information on inheritances. However, we can link young top earners to their parents. In the parent-linked sample, we can therefore compute a likely conservative estimate of the self-made share of top earn- ers under the assumption that top earners with sufficiently low- earning parents almost surely do not have high incomes through financial inheritance. Specifically, we attempt to link all of the individuals born 1980–1982 in our top incomes data to parent-income percentiles, using parent-child links and parent income percentiles provided by Chetty et al. (2019). The year 1980 is the first birth cohort for which parent income can be measured. We match 83% of top 1% individuals born in 1980–1982 to their parents; parent in- come is unavailable for individuals who immigrated to the United States after their teenage years. Parent income is defined as mean adjusted gross income of the child’s parents when the child is aged 15–19. Parent-income percentiles are defined within birth co- horts, with the top 1% ranging between $511K and $552K in 2014 dollars. Bottom 99% parents are therefore unlikely to have assets above the 2014 estate tax exemption of $5.3 million and are un- likely to make large enough financial bequests to place a child into a top income group. We therefore classify an individual as self-made if her parents were not in the top 1%. This is a con- servative classification, as many children of the top 1% do not work for their parents’ firms and do not receive especially large financial inheritances.50 Figure VII, Panel B plots the results. A slightly larger share of the parent-linked sample is classified as human-capital rich than in the overall sample, but the differences are small. The fig- ure shows that across income definitions and top income groups,

50. Averaging parent incomes over five years smooths out fluctuations in parental income, for example, due to temporary business losses. While it is possible that children receive large inheritances from rich grandparents, it is unlikely that the middle generation (the parents) would have relatively low income. 56 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 more than three out of four of top earners in the parent-linked sample did not have top 1% parents. For example among million- dollar earners, 85.1% in the fiscal income series and 75.3% in the imputed national income series are self-made. The remaining bars plot similar statistics for human-capital rich (i.e., those with majority income from labor) and entrepreneurs (i.e., those with majority income from pass-throughs). In all cases, at least 74% are self-made. Thus, children of the top 1% are very dispropor- tionately represented among young million-dollar-earners but do not constitute a majority. Recall that these self-made statistics are likely lower bounds, as many adult children of the top 1% are also not dependent on financial inheritance. Although we can mea- sure these outcomes only for the 1980–1982 cohorts, the results support the conclusion that our human-capital-rich statistics are robust to excluding any financial inheritances recharacterized as labor income. Note that Chetty et al. (2014) (CHKS) published a 100-by- 100 appendix transition matrix that suggests an even higher self-made share of 90.4%. Yet because they measure child in- come within the 1980–1982 birth cohorts rather than nationally, many of their top 1% children (measured at approximately age 30) were not in the overall (i.e., across all ages) top 1% and in particular were not million-dollar earners or in the top 0.1%. Our self-made statistics reach further into the tail of the income distribution and are computed in both fiscal income (as in CHKS) and in imputed national income.51

V.C. Top Labor Income and Entrepreneurial Income Are Large This subsection uses our labor-versus-capital classification of pass-through income to characterize the labor share and the entrepreneurial share of top incomes. One reason the top 1% are of interest is that their earnings constitute a disproportionate share of the economy and tax base. Therefore, it is useful to conduct a

51. CHKS find that children’s income ranks stabilize by their early 30s, sug- gesting that most of their top 1% children will eventually lie in the overall top 1% as their incomes grow over the lifecycle. CHKS measure parent and child incomes using fiscal income. They do not publish their top 1% child income threshold, but their top 1% child income mean ($423K in 2014 dollars) is nearly the same as our top 1% fiscal income threshold ($390K), which implies that their top group encompasses substantially lower earners than ours. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 57 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 dollar-level analysis of top earners that complements our person- level analysis. We divide top pass-through income into labor and capital por- tions and then add other sources of labor and capital income to account for total top income. As before, we allocate 75% of top pass-through income to labor and the rest to capital.52 We also use our linked firm-owner-worker files to determine how much W-2 wage income accrues to pass-through business owners, which enables us to quantify total top entrepreneurial income. These contributions enable a more comprehensive analysis of the nature of top earners’ income—how much is labor income, how much is entrepreneurial income, and how these amounts compare to other income components—than has been possible. We find that top la- bor income and top entrepreneurial income are substantial and larger than previously documented. Figure VIII, Panel A shows how the results for the top decile from Figure I, Panel B change when combining wage income and the human capital component of pass-through income. Figure VIII, Panel B shows results for our top income groups. We present two findings. First, despite the fact that capital income accrues disproportionately to top earners, we find that a large share of top income is labor income. In particular, 77% of top 1% fiscal income and 52% of top 1% imputed national income is clas- sified as labor income. Hence, our classification of three-quarters of pass-through income as labor income reverses the earlier finding in PSZ that a minority (45%) of top 1% imputed national income is labor income. Even among million-dollar earners, 71% of fiscal income and 47% of imputed national income is labor income. In the top 0.1%, labor income shares fall to the still large numbers of 69% and 42%, respectively.53 Second, top entrepreneurial income is large. We define entrepreneurial income as the sum of two components: (i) pass- through income, and (ii) W-2 wage payments to pass-through

52. See Online Appendix Figure I.8 for results using alternative labor shares. See also Online Appendix Figure I.10 for alternative results when reclassifying all wages from private C-corporations as capital. 53. To evaluate the robustness of these results, we consider two conserva- tive scenarios. Online Appendix Figure I.8 shows that the top 1% labor share in imputed national income is 48% when classifying only 59.6% (56% after tax im- putations) of pass-through income as labor income. Online Appendix Figure I.10 shows that the top 1% labor share in imputed national income is 47% when very conservatively reclassifying all private C-corporation wages as profits. 58 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Share of Income by Source Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 100 100 80 80 60 60 40 40 Share of Bin's INI (%) 20 20 Share of Bin's Fiscal Income (%) 0 0 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P90-91 P91-92 P92-93 P93-94 P94-95 P95-96 P96-97 P97-98 P98-99 P99-99.9 P99-99.9 P99.9-100 P99.9-100 Fiscal Income Bin Imputed National Income Bin Wages Wages + .75 Pass-through Wages Wages + .75 Pass-through Business Business - .75 Pass-through Business Business - .75 Pass-through Other capital income Other capital income

(B) Top Labor and Capital Income Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 2,000 3,000 825.8

92.2 1,500 773.4

2,000 677.0 433.5 49.8 47% 1,000 118.1 290.9 452.9 233.7 Income (B) Income (B) 339.1 30.3 35% Labor Income=52% 188.4 329.4 42% 403.6 245.8 485.0 59.5 1,000 35% 71%

Labor Income=77% 134.7

500 41.5 398.8

263.0 69% 134.5 208.9 340.8 44% Entrepreneurial Income=39%

45% 688.7 108.7 87.7 69.6 Entrepreneurial Income=35% 476.3 76.7 65.2 345.5 141.6 100.4 84.0 0 0 Top 1% Million-dollar earners Top 0.1% Top 1% Million-dollar earners Top 0.1% Nonowner wages Owner wages Nonowner wages Owner wages Pass-through labor Pass-through capital Pass-through labor Pass-through capital C-corporation dividends Other capital income C-corporation dividends + RE Other capital income

FIGURE VIII How Do Top Earners Earn Their Income? This figure uses our top-incomes data to quantify sources of top incomes in 2014. Wages, pass-through income, and C-corporation income (dividends, or divi- dends and retained earnings), and other capital income are defined as in Figure I. Pass-through labor income equals 75% of pass-through income (before INI tax allo- cations that reduce the INI top 1% pass-through labor share to 70%); pass-through capital income equals the remainder of pass-through income. Owner wages equal W-2 wages paid to owners from pass-throughs they own; nonowner wages equal the remainder of wages. The Panel B bars list Nonowner wages on top, then Owner wages, etc., as listed in the legends. owners. Figure I showed that 32%–39% of top 1% and top 0.1% fiscal income is pass-through income. Adding owner wage payments, which has not been previously possible, increases top entrepreneurial income to 35%–45%. Note that some portion of C-corporation income also accrues to founders, so a broader def- inition of entrepreneurial income would yield larger estimates.54

54. A large share of C-corporation income is earned by publicly traded compa- nies and does not accrue to founders in the year it is earned. For example, Jeff Bezos CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 59 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Top entrepreneurial income is large relative to all other in- come components. In every top income group and income defi- nition, entrepreneurial income rivals or exceeds both nonowner wage income and non-pass-through capital income. For example among million-dollar earners, 44% of fiscal income and 35% of im- puted national income is pass-through entrepreneurial income. In contrast, 37% of fiscal income and 22% of imputed national in- come is nonowner wage income, and 19% of fiscal income and 44% of imputed national income is non-pass-through capital income. Notably, entrepreneurial income far exceeds C-corporation (and therefore public equity) income, which amounts to 8% of fiscal in- come and 20% of imputed national income. Hence, entrepreneurial income constitutes a large portion of U.S. top incomes.

VI. THE GROWTH OF TOP ENTREPRENEURIAL INCOME This section puts the cross-sectional results on top business income in the context of how top income inequality has evolved over the past five decades. We find that top pass-through in- come has grown dramatically over time, even after adjusting for tax-induced organizational form switching. We then use our linked firm-owner-worker data from 2001–2014 to decompose this growth into three components—labor productivity, redistribution from workers to owners, and sectoral scale. We find important roles for the growth in labor productivity as well as redistribution from workers to owners.

VI.A. The Sources of Top Income Growth As in Section III.A, we decompose top incomes into three sources: wage income, business income, and other capital income. Figure IX, Panel A plots the time series of these sources using top fiscal income and imputed national income. Figure IX, Panel B plots the time series of the two components of business income: pass-through income and C-corporation income. Figure IX, Panel C plots the time series of the top 1% labor share, defined either

became 2018’s richest person in the world largely by founding Amazon. He owned 48% of Amazon prior to its 1997 IPO but sold most of that stake by 2018, so the vast majority of Amazon’s 2018 profits accrued to people other than Bezos. Hence, even if C-corporations could be linked to owners, the national income concept has limitations in classifying entrepreneurial income. The Haig-Simons income con- cept, which includes price-driven capital gains omitted from the national income concept, could prove fruitful in future work. 60 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Sources of Top 1% Income Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 10 10 8 8 6 6 4 4 Top 1% income in this form Top 1% income in this form 2 2 as share of fiscal income (%) as share of national income (%) 0 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Wage income Wage income Business income Business income Other capital income Other capital income

(B) Sources of Top 1% Business Income Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 Top 1% income in this form Top 1% income in this form as share of fiscal income (%) as share of national income (%) 0 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Pass-through income Pass-through income C-corporation dividends C-corporation dividends + retained earnings

(C) Top 1% Labor Share Fiscal Income (FI) Imputed National Income (INI) 80 80 70 70 60 60 50 50 40 40 30 Labor share of top 1% 30 imputed national income (%) 20 20 Labor share of top 1% fiscal income (%) 10 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 10 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Wage income + .75 Pass-through [SYZZ] Wage income + .75 Pass-through [SYZZ] Wage income + .7 (Pass-through - S-corporation) [PSZ] Wage income Wage income

FIGURE IX Business Income and Rising U.S. Income Inequality (1960–2014) This figure uses our top-incomes data to show the relative importance of different income sources for the evolution of top-income shares. See the notes to Figure I for definitions. with or without the human capital component of pass-through income. Three facts emerge. First, the second half of the twentieth century saw a spectacular rise in wage income for top earners. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 61 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 However, since the late 1990s, rising top wage income ceded to rising top nonwage income. Second, the vast majority of rising top nonwage income came in the form of business income.55 In both fiscal and imputed na- tional income, the path of top wage income mirrors the path of top business income, suggesting that some of the observed slowdown in top wage growth manifested in faster business income growth. Indeed, adding 75% of pass-through income to wage income in defining the top 1% labor share substantially attenuates the de- cline in top labor income since the 1990s. Specifically, the top 1% labor share in fiscal income exceeds 75% without much of a trend since the late 1980s. In imputed national income, the top 1% labor share is lower (52%), having surged above 60% in the late 1990s and returned to its post-1985 average in recent years. Third, within business income, most of the growth took the form of pass-through income, rather than C-corporation income. The enduring impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86) on the distribution of business income is clearly visible in these series (Gordon and MacKie-Mason 1994; Slemrod 1996; MacKie-Mason and Gordon 1997; Gordon and Slemrod 2000; Clarke and Kopczuk 2017). Because the reform raised the burden on traditional C- corporations and lowered top personal income rates, pass-through income jumped and has been steadily rising ever since, as new and growing businesses are more likely to choose pass-through form. Pass-through income growth features centrally in both the fiscal income and imputed national income series, which also includes imputed C-corporation retained earnings. In Online Appendix F, we quantitatively evaluate the rel- ative contributions to top income growth and business income growth over 1990–2014 and 2000–2014 of various business in- come sources under alternative approaches for imputing retained earnings. We estimate that pass-through accounts for 60%–73% of the business income growth since 1990 and 38%–56% of the business income growth since 2000.56 Retained earnings account

55. In both fiscal income and imputed national income, the components of nonwage income not included in business income are much less consequential. The fiscal income shows essentially no growth in this category, whereas the imputed national income series shows modest growth, though some disagreement remains about the size of this increase. See Auten and Splinter (2018) and Bricker et al. (2016). 56. The year 2000 appears to be a local minimum for C-corporation income, likely driven by fluctuations. The more robust fact is the reversal of 62 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 for more than two-thirds of C-corporation income growth, which underscores the importance of including retained earnings when studying top income growth. Understanding the rise of retained earnings, how it contributes to the aggregate capital share, and the rise of superstar firms is an important topic for ongoing and future research.

1. Pass-through Growth Is Not Just a Reporting Phenomenon. Rising top pass-through income partly reflects a type of relabeling of business income, as preexisting businesses reorganized from C- corporation to pass-through form and entrants increasingly chose pass-through form following TRA86. Focusing on 2001–2014, dur- ing which our linked firm-owner data are available, the pass- through share of total business sales—which rose from approx- imately 10% in the mid-1980s to 20% in 1990 to 35% in recent years—indicates that some share of rising top pass-through in- come is an artifact of changes in the organizational form through which business income is reported. We now quantify how much of the rise in top pass-through income is in fact a real economic phenomenon. Online Appendix H.3 contains more detail. To correct for the effect of differential net entry into the pass- through sector, we construct a counterfactual pass-through profit series that assumes the level of pass-through sales remains a constant share of total business sales (including S-corporations, C-corporations, and partnerships) throughout the time period. In 2014, the share of profit levels due to organizational-form changes is approximately 26%, while 74% of pass-through profits remain under the constant share assumption. In terms of growth, ac- tual top 0.1% profits increased 240% between 2001 and 2014 in real terms, and counterfactual profits rose 178%. Thus, most of the growth in top profits remains after adjusting for orga- nizational form reorganization.57 We note for the next subsec- tion that although we adjust the level of pass-through income of organizational-form changes, we make no adjustments for any compositional effects.

C-corporation income and pass-through income in the overall contribution to top income inequality over the past 50 years. 57. We consider an alternative approach to measuring the role of organizational-form switching using the population of businesses that switch from C-corporation to S-corporation form between 2001 and 2014. We find that 70% of the growth in S-corporation profits is due to firms that did not switch from C- corporation form during this time. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 63 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 VI.B. How Is Entrepreneurial Income Rising? Productivity versus Redistribution Investigating the relative contributions of the growth and dis- tribution of income can shed light on how entrepreneurial income has increased in recent years. Entrepreneurial income growth can come from two sources: growth in value added and growth in owners’ share of value added. Value-added growth can support explanations that emphasize technological progress, and owner share growth can support explanations that emphasize zero-sum compensation bargaining. A combination of value-added growth and owner share growth could also partly reflect managerial-skill- biased technological change. For example, an increase in the out- put elasticity of owner labor or network connections would result in both more value added and a larger owner share. We can decompose the overall growth in entrepreneurial in- come I into value-added growth and redistribution to owners:

Value-Added Growth    Redistribution VA    (3) I = + L + sowner ,  L Scale Labor Productivity where X denotes the log change in X, value-added growth sums growth in labor productivity and scale, and sowner is the share of value added that accrues to owners in either the form of owner wages or profits. We measure labor productivity as value added per worker, where value added equals profits plus W-2 wages and where the number of workers equals the number of W-2s issued by the firm. We measure scale as the number of workers.58 Figure X presents data on the creation and distribution of income in the pass-through sector among firms with top owners. Panels A and B focus on the components of value-added growth. Panel A shows how labor productivity (measured as value added per worker) and entrepreneurial income per worker have evolved

58. Gabaix and Landier (2008) emphasize firm size of competing firms as an important driver of CEO pay growth. Online Appendix Table J.10 implements a similar firm-level analysis to theirs. We find that top entrepreneurial income is increasing in firm size, but own-firm size is more important than the reference firm. These results suggest that top entrepreneurial income strongly depends on how large their firms are but somewhat less on factors that influence the market for CEO pay of the largest firms in the economy. 64 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 (A) Value-Added and Entrepreneurial (B) Pass-through Employment Income per Worker Adjusted for Org. Form Changes 40 60 50 30 40 30 20 Millions of Workers Thousands of Dollars 20 10 10 2011 2011 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 2013 2014 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 2013 2014

Top 1% Top 0.1% Top 1% Top 0.1% Value Added / L Value Added / L Number of Workers Number of Workers Entrepreneurial Income / L Entrepreneurial Income / L Org.-Form-Changes Adj. Org.-Form-Changes Adj.

(C) Decomposing Entrepreneurial (D) Falling Wages and Rising Income Growth Entrepreneurial Income Top 1% Top 0.1% 60 60

Top 1% (2001-2014) -24.1 63.0 61.1 6.5

45 9.3 45

Top 0.1% (2001-2014) -16.4 60.7 55.6 8.9 11.2 62.5

30 30 59.8 52.1 45.5 47.9 Top 1% (2004-2014) -21.9 75.5 46.4 38.6 31.2 15 15

Share of Value Added (%) Share of Value 26.2 Added (%) Share of Value

Top 0.1% (2004-2014) -32.5 83.3 49.2 0 Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay 0 Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay 2001 2014 2001 2014 -50 0 50 100 150 Share of Growth in Entrepreneurial Income (%) Entrep. Inc.: Profits Entrep. Inc.: Owner Wages Workers VA per Worker Owner Share Worker Pay

FIGURE X Why Is Entrepreneurial Income Rising? Productivity, Scale, or Redistribution Panel A uses our linked firm-owner data to plot aggregate value added per worker and entrepreneurial income (equal to pass-through income plus owner wages) per worker for top 1% and top 0.1% pass-through businesses. Panel B plots pass-through employment (the annual number of W-2s) for top 1% and top 0.1% pass-throughs. The Org.-Form-Changes Adjusted series reduces the main series’ growth by a factor equal to the pass-through sales share of total business sales in 2001 divided by the contemporaneous pass-through sales share. For 2014, this procedure reduces growth since 2001 by 24%. Panel C uses equation (3) to decompose the total growth in top entrepreneurial income into contributions from growth in value added per worker, in the owner share of value added, and in total employment adjusted for organizational-form changes. Results for total growth from 2001 to 2014 and from 2004 to 2014 are shown. Panel D shows the distribution of value added accruing to owners (in the form of profits and owner wages) and to nonowner workers (in the form of wages) for top-owned firms in 2001 and in 2014. since 2001. Panel B shows how the aggregate number of work- ers employed by top pass-throughs has evolved since 2001. We also present an adjusted series to account for organizational-form switching. Following this analysis, the adjusted series scales ac- tual employment by a factor equal to the pass-through sales share of total business sales in 2001 divided by the contemporaneous CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 65 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 pass-through sales share. For example, in 2014, this procedure reduces employment growth since 2001 by 24%. Labor productivity of top-owned firms has grown substan- tially from $33K to $43K. This increase in value added per worker is consistent with explanations of top-pay growth that emphasize technological progress, demand-driven growth in the service sec- tor, or higher markups. Entrepreneurial income has tracked the evolution of labor productivity closely, suggesting that an impor- tant part of overall top entrepreneurial income growth is due to these drivers of value-added growth. Aggregate pass-through em- ployment has increased more modestly and fluctuates consider- ably with the business cycle. Adjusting for organizational-form changes leaves the size of the workforce in top-owned firms essen- tially unchanged from 2001 to 2014. This pattern contrasts with the strong growth in top-owned profits even after adjusting for organizational-form changes. Increasing profits without commen- surate employment growth is consistent with the recent pattern of “scale without mass” observed in large public firms (Brynjolfsson et al. 2008; Autor et al. 2017). Figure X, Panel C uses equation (3) to divide the total growth in top entrepreneurial income into contributions from growth in value added per worker, in the entrepreneurial income share of value added, and in total employment adjusted for organizational- form changes. We measure these changes as the growth from the level in 2001 to the level in 2014. Because there was a recession in 2001 and not in 2014, we also show the growth from the level in 2004. For top 1% pass-throughs, value added per worker, employ- ment, and the owner share increased by 25.3%, −9.7%, and 24.5%, respectively, from 2001 to 2014, after adjusting this employ- ment growth for organizational-form changes.59 Thus, 63% of the 25.3% growth in top 1% entrepreneurial income (equal to 25.3%−9.7%+24.5% ) comes from rising labor productivity, −24% comes from lower employment, and the remaining 61% comes from a growing owner share of value added. Overall growth for top 0.1% firms was larger, though the relative contributions from productivity and entrepreneurial income are similar.60 Using 2004 as the

59. The unadjusted employment growth is 23.1%. 60. Specifically, 61% of the overall top 0.1% pay growth comes from rising labor productivity, −16% comes from lower employment, and 56% comes from owner share growth. 66 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 reference year modestly increases the importance of labor pro- ductivity growth, but the results are similar. Figure X, Panel D shows that the share of value added going to nonowner workers fell substantially among top-owned pass- throughs from 2001 to 2014. Over this period, the owner share increased from 37% to 48% of value added for top 1% firms and from 40% to 52% for top 0.1% firms. The figure also shows how the composition of entrepreneurial income evolved over this time period, with owners paying themselves less in wages and more in profits. The share of value added going to owners in the form of wages fell by 1.9 percentage points for top-owned firms. Thus, interpreting the fall of wage income in value added as reflecting income lost by workers would overstate the decline in the labor share; some of the fall reflects the rise of recharacterized owner wages. Overall, growth in entrepreneurial income is explained by both rising labor productivity and a rising share of value added accruing to owners. In contrast, after accounting for the growth due to organizational-form changes, rising firm scale in the form of employment plays no role in the growth of top entrepreneurial income. Economic explanations that emphasize growing the pie, rather than zero-sum bargaining over its distribution, are neces- sary to fit the facts. Yet such explanations would be incomplete without rationalizing how, as labor productivity grows, owner- managers appear to capture an increasing share.

VII. CONCLUSION We have used deidentified U.S. tax records, including novel linked firm-owner-worker data, to investigate the importance of human capital at the top of the U.S. income distribution. The data reveal a striking world of business owners who prevail at the top of the income distribution. We find that most private business profits reflect the return to owner human capital. Overall, top earners are predominantly human-capital rich, and the majority of top income accrues to the human capital of wage earners and entrepreneurs, not financial capital. We highlight three directions for future research. First, the presence and growth of recharacterized labor income mechani- cally reduces the measured labor share in the U.S. corporate sec- tor. More broadly, economic measurement of labor and capital income depends on the incentives and reporting structure of the CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 67 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 tax system. Future research on top inequality should continue to engage with the role of entrepreneurial income amid a real-world environment of changing tax policy, including by investigating the human capital component of other forms of capital income such as C-corporation income and rental income. To the extent that labor income is characterized as capital income, there may be a rationale for aligning capital and labor income tax rates (Piketty and Saez 2013). Second, linking C-corporations to their owners would improve measurement of top income and wealth inequality. The Online Appendix explores various methods of allocating C-corporation retained earnings, which can be used to improve corporate wealth estimates in the absence of direct ownership data. Linking un- reported profits from unincorporated businesses to their owners would also improve measurement. Top wealth estimates based on capitalized income flows and a constant returns assumption can be improved by accounting for the higher profitability of top-owned firms. Third, much rising top income inequality remains consistent with rising private returns to top human capital, but we stress that our findings are silent on the social value of those returns. For example, private returns to owner-manager factors can exceed social returns because of rent seeking, elite connections, and un- equal access to the opportunity to enter certain professions, indus- tries, or markets. Normative conclusions about the social value of top human capital therefore require data and assumptions beyond the scope of this article. Future research should investigate the link between private and social returns, an important next step in explaining their evolution and assessing policy implications.

U.S. T REASURY DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA,BERKELEY, AND NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH PRINCETON UNIVERSITY AND NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO BOOTH SCHOOL OF BUSINESS AND NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL An Online Appendix for this article can be found at The Quar- terly Journal of Economics online. Code replicating tables and 68 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 figures in this article can be found in Smith et al. (2019),inthe Harvard Dataverse, doi:10.7910/DVN/1GIPCL.

REFERENCES Abowd, John, Francis Kramarz, and David Margolis, “High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms,” Econometrica, 67 (1999), 251–333. Alstadsaeter, Annette, Martin Jacob, Wojciech Kopczuk, and Kjetil Telle, “Account- ing for Business Income in Measuring Top Income Shares: Integrated Accrual Approach Using Individual and Firm Data from Norway,” NBER Working Paper no. 22888, 2016. Atkinson, Anthony Barnes, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “The Design of Tax Structure: Direct versus Indirect Taxation,” Journal of Public Economics, 6 (1976), 55– 75. Auten, Gerald, and David Splinter, “Using Tax Data to Measure Long-Term Trends in U.S. Income Inequality,” Treasury Office of Tax Analysis Working Paper, 2018. Autor, David, David Dorn, Lawrence F. Katz, Christina Patterson, and John Van Reenen, “The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms,” NBER Working Paper no. 23396, 2017. Autor, David H., Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney, “Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists,” Review of Economics and Statistics,90 (2008), 300–323. Bakija, Jon, Adam Cole, and Bradley T. Heim, “Jobs and Income Growth of Top Earners and the Causes of Changing Income Inequality: Evidence from U.S. Tax Return Data,” Williams College Working Paper, 2012. Becker, Sascha, and Hans Hvide, “Do Entrepreneurs Matter?” IZA Working Paper, 2017. Bennedsen, Morten, Kasper Meisner Nielsen, Francisco Perez-Gonz´ alez,´ and Daniel Wolfenzon, “Inside the Family Firm: The Role of Families in Succes- sion Decisions and Performance,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (2007), 647–691. Bennedsen, Morten, Francisco Perez-Gonz´ alez,´ and Daniel Wolfenzon, “Do CEOs Matter: Evidence from Hospitalization Events,” Journal of Finance, (forth- coming). Bhandari, Anmol, and Ellen R. McGrattan, “Sweat Equity in U.S. Private Busi- ness,” NBER Working Paper no. 24520, 2018. Bricker, Jesse, Alice Henriques, Jacob Krimmel, and John Sabelhaus, “Measur- ing Income and Wealth at the Top Using Administrative and Survey Data,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2016 (2016), 261–331. Brynjolfsson, Erik, Andrew McAfee, Michael Sorell, and Feng Zhu, “Scale without Mass: Business Process Replication and Industry Dynamics,” HBS Working Paper 07-016, 2008. Caballero, Ricardo J., Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, “Rents, Technical Change, and Risk Premia Accounting for Secular Trends in Interest Rates, Returns on Capital, Earning Yields, and Factor Shares,” American Economic Review, 107 (2017), 614–620. Card, David, Jorg¨ Heining, and Patrick Kline, “Workplace Heterogeneity and the Rise of West German Wage Inequality,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128 (2013), 967–1015. Chamley, Christophe, “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilib- rium with Infinite Lives,” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 54 (1986), 607–622. Chetty, Raj, John N. Friedman, Emmanuel Saez, Nicholas Turner, and Danny Yagan, “Income Segregation and Intergenerational Mobility across Colleges in the United States,” NBER Working Paper no. 23618, 2019. CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 69 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline, and Emmanuel Saez, “Where Is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational Mobility in the United States,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129 (2014), 1553–1623. Chetty, Raj, and Emmanuel Saez, “Dividend Taxes and Corporate Behavior: Evi- dence from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120 (2005), 791. Clarke, Conor, and Wojciech Kopczuk, “Business Income and Business Taxation in the United States since the 1950s,” Tax Policy and the Economy, 31 (2017), 121–159. Cooper, Michael, John McClelland, James Pearce, Richard Prisinzano, Joseph Sullivan, Danny Yagan, Owen Zidar, and Eric Zwick, “Business in the United States: Who Owns It, and How Much Tax Do They Pay?,” TaxPolicyandthe Economy, 30 (2016), 91–128. De Loecker, Jan, and Jan Eeckhout, “The Rise of Market Power and the Macroe- conomic Implications,” NBER Working Paper no. 22822, 2017. DeBacker, Jason M., and Richard Prisinzano, “The Rise of Partnerships,” Tax Notes, 147 (2015), 1563–1575. Dyrda, Sebastian, and Benjamin Pugsley, “Taxes, Regulations of Businesses and Evolution of Income Inequality in the US,” University of Toronto Working Paper, 2018. Edmans, Alex, and Xavier Gabaix, “Executive Compensation: A Modern Primer,” Journal of Economic Literature, 54 (2016), 1232–1287. Fagereng, Andreas, Luigi Guiso, Davide Malacrino, and Luigi Pistaferri, “Het- erogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth,” NBER Working Paper no. 22822, 2016. Fisman, Raymond, “Estimating the Value of Political Connections,” American Eco- nomic Review, 91 (2001), 1095–1102. Foster, Lucia, John Haltiwanger, and Chad Syverson, “Reallocation, Firm Turnover, and Efficiency: Selection on Productivity or Profitability?,” Amer- ican Economic Review, 98 (2008), 394–425. Gabaix, Xavier, and Augustin Landier, “Why Has CEO Pay Increased So Much?,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123 (2008), 49–100. Goldin, Claudia Dale, and Lawrence F. Katz, The Race between Education and Technology (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2009). Gordon, Roger, and Joel Slemrod, “Are ‘Real’ Responses to Taxes Simply Income Shifting between Corporate and Personal Tax Bases,” in Does Atlas Shrug? The Economic Consequences of Taxing the Rich, Joel Slemrod, ed. (Cambridge, MA: Russell Sage Foundation Books at Harvard University Press, 2000), 240– 288. Gordon, Roger H., and Jeffrey K. MacKie-Mason, “Tax Distortions to the Choice of Organizational Form,” Journal of Public Economics, 55 (1994), 279–306. Hall, Robert E., “The Relation between Price and Marginal Cost in US Industry,” Journal of Political Economy, 96 (1988), 921–947. Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter Klenow, “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124 (2009), 1403–1448. Jager,¨ Simon, “How Substitutable Are Workers? Evidence from Worker Deaths,” MIT Working Paper, 2016. Jaravel, Xavier, Neviana Petkova, and Alex Bell, “Team-Specific Capital and In- novation,” American Economic Review, 108 (2018), 1034–1073. Johnson, W. Bruce, Robert P. Magee, Nandu J. Nagarajan, and Harry A. New- man, “An Analysis of the Stock Price Reaction to Sudden Executive Deaths: Implications for the Managerial Labor Market,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7 (1985), 151–174. Judd, Kenneth L., “Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model,” Journal of Public Economics, 28 (1985), 59–83. Kaplan, Steven N., and Joshua Rauh, “It’s the Market: The Broad-Based Rise in theReturntoTopTalent,”Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27 (2013), 35–55. Karabarbounis, Loukas, and Brent Neiman, “The Global Decline of the Labor Share,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129 (2014), 61–103. 70 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Katz, Lawrence F., and Kevin M. Murphy, “Changes in Relative Wages, 1963– 1987: Factors,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107 (1992), 35–78. Khwaja, Asim Ijaz, and Atif Mian, “Do Lenders Favor Politically Connected Firms? Rent Provision in an Emerging ,” Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics, 120 (2005), 1371–1411. Kopczuk, Wojciech, and Emmanuel Saez, “Top Wealth Shares in the United States, 1916–2000: Evidence From Estate Tax Returns,” National Tax Journal,57 (2004), 445–487. Kotlikoff, Laurence J., and Lawrence H. Summers, “The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital Accumulation,” Journal of Political Economy, 89 (1981), 706–732. Krueger, Anne O., “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review, 64 (1974), 291–303. Kuziemko, Ilyana, Michael I. Norton, Emmanuel Saez, and Stefanie Stantcheva, “How Elastic Are Preferences for Redistribution? Evidence from Randomized Survey Experiments,” American Economic Review, 105 (2015), 1478–1508. MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K., and Roger H. Gordon, “How Much Do Taxes Discourage Incorporation?,” Journal of Finance, 52 (1997), 477–506. Modigliani, Franco, “Life Cycle, Lndividual Thrift, and the Wealth of Nations,” American Economic Review, 76 (1986), 297–313. Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, “The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106 (1991), 503–530. Murphy, Kevin M., and Robert H. Topel, “Human Capital Investment, Inequality, and Economic Growth,” Journal of Labor Economics, 34 (2016), S99–S127. Perez-Gonz´ alez,´ Francisco, “Inherited Control and Firm Performance,” American Economic Review, 96 (2006), 1559–1588. Piketty, Thomas, “On the Long-Run Evolution of Inheritance: France 1820–2050,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126 (2011), 1071–1131. ———, Capital in the 21st Century (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2014). Piketty, Thomas, Gilles Postel-Vinay, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, “Inherited vs Self-Made Wealth: Theory & Evidence from a Rentier Society (Paris 1872– 1927),” Explorations in Economic History, 51 (2014), 21–40. Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez, “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (2003), 1–41. ———, “Optimal Labor Income Taxation,” in Handbook of Public Economics, vol. 5, (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2013), 391–474. Piketty, Thomas, Emmanuel Saez, and Stefanie Stantcheva, “Optimal Taxation of Top Labor Incomes: A Tale of Three Elasticities,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6 (2014), 230–271. Piketty, Thomas, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman, “Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Estimates for The United States,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133 (2018), 553–609. Piketty, Thomas, and Gabriel Zucman, “Capital Is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries, 1700–2010,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129 (2014), 1255–1310. Prisinzano, Richard, and James Pearce, “Tax Based Switching of Business Income,” 2017, U.S. Department of Treasury Working Paper. Rognlie, Matthew, “Deciphering the Fall and Rise in the Net Capital Share: Accu- mulation or Scarcity?,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2016 (2016), 1–69. Saez, Emmanuel, and Gabriel Zucman, “Wealth Inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence from Capitalized Income Tax Data,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131 (2016), 519–578. Slemrod, Joel, “High Income Families and the Tax Changes of the 1980s: The Anatomy of Behavioral Response,” in Empirical Foundations of Household CAPITALISTS IN THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 71 Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/qje/advance-article-abstract/doi/10.1093/qje/qjz020/5542244 by guest on 09 September 2019 Taxation, Martin Feldstein and James M. Poterba, eds. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996), 169–192. Smith, Matthew, Danny Yagan, Owen Zidar, and Eric Zwick, “Replication Data for: ‘Capitalists in the Twenty-First Century’,” 2019, Harvard Dataverse, doi:10.7910/DVN/1GIPCL. Song, Jae, David Price, Fatih Guvenen, Nicholas Bloom, and Till von Wachter, “Firming Up Inequality,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134 (2019), 1–50. Syverson, Chad, “What Determines Productivity?,” Journal of Economic Litera- ture, 49 (2011), 326–365. Yagan, Danny, “Capital Tax Reform and the Real Economy: The Effects of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut,” American Economic Review, 105 (2015), 3531–3563. Zimmerman, Seth D., “Elite Colleges and Upward Mobility to Top Jobs and Top Incomes,” American Economic Review, 109 (2019), 1–47. Zwick, Eric, and James Mahon, “Tax Policy and Heterogeneous Investment Behavior,” American Economic Review, 107 (2017), 217–248. For Online Publication

This appendix supplements our paper “Capitalists in the Twenty-First Century” with the following sections:

Section A provides institutional detail. • Section B details variable definitions and additional data construction steps. • Section C uses the Piketty, Saez and Zucman (2018) (henceforth PSZ) published ap- • pendix to illustrate that pass-through income is large in top imputed national income.

Section D explains our replacement of PSZ’s extrapolated wealth data 2011–2014 with • actual aggregate wealth estimates, which a↵ects the composition of top equity incomes in imputed national income.

Section E documents that realized capital gains often do not reflect C-corporation • income and that using 100% of realized capital gains to impute retained earnings may allocate too much retained earnings to top earners.

Section F studies the relative importance of pass-through and C-corporation income • under di↵erent assumptions for imputing C-corporation retained earnings. This section explains and replicates the imputed national income estimates for business income in PSZ. It then quantifies the level and growth of top 1% retained earnings under alternative scenarios.

Section G discusses other types of capital income in imputed national income that do • not appear in fiscal income.

Section H contains supplemental robustness analyses. • Section I contains appendix figures. • Section J contains appendix tables. •

60 A Detail on How U.S. Businesses Are Organized and Taxed

A.1 Detail on how U.S. Businesses Are Organized and Taxed

This subsection provides additional detail on sole proprietorships, the tax treatment of dif- ferent business entities and types of compensation, and more background on policy changes.

Sole proprietorships There are other types of businesses besides C-corporations, S- corporations, and partnerships.61 For example, sole proprietorships (e.g., self-employed house cleaning enterprises) are unincorporated business entities owned by individual tax- payers. Their annual income is taxed at ordinary personal income tax rates at the owner level on Form 1040, Schedule C. Sole proprietors lack limited liability and sole proprietorship dividends are not taxed.62

Tax Treatment by Corporate Form We describe the tax treatment as of 2014, which is the most recent year for which tax data are available. Considering only federal taxes for simplicity, C-corporations pay the corporate income tax, which is a nearly flat 35% rate on their annual taxable income, and their owners are liable for the dividend income tax or (23.8% in the top personal bracket, which includes the 2013 A↵ordable Care Act (ACA) surtax of 3.8% on investment income) on the remaining 65% of income when it is distributed to owners. These taxes amount to an estimated all-in top tax rate on C-corporations of 44.7%.63 Partnerships typically enjoy lower taxes than identical C-corporations: annual partnership income is taxed at the owner level at ordinary income tax rates and self-employment tax rates (totaling 43.4% at the top),

61Other entity types include regulated investment companies (RICs), real estate investment trusts (REITs), real estate mortgage investment conduits (REMICs), and disregarded entities. 62Note that, as pointed out by Thomas Brennan, one can use an LLC and check the box to treat sole- proprietorships as a disregarded entity. We thank him for his close reading of the institutional detail section and many helpful comments. 63Economists typically assume that half of distributions face the statutory dividend tax rate while the other half is taxed at one quarter of the capital gains tax rate due to tax deferral from retained earnings and other avoidance. The estimate 44.7% equals 35% + 65% (.5 23.8% + .5 1 23.8%). ⇥ ⇥ ⇥ 4 ⇥

61 with no other income taxes or taxes on distributions.64 S-corporations usually face the weakly lowest taxes. S-corporation income is taxed iden- tically to partnership income, except that if the owner “materially participates” in the firm’s operation, the income is classified as active (“non-passive”) income and faces only the ordi- nary income tax (39.6% at the top).65 Owners determine their material participation status, which typically requires the owner to supply at least 500 hours of labor to the firm in the year the income was earned. Owners face tax incentives to classify themselves as material participants in order for their income to be deemed active and face lower taxes.66 Note that whereas a partnership owner typically faces identical taxes when receiving her income as W-2 wage income and business income, an S-corporation owner faces lower taxes when receiving her income as business income.

Policy Changes Historically, U.S. business activity was largely organized in one of two forms: sole proprietorships (accounting for 25% of 1985 taxable business income) or C- corporations (accounting for 75%) (Cooper, McClelland, Pearce, Prisinzano, Sullivan, Yagan, Zidar and Zwick, 2016; Clarke and Kopczuk, 2017). The Tax Reform Act of 1986 lowered the top individual tax rate below the rate and raised relative tax burdens on C-corporations. These rate and base changes resulted in the steady growth of the pass-through sector. There are other policy changes the a↵ected S-corporations and other pass-throughs.67 In 1993, the cap on wage taxes for Medicare was removed, which provided additional incentive to receive compensation in the

64This tax treatment applies to general partners. Limited partners are exempt from self-employment taxes but are subject to the Net Investment Income Tax, which also yields a top rate of 43.4%. Limited partners can sometimes be classified as non-passive and therefore taxed at 39.6% at the top, like non-passive S-corporation owners. However, owner-managers typically must be classified as general partners. 65Passive S-corporation owners are subject to the Net Investment Income Tax, which yields a top rate of 43.4%. 66An S-corporation owner-manager’s W-2 compensation is required to be “reasonable” and to reflect the market-value of labor services. The IRS rarely adjusts tax liabilities by deeming W-2 compensation to be unreasonable. Before the Net Investment Income Tax of 2013 that assessed a surtax on passive but not active S-corporation income, the incentive to declare one’s S-corporation income as active rather than passive was limited to deducting active losses from one’s other active income like wage and salary income. Auten, Splinter and Nelson (2016) document shifting of passive to active S-corporation income in response to the 2013 change. 67We thank Thomas Brennan for pointing out many of these changes, some of which we hadn’t highlighted in the previous version of the draft. Nelson (2016) provides a detailed account of how rules governing S- corporations have evolved over time and have generally made adopting this form more favorable.

62 form of S-corporation profit as S-corporation profits do not face the 2.9% Medicare tax. From 2001 to 2003, the top rate on personal income declined from 39.6% to 35%, which increased the relative attractiveness of pass-through corporate forms. However, over that same period, the dividend tax rate was cut from 39.6% to 15%, increasing the relative attractiveness of C- corporations. In 2004, the AJCA relaxed S-corporation rules in the following ways: up to 100 owners were allowed, “families” count as one owner, ESOP restrictions were relaxed, bank S-corporations were allowed, and IRA ownership of bank S-corporations were allowed. From 2009-2015, there were reductions in the holding period required for built-in-gains. Finally, as mentioned above, the introduction of ACA taxes in 2013 includes an e↵ective 3.8% tax on wages and dividends, but active S-corporation income does not face this additional 3.8% tax.

63 B Data Appendix

Variable Definitions

This appendix subsection defines variables in the linked firm-owner-worker data, introduced in Section 1.3. All variables are annual and are available in all years. Year refers to calendar year, which by law is also each S-corporation’s and partnership’s fiscal year. All dollar values are inflated to 2014 dollars. Deflators were calculated using price data from the BEA Table 1.1.4 (“Price Indexes for Gross Domestic Product”).

1. Firm-level. A firm is an S-corporation or partnership. Sales is the firm’s operating revenue (gross sales minus returns) as listed on the 1120S or 1065. For example, see Form 1120S line 1a-1b. Passively earned income (e.g., interest on bank deposits) is excluded. Profits is the firm’s ordinary business income, equal to operating revenue minus costs as listed on the 1120S or 1065. Costs equals the sum of inputs (cost of goods sold), employee and owner wage compensation, rent, interest, capital asset tax depreciation, and other de- ductions related to ordinary business. Profits are divided among owners (pro rata according to ownership stakes at S-corporations) on Forms K-1, which owners then include on their Form 1040, Schedule E. Hence, except for Form 1040 loss limitations, profits are exactly the S-corporation and partnership income concept that appears as pass-through income on personal income tax returns. Profits per worker equals profits divided by the number of workers. Number of workers and number of employees equals the number of individuals who received a W-2 from the firm that year. Industry is the four-digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) code reported by the firm on its 1120S or 1065 as corresponding to its principal business activity. A firm is a top-owned firm if it has an owner in the top 1% or top 0.1% of the income distribution. Million-dollar owners are with over one million dollars in income.

2. Owner-level. Afirmownerisatop 1% owner,atop 1-0.1% owner,oratop 0.1% owner if her tax unit’s fiscal income lies in a year’s top 1%, the top 1% but not the top 0.1%, or the top 0.1% of all tax units in the year, respectively. She is a million-dollar earner

64 if her tax unit’s fiscal income exceeds one million dollars. Pass-through income equals the owner’s share of the profits from the pass-through. Owner wages equals W-2 payments from the pass-through, as reflected in merged W-2 records. Entrepreneurial income equals pass- through income plus owner wages. An owner’s pass-through income is reported as active if the owner reports any of her pass-through income in the personal income tax return boxes indicating material participation (typically at least 500 hours over the calendar year) in the operations of any of her pass-throughs and is reported as passive otherwise. Owners face tax incentives to classify themselves to classify themselves as material participants in order for their income to be deemed active and face lower taxes.68

Imputations for Owner Wages

Before merging owner wages from our linked-firm-owner data to our top incomes data, we impute owner wages to some rows. As explained in Section 1.3, some firms pay W-2 wages but cannot be linked to any W-2s. We start by dividing all individuals in the linked-firm-owner- worker data into two groups: candidates for imputation and non-candidates for imputation. We define candidates for imputation as all owners of firms that (a) deducted salaries-and- wages, ocer compensation, or guaranteed payments to partners from their pass-through tax returns and (b) were not linked to any W-2s. All other individuals are non-candidates for imputation. For every non-candidate, we compute the owner-wages share of the owner’s total wages.69 Many non-candidate observations have owner-wages share of 0. We then impute owner wages to candidates for imputation as follows. We group all firm-owner observations into bins defined by year, organizational form (S-corporation or partnership), type and number of owners (passive, active and the firm has only 1 owner, active and the firm has 2 owners, active and the firm has 3-4 owners, or active and the firm has

68Before the Net Investment Income Tax of 2013 that assessed a surtax on passive but not active S- corporation income, the incentive to declare one’s S-corporation income as active rather than passive was limited to deducting active losses from one’s other active income like wage and salary income. After the NIIT, active S-corporation income enjoyed lower taxes than passive S-corporation income; the same distinction was not applied to partnership income. Auten, Splinter and Nelson (2016) document shifting of passive to active S-corporation income in response to the 2013 change. 69An owner who received wages only from a firm she owns has an owner-wages share of 1. An owner who received no owner wages has an owner-wages share of 0. An owner who received owner wages and wages from another firm has an owner-wages share (0, 1). 2

65 5ormoreowners),andfirmsalesbin($0-100K,$100-500K,$500K-1M,$1M-5M,$5M-50M, and $50M+). Then for every candidate observation, we find the non-candidate observation within the same group that has the closest total owner wages and impute owner wages equal to the product of the non-candidate’s owner-wages share and the candidate’s total wages.70 This procedure ensures that the distribution of imputed owner wages exactly replicates the distribution of directly observed owner wages, including numerous zeros. Finally, we merge owner wages from the linked data to the top incomes data by owner-masked SSN. If an individual in the top incomes data does not match to the linked data, she is assigned owner wages of zero.

Imputations for Private C-Corporation Wages

Our second robustness analysis of Section H.2 required us to identify 2014 top earners whose highest-paying W-2 was issued by a private C-corporation. We identify them in five steps. First, we compile a list of the universe of 2014 businesses, including C-corporations, S- corporations, partnerships, and non-profits. Second, we define private C-corporations as all C-corporations whose EINs do not appear in Compustat. Third, we merge our universe of businesses to our top incomes data by the EIN on individuals’ highest-paying W-2 and thereby classify 8.1% of top 1% individuals (by imputed national income) as being paid wages by a private C-corporation. At this point in the procedure, a substantial share of individuals with a W-2 are “ghost payees”: they were not matched to any business in step 3, either because they were gov- ernment employees (and thus were correctly unmatched to a business) or because their non-government employer issued W-2s under a di↵erent EIN from the one under which it paid taxes (and thus were erroneously unmatched to a business). Similarly, many private C-corporations are “ghost payers”: they deducted wages and salaries or ocer compensation on their tax returns but matched to no W-2 in the universe of W-2s, suggesting that they issued W-2s under a di↵erent EIN from the one under which it paid taxes. There are thus

70Consider an example. Suppose that in 2014, Jane Doe had $100,000 in total wages and was an owner of the S-Corporation Acme Inc. Acme deducted ocer compensation but was linked to no W-2s. Suppose that the nearest non-candidate owner in Jane’s group had $100,002 in total wages, $50,001 of which came from the S-corporation. Then we would impute $50,000 of owner wages to Jane.

66 likely missing matches between private C-corporations and our top incomes data. In our fourth step, we impute those missing matches by assuming that—within size bins—the match rate between ghost payers and ghost payees is the same as between directly observed private C-corporations and eligible top earners, in the third step above. Specifically, we divide top-earning individuals into three income bins based on imputed national income: those in the top 1% but with less imputed national income than $1M, those with greater than $1M but not in the top 0.1%, and those in the top 0.1%. We divide all private C- corporations into five firm size bins based on the sum of their deducted wages and salaries and ocer compensation: $0, ($0,$100K], ($100K,$1M], ($1M,$10M], and $10M+. Within each income bin b,wecomputetheweightednumbermatchedbf of individuals who matched to a private C-corporation by firm size bin f.Wethenimputeprivate-C-corporation-payer

0 classification to the weighted number matchedb of ghost payees in each income bin b:

NumGhostP ayers 0 f matchedb = matchedbf , (4) ⇥ NumNonghostP ayersf Xf where NumGhostP ayersf is the number of private C-corporations in size bin f and

NumNonghostP ayersf is the number of all other private C-corporations in size bin f.We therefore classifiy a large number of ghost payees as having a private C-corporation payer to the extent that a large number of similar-earning individuals were matched directly to a private C-corporation payer and that a large number of private C-corporations were ghost payers. This imputation step classifies an additional 4.9% of top-1% individuals as having a private C-corporation payer. In our fifth step, we conservatively classify all of an individual’s wages as capital income if and only if she is classified as having a private C-corporation payer in step 3 or 4 above.

67 C Pass-Through Income in Imputed National Income

Pass-through income constitutes one-third (32.5%) of top 1% imputed national income (Fig- ures 1C and 8B). PSZ’s Online Appendix Section C.2 focuses on S-corporation income in discussing an earlier draft of our paper and indicates that S-corporation income is a small share of top imputed national income. This appendix uses PSZ’s published appendix to reconcile these two facts and show that pass-through income is indeed large in top imputed national income. Like the current version of our paper, the first version studied all pass-through income. However, for data reasons, the first version focused much of the empirical analysis on S- corporation income. PSZ plot the share of top 1% income over time earned in the form of S- corporation income, non-S-corporation labor income, and non-S-corporation capital income. Figure I.14A replicates Appendix Figure S.34 from PSZ using data from the supplementary spreadsheet.71 PSZ conclude that S-corporation income is minor. PSZ do not include partnership or other non-S-corporation pass-through income in their discussion, instead focusing only on S-corporation income. PSZ also divide non-S-corporation pass-through income into 65% labor income and 35% capital income. Including all compo- nents of pass-through income reveals the large and growing importance of pass-through income for top incomes for two reasons. First, because other components of top labor and capital income have been shrinking over time, the importance of partnerships is muted in PSZ’s composite labor and capital income series. Second, fiscal partnership income accounts for 46% of pass-through business income at the top in imputed national income. Our paper’s focus on private pass-through business income includes both S-corporations and partnerships. Figure I.14B uses PSZ’s supplementary spreadsheet to modify Figure I.14A by applying shading to the components of labor and capital income that reflect allocations from non-S- corporation pass-through income (“mixed income”).72 Figure I.14C applies the same shading to all pass-through income. Including partnership and other mixed income makes clear the importance of pass-

71Sheet TB2f in http://gabriel-zucman.eu/files/PSZ2017AppendixTablesII(Distrib).xlsx. 72In defining mixed income, the supplementary spreadsheet does not separately break out sole proprietor’s income and unreported non-corporate-business income from partnership income. This section therefore does not attempt to decompose mixed income further.

68 through income in imputed national income. Pass-through income has grown dramatically since the 1980s. Pass-through income was less than half the size of other capital income in the 1960s and rose to surpass other capital income briefly in the 2000s. In 2014, one-third of top 1% imputed national income is pass-through income, with the rest split nearly evenly between non-pass-through labor and non-pass-through capital income. In imputed national income, pass-through income has been secularly rising since 1990, while retained earnings steadily declined from the 1960s and then recovered somewhat since 2000. C-corporation income was much more important for top incomes in the 1960s and 1970s, prior to the 1986 tax reform, than in recent decades. In 2014, pass-through income in imputed national income is much larger than C-corporation income, including imputed retained earnings.

69 D Imputed National Income Data Update

For their analysis of the composition of top 1% incomes (Online Appendix Section C.2 and Sheet TB2f), PSZ use actual aggregate S-corporation and C-corportion wealth estimates from the US Financial Accounts for the years prior to 2011. For 2011–2014, PSZ extrapolate top 1% S-corporation and C-corporation wealth: they start with the 2010 values and then grow them using the growth rate of aggregate household equity wealth. We update this series to reflect actual aggregate wealth estimates. This update does not a↵ect an individual’s total income; it alters the allocation of that income among sources. See Appendix F for the formulas we use to replicate estimates in PSZ with unextrapolated data. Figure I.15 presents results of this update. The updated Financial Accounts wealth estimates increase aggregrate S-corporation wealth and reduce aggregate household C- corporation weath. Accordingly, imputed S-corporation income rises by approximately 21%, or $47B, and the sum of C-corporation dividends and retained earnings falls by this amount. Figures I.16A-B show the e↵ect of this update on relative contributions of S-corporation and C-corporation income to top 1% business income growth. The graph also includes partnership income (first two bars) and other non-S-corporation pass-through income (third bar) to study the evolution of all business income. Figure I.16A focuses on the period from 1990 to 2014 to study the full time series after TRA86 (including transition years). Figure I.16B focuses on the period from 2000 to 2014 (as emphasized by PSZ). For each scenario, we compute the contribution of business income to top 1% income growth (e.g., business income increased by 2.8% of national income from 1990 to 2014) and divide this amount into contributions from each source (e.g., S-corporation income increased by 1.1% of national income from 1990 to 2014, or 40% of the business income increase). For the time period 2000–2014, the original PSZ series shows S-corporation income con- tributed 6% to business income growth. Using updated unextrapolated data increases this contribution to 19%. The update increases the total pass-through contribution from 25% to 38% of the growth in total business income over this time. The contribution of C-corporation income contracts symmetrically: in the original PSZ series, C-corporation income contributed 74% to total business income growth; in unextrapolated data, the contribution falls to 61%.

70 Going back to 1990, the updated series shows a relative contribution of 60% to 63% for pass- through income, up from 51% in the original PSZ series, and 37% to 40% for C-corporation income including retained earnings, down from 49%. Thus, pass-through income is a major contributor to business income growth in the updated data.

71 E Imputing Retained Earnings with Realized Capital Gains

The retained earnings of C-corporations is an important component of national income that does not appear in fiscal income. In creating the imputed national income series, PSZ impute retained earnings to individuals based on inferred C-corporation stock that is directly held.73 Their approach infers aggregate C-corporation ownership using the sum of taxable dividends and 100% of realized capital gains, because C-corporation income can appear on individual tax returns in either form. Dividends always reflect C-corporation income. This appendix documents that realized capital gains often do not and illustrates the implications for imputing top incomes. Specif- ically, because realized capital gains are much larger and more concentrated among top 1% earners than dividends, using 100% of realized capital gains to impute retained earnings may allocate too much retained earnings to top 1% earners. Figure I.17A uses public aggregates from the IRS Statistics of Income for realized capital gains, broken down by asset class.74 Alargeshareofrealizedcapitalgainsarenotduetothe sale of corporate stock. In recent years, the share of net gains attributed to stock sales and mutual funds, most of which is C-corporation stock, is approximately 25%. Another 25% includes directly owned non-C-corporate-stock asset sales, such as real estate and financial securities. The remaining 50% of gains are in the form of pass-through gains, which includes indirectly owned C-corporate stock but also includes indirect ownership of other assets and recharacterized labor income in the form of carried interest for hedge fund and private equity managers. If anything, the importance of C-corporation stock has fallen over time following the boom in the late 1990s. Hence, 25% to 75% of realized capital gains reflects the sale of C-corporate stock. Figure I.17B plots macroeconomic retained earnings, the household sector’s share of macroeconomic retained earnings, and total fiscal realized capital gains over 1962–2014 (all in 2014 dollars).

73The share of C-corporation stock held by pensions and non-profits is imputed to the pension sector and allocated separately as pension income. When PSZ emphasize the importance of retained earnings for top 1% incomes, they refer to the directly held component and not the pension component. 74See https://www.irs.gov/statistics/soi-tax-stats-sales-of-capital-assets-reported-on-individual-tax-returns for the data.

72 The broad nature of realized capital gains can explain why total realized capital gains of $732B in 2014 vastly exceeds the total household share of retained earnings ($306B). In 2014, total realized capital gains even exceeds the overall macroeconomic flow of retained earnings ($649B). Figure I.17B shows these facts are true in most years between 1962 and 2014. The gap between realized capital gains and the household share of retained earnings widened from the 1980s through the 2000s, suggesting over-allocation of retained earnings to top 1% earners may be increasing over time. These patterns materially a↵ect top retained earnings imputations in 2014. In the fiscal income inputs to PSZ’s imputation, the top 1% receive 74% of the $732B of realized capital gains but only 49% of the $271B of C-corporation dividends. Thus, the top 1% share of

$132B+$539B allocated retained earnings in imputed national income is 67% = $271B+$732B when using PSZ’s 100% assumption. If we instead use 25% of realized capital gains combined with C- corporation dividends when allocating C-corporation retained earnings, the top 1% share of

$132B+0.25 $539B allocated retained earnings is 59% = $271B+0.25·$732B . Hence, imputed national income may · allocate too much retained earnings to top 1% earners and not enough to lower earners.

73 F Imputing Retained Earnings under Alternative As- sumptions

This appendix studies the relative importance of pass-through and C-corporation income under di↵erent assumptions for imputing C-corporation retained earnings. Section F.1 ex- plains our successful replication of the imputed national income estimates in PSZ. Section F.2 studies the robustness of results to the weight placed on realized capital gains when imputing retained earnings. Section F.3 quantifies the level of top 1% retained earnings in 2014 under alternative scenarios. Section F.4 quantifies the growth of top 1% retained earnings since 1990 and 2000 under alternative scenarios and compares that growth to other components of business income.

F.1 Replicating the INI Retained Earnings Imputation

Overview of calculation. The imputed national income (INI) approach in PSZ uses fiscal income data to build allocation factors and apply these factors to produce a “top down” imputation of all components of national income, which by construction sum to total national income. For equity income, this procedure allocates to di↵erent people the aggregate flow of S-corporation income, C-corporation dividends, C-corporation retained earnings, and corporate taxes, which equals $2.15T in aggregate in 2014. The final result is a pretax division of this aggregate flow between S-corporation income, C-corporation dividends, and C-corporation retained earnings. This section replicates PSZ’s INI estimates, carefully following the computations in their analysis spreadsheets and replication code.75

Imputing retained earnings in 2014. The first step is to compute the share of this $2.15T flow that accrues to the top 1%, which equals 34%. This allocation share equals the sum of estimated top 1% S-corporation and C-corporation wealth divided by macro equity wealth in the household, non-profit, and pension sectors. The top 1% S- and C-corporation wealth estimates capitalize fiscal income following the method of Saez and Zucman (2016).

75The final numbers appear in Sheet TB2f, Columns B through M, in http://gabriel-zucman.eu/ files/PSZ2017AppendixTablesII(Distrib).xlsx. Note that we convert shares of income to dollars to make comparison of alternative scenarios more straightforward.

74 In the case of S-corporation wealth, the procedure first allocates macro S- corporation wealth ($2.8T) in proportion to the top 1% share of fiscal S-corporation income (=$229B/$407B=56%). In the case of C-corporation wealth, the proce- dure first allocates macro C-corporation wealth owned by households ($11T) in pro- portion to an individual’s share of taxable dividends and realized capital gains (=($132B+$539B)/($271B+$732B)=67%). These calculations yield $8.9T of top 1% S- plus C-corporation wealth, or 34% of total macro equity wealth ($26.2T). The top 1% flow of equity income is $733B (= $2.15T .34). ⇥ The second step divides the top 1% flow of equity income ($733B) into proportional con- tributions from C-corporation retained earnings, C-corporation dividends, and S-corporation income. As above, each source of equity income uses wealth estimates based on fiscal income to apportion macroeconomic flows. C-corporation retained earnings are defined as macroeconomic retained earnings ($649B) multiplied by top 1% estimated C-corporation wealth ($7.4T) divided by macro C- corporation wealth ($23.4T), yielding $205B. Similar steps yield $177B for C-corporation dividends and $231B for S-corporation dividends. Combining these components yields a retained earnings share of $205B/($205B+$177B+$231B), equal to 33%. The final estimate for retained earnings in the top 1% percent is the product of $733B (the result of the first step) and 33% (the result of the second step), which equals $245B.

General formulas and inputs for top 1% imputed retained earnings. This sub- section describes in more detail the imputed national income mapping from raw inputs to imputed retained earnings, in order to clarify how alternative assumptions a↵ect the proce- dure. This mapping combines data from three sources: fiscal income data, macroeconomic income data from NIPA, and macroeconomic wealth data from the US Financial Accounts. The mapping begins with a top-level number of macroeconomic income from equity to allocate between S-corporations and C-corporations. The formula for S-corp dividends is the product of an allocation factor and total top 1% income from equity (the formulas for C dividends and retained earnings are analogous):

75 top 1% S-corp dividends = S income allocation factor Total top 1% income from equity ⇥ =(top 1% equity wealth) (Aggregate equity yield) ⇥ | {z } (5)

The S-corporation income allocation factor is the proportional contribution of S- corporation income to top 1% pretax equity income. Total top 1% income from equity equals an estimate of top 1% equity wealth multiplied by an aggregate equity yield, which uses only publicly available macro statistics. Following Saez and Zucman (2016), top 1% wealth is a capitalized wealth estimate, derived by multiplying a flow of fiscal income by a capitalization factor combining fiscal income and macroeconomic wealth statistics from the US Financial Accounts. Several inputs are required to compute top 1% equity wealth and the aggregate equity yield. We first substitute data series from fiscal income data and macroeconomic data into equation (5). We then rearrange this formula to isolate factors derived from tax data and those from macroeconomic data:

=Sincomeallocationfactor total S wealth total C household wealth (top 1% S divs) +(top 1% C divs + top 1% cap gains) ⇥ ⇥ total S divs ⇥ total C divs + total cap gains  ✓ ◆ ✓ ◆ household equity wealth FoF (total C,S divs + retained earnings + taxes) household equity wealth FoF+pension equity wealth FoF ⇥ (6) ⇥ 2 total C,S household⇣ wealth ⌘ 3 4 5 =Sincomeallocationfactor top 1% S divs top 1% C divs + top 1% cap gains (total S wealth)+ (total C household wealth) ⇥ total S divs ⇥ total C divs + total cap gains ⇥ ✓ ◆ ✓ ◆ 1 (total C,S divs + retained earnings + taxes) , (7) ⇥ household equity wealth FoF + pension equity wealth FoF ⇥ ✓ ◆ where bold is used to denote tax data and italics denote NIPA and US Financial Accounts data. When neither bold nor italic are used, the item combines both tax and NIPA/Financial Accounts data. Total top 1% equity equals the sum of top 1% S-corporation wealth and top 1% C- corporation wealth. Top 1% S-corporation wealth equals top 1% S-corporation fiscal income

76 times total Financial Accounts S-corporation wealth divided by total S-corporation fiscal income. Similarly, top 1% C-corporation wealth equals the sum of top 1% C-corporation fiscal dividends and top 1% realized capital gains times total C-corporation wealth held by households divided by the sum of total C-corporation fiscal dividends and total realized capital gains. The aggregate equity yield equals the macroeconomic flow of dividends plus retained earnings from C-corporations plus corporate tax payments from NIPA divided by total macroeconomic equity wealth owned by households, non-profits, and pensions. The S-corporation income allocation factor equals a/(a + b + c), where a is the S- corporation allocation component, b is the C-corporation dividends allocation component, and c is the C-corporation retained earnings component. These allocation components are similar to the overall formula for S-corporation and C-corporation income, except they allo- cate a pre-tax macroeconomic income flow across the income distribution. Each allocation component is defined as an estimate of top 1% wealth in either S-corporation or C-corporation form multiplied by a macroeconomic yield on total S-corporation or C-corporation wealth. In the case of S-corporations, because all wealth is held by households, the formula simplifies to allocating macroeconomic S-corporation dividends (which may di↵er slightly from fiscal income S-corporation dividends due to a di↵erent sampling period) in proportion to the top 1% share of fiscal income S-corporation dividends. In the case of C-corporations, because asubstantialshareofC-corporationwealthisheldoutsidethehouseholdsector,thereisa third term that reduces the amount of C-corporation income to the share held directly by households. The formula for the S-corporation allocation component is:

total S divs a =top1%Swealth ⇥ total S wealth ✓ ◆ total S wealth total S divs = top 1% S divs ⇥ total S divs ⇥ total S wealth ✓ ◆ ✓ ◆ top 1% S divs = total S divs total S divs ⇥

77 The formula for the C-corporation allocation component is:

total C divs b =top1%Cwealth ⇥ total C wealth ✓ ◆ total C household wealth total C divs =(top 1% C divs + top 1% cap gains) ⇥ total C divs + total cap gains ⇥ total C wealth ✓ ◆ ✓ ◆ top 1% C divs + top 1% cap gains total C household wealth = total C divs total C divs + total cap gains ⇥ total C household wealth + total C pension wealth ⇥ ✓ ◆ ✓ ◆

The formula for C retained earnings from the allocation component is:

retained earnings c = top 1% C wealth ⇥ total C wealth ✓ ◆ top 1% C divs + top 1% cap gains = total C divs + total cap gains ✓ ◆ total C household wealth retained earnings ⇥ total C household wealth + total C pension wealth ⇥ ✓ ◆

Figure I.18 implements these formulas and compares the replication of the final imputed income estimates to those in PSZ’s appendix spreadsheet, converted to dollars to aid compar- ison of alternative scenarios. The replication closely matches the imputed national income estimates in PSZ.76

F.2 Imputing Retained Earnings with Di↵erent Weights on Real- ized Capital Gains

Figures I.19A-C plot the equity-income-component series under alternative methods for us- ing realized capital gains to allocate C-corporation ownership shares. The graphs compare a dividends-only method to scenarios that use dividends plus 25%, 50%, or 100% of realized capital gains. We make these adjustments for wealth estimates used in both the alloca- tion and total equity income components of the imputed national income formulas above. For comparison purposes, we also plot a Fiscal Income + RE + Tax scenario, which uses fiscal income data for S-corporation dividends, C-corporation dividends, and partnership income; allocates C-corporation retained earnings in proportion to the household share of

76Slight di↵erences appear in the graph; there are minor discrepancies in the underlying raw micro and macro files we were given by PSZ. Note this replication seeks to match PSZ’s appendix spreadsheet estimates, including estimates from 2011–2014 based on extrapolated wealth data. Below, we present series with unextrapolated wealth inputs.

78 C-corporation dividends; and allocates corporate tax in proportion to these pre-tax figures. See Online Appendix E for additional details. The figures display a wide range in top 1% C-corporation dividends and retained earnings under alternative scenarios. Top 1% S-corporation income is largely unchanged, though the Fiscal Income + RE + Tax scenario shows greater volatility during the recent recession. In 2014, top 1% C-corporation dividends vary from $145B in the dividends only scenario to $182B when 25% of realized capital gains are used to $212B when 100% of realized capital gains are used. For retained earnings, the dividends only scenario yields $167B versus $210B when 25% of realized capital gains are used versus $245B when 100% of realized capital gains are used. The Fiscal Income + RE + Tax scenario yields $150B for top 1% C-corporation dividends and $170B for top 1% retained earnings.

F.3 Quantifying Top 1% Retained Earnings and Pass-through In- come in 2014

Figures I.20A-B explore the relative importance of the components of top 1% business income in 2014 under a range of assumptions for imputing retained earnings. The PSZ (2018) series presents the imputed national income estimates from PSZ’s paper as published, including S- corporation income ($229B), C-corporation dividends ($234B), and C-corporation retained earnings ($270B). Partnership income ($174B) equals fiscal partnership income (without adding a tax imputation) using INI ranks and household definitions to identify the top 1% percent.77 The PSZ Updated series updates the INI series in PSZ (2018) to reflect unextrapolated aggregate wealth estimates. When combined with fiscal partnership income, top 1% pass-through income in this series ($450B) roughly equals C-corporation dividends plus retained earnings ($457B). See Online Appendix D for additional details. The next series (Fiscal Income + RE + Tax) presents a “bottom up” approach that reports raw fiscal income for S-corporation dividends, partnership income, and C-corporation dividends. For C-corporation retained earnings, we allocate a share of macroeconomic re- tained earnings in proportion to fiscal C-corporation dividends only. We then allocate cor-

77Using fiscal partnership income here is conservative relative to imputed mixed income, which is consid- erably larger.

79 porate tax to each component in proportion to these pre-tax figures. This series retains the ranking and household definitions in INI. The next series (PS (2003) Ranks)appliesthe Fiscal Income + RE + Tax method but uses the Piketty and Saez (2003) method to sort households using fiscal income excluding capital gains and define households as tax units, thereby determining which units are considered top 1%. The remaining series apply the extrapolation update and modify the method for imputing components of equity income. The Divs Only (A+W) (“A” for Allocation, “W” for Wealth) series uses fiscal C-corporation dividends (and not realized capital gains) to compute C-corporation dividend and C-corporation retained earnings allocation factors (in step two above) and to compute top 1% equity income (in step one above)—i.e., it only uses the ownership composition of fiscal C-corporation dividends to estimate top 1% C-corporation wealth. The Divs + 0.25 CapG (A+W) and Divs + 0.5 CapG (A+W) use the sum of dividends and 25% or 50% of realized capital gains to compute allocation factors and top 1% equity income. The Divs Only series uses fiscal C-corporation dividends only when computing the allocation factors, but leaves top 1% equity income unchanged. The Add Pships series introduces partnership income as a fourth allocation component and adds this income to total equity income to be allocated, thus treating partnership income as a type of business income to be allocated similarly to S-corporation and C-corporation income. The Divs Only, Pships series uses both the Divs Only method for allocation and the Add Pships method to include partnership income. Finally, the Divs Only (A+W), Pships (“A” for Allocation, “W” for Wealth) series applies the Divs Only, Pships method and further uses the Divs Only wealth estimates to compute top 1% equity income. The analysis delivers three findings. First, across scenarios, pass-through income is quan- titatively important for top 1% incomes and usually larger than C-corporation income includ- ing retained earnings. Estimates of top 1% C-corporation income are sensitive to imputation assumptions. Second, using only dividends to allocate retained earnings delivers estimates for top 1% C-corporation dividends closer to observed taxable dividends.78 C-corporation dividends

78If one were to shrink top dividends and inflate top retained earnings, then one would be assuming a

80 in the PSZ Updated series are $212B, which exceeds by 46% the $145B in the Divs Only (A+W) series and by 41% the $150B in the Fiscal Income + RE + Tax series. Corresponding estimates of top 1% retained earnings range between $135B and $215B. The estimate from the Fiscal Income + RE + Tax series is $170B. Refinements that incorporate partnership income reduce the relative contribution and possible bias from estimated top 1% C-corporation wealth in the calculation of total equity income. Third, ranking e↵ects are relatively modest. Comparing the PS (2003) series to the Fiscal Income + RE + Tax series, C-corporation dividends and imputed retained earnings fall 19% and 14%, S-corporation income falls 24% from $306B to $233B, and partnership income falls 14% from $229B to $198B.

F.4 Quantifying the Growth of Retained Earnings

Following the alternative imputation approaches described in the prior section, Figures I.21A- Eillustratetherangeofimpliedrelativecontributionstotop1%incomegrowthfrompass- through and C-corporation income. Figures I.21A, I.21B, and I.21C respectively present the time series from 1990 to 2014 of S- corporation income, C-corporation dividends, and C-corporation retained earnings. Figures I.21D and I.21E quantify the relative contributions from S-corporation income, partnerships, and C-corporation income to overall business income growth, following the same approach as in Figures I.16A and I.16B. The data support PSZ’s finding on the large role in recent years of C-corporation income growth. C-corporation income accounts for 61% in the PSZ Updated series, 49% in the Fiscal Income + RE + Tax scenario, and always at least 44%. Retained earnings account for more than two-thirds of C-corporation income growth since 2000. In the time series, the year 2000 appears to be a local minimum for C-corporation income, likely driven by business cycle fluctuations. Starting in other nearby years yields smaller relative growth contributions for C-corporation income. Going back to 1990, pass-through income growth exceeds C-corporation growth across scenarios. In the Fiscal Income + RE di↵erent dividend payout ratio among top-owned C-corporation equity than bottom-owned C-corporation equity.

81 +Taxscenario,pass-throughincomeaccountsfor67%ofthegrowthsince1990and51%of the growth since 2000. S-corporation and partnership growth have provided approximately equal contributions to this growth.

82 G Other Capital Income in Imputed National Income

PSZ identify the rise of retained earnings since 2000 as the key discrepancy between a fiscal-income-based analysis and an imputed-national-income-based analysis. They write the “macro flow of retained earnings amounts to 5.1% of national income (on average over 2010–2014),” and that this flow contributes 1.2 points to the overall 1.9 point increase in the top 1% share in the PSZ series. For this reason, the prior appendices focus on this component of capital income. PSZ also write about missing tax-exempt capital income more broadly, noting that ob- served ordinary capital income misses “two-thirds of economic capital income.” In imputed national income, many of the largest components of national income not included in fiscal in- come are allocated roughly in proportion to fiscal income, including public goods spending, the government deficit, certain taxes, and pension benefits. Allocating these components alters the level of income but not its distribution. The other components of capital income PSZ mention—imputed housing rents, capital income paid to pension funds, dividends and interest retained in trusts, and corporate taxes— are less important than retained earnings, as shown in the analysis of the composition of top incomes in fiscal income and imputed national income in Figure 1 of our paper:

Imputed housing rents. While a large portion of unobserved capital income, imputed • housing rents are broadly held among the top 50% of the population.

Capital income (interest and dividends) paid to pension funds. In fiscal income, defined • contribution pensions show up when beneficiaries take distributions. These flows are therefore captured by fiscal income. In imputed national income, pension benefits are allocated in proportion to contributions, proxied by the distribution of taxable wage income. As wage income is more broadly distributed than taxable capital income, this approach has a small e↵ect on the top 1% income composition (as noted in PSZ, footnote 52, p.589, and discussion on p.577, Section IV.A).

Dividends and interest retained in trusts. We have not conducted a full reconciliation • for how this income is distributed in imputed national income. At least some of the

83 income flows through to tax returns and therefore appears in fiscal income. Of the components responsible for top 1% income growth in imputed national income, this item does not appear as a central driver.

Corporate tax. Corporate tax receipts have been falling over time and thus cannot • account for the growth in top 1% incomes observed in imputed national income. The retained earnings allocations in the prior sections account for corporate tax distributed across the pass-through and C-corporation sector, consistent with imputed national income estimates in PSZ.

When combined, these components very modestly contribute to top 1% income growth over time and remain smaller than either C-corporation or pass-through income. The key ex- cluded component driving the di↵erence between fiscal income and imputed national income is the allocation of C-corporation retained earnings. Two additional comments regarding these series deserve mention. First, there is a large gap between pass-through income in imputed national income and in fiscal income, despite the fact that in principle all of this income should appear on tax returns. We believe this gap owes primarily to the allocation of underreported income included in proprietors’ income in the national accounts. Auten and Splinter (2017) identify this factor as the most important di↵erence between their estimate of the top 1% share and imputed national income in PSZ. While large, this component did not grow disproportionately over the 1990–2014 period, so focusing on the fiscal partnership income series does not a↵ect our main conclusions (see Figures I.16A-B). Second, the largest component of non-business capital income that di↵ers from fiscal income and contributes to top 1% growth is interest income. We have not conducted a full reconciliation for this series. With imputed national income ranks, the taxable interest series is substantially lower than the imputed national income series and fell as a share of national income in recent decades. Further evidence of how interest income not present on tax returns is distributed would be valuable.

84 H Supplemental Analyses

H.1 Heterogeneous Profitability is Not Risk

Does high profitability at top-owned firms reflects payment for higher undiversifiable risk? For example, if top-owned firms have a higher probability of failure, owners could be com- pensated for that risk by higher profitability in years of survival. The blue circles (left axis) in Figure I.13 plots the share of year-2001 firms in the main sample that had exited the sample by 2014 (which typically indicates failure) versus 2001 owner personal income rank, weighting by the firm’s 2001 number of workers. Rather than experiencing higher exit rates than average, top-owned firms experienced lower exit rates than average. This finding suggests that top-owned firms exhibit higher profitability and lower risk. Whereas the exit rate measure proxies for risk along the extensive margin of firm exit, we employ a second measure that proxies for risk: a version of the Sharpe ratio, computed within each personal income bin. The Sharpe ratio—defined as an asset’s mean return divided by the standard deviation of its returns—is commonly used in finance to assess whether an asset’s return compensates for its risk. A high Sharpe ratio indicates returns in excess of what one would expect given the risk. In our context, higher Sharpe ratios among top- owned firms would indicate that top-owned firms’ high profitability more than suciently compensates their owners for their risk. For each year 2011–2014 in the main sample, we compute each personal income bin’s Sharpe ratio as the ratio of employment-weighted mean profitability to the employment-weighted standard deviation of profitability across owner- firm observations. We then average those within-bin Sharpe ratios evenly across years and plot the means in the green triangles (right axis) of Figure I.13. Top income bins have higher standard deviations of profitability, indicating somewhat higher risk. However, profitability is so much higher in top income bins that we find higher Sharpe ratios among top-owned firms. This finding suggests that higher risk does not explain higher profitability among top-owned firms.

85 H.2 The Human-Capital-Rich Finding Is Robust

Figure 7 used our preferred estimate of 75% for the human capital share of pass-through income. Seventy-five percent is the average of the six estimates—two estimates for each of three income groups—presented in Table 4. Online Appendix Figure I.7 repeats Figure 7whenusingtheminimumestimatefromTable4foreachincomegroup.Specifically,in Online Appendix Figure I.7, the top 1% bars classify 59.6% of pass-through income as labor income, the million-dollar-earner bars classify 81.6%, and the top 0.1% bars classify 71.7%. In each of the six permutations plotted in Online Appendix Figure I.7, most top earners are human-capital rich. As discussed in Section 3.3 and by PSZ, the same tax considerations that apparently lead human capital returns among pass-through owners to be characterized as profits can work in reverse at private C-corporations. The wages of private C-corporation owners may therefore contain non-human-capital returns, leading us to classify some top earners as human-capital rich when they are in fact financial-capital rich.79 Online Appendix Figure I.10 therefore repeats Figure 7 under the conservative assumption that all of an individual’s wages are capital income and not labor income, if her highest-paying W-2 was issued by a private C- corporation. We did so by merging the universe of Employer Identification Numbers (EINs) from private C-corporation tax filings to the EIN on the highest-paying W-2 of each top earner with a W-2, accounting for the fact that not every private C-corporation can be matched to its W-2s. See Online Appendix B for details. In each of the six permutations plotted in Online Appendix Figure I.10, we continue to find that a majority of top earners are human-capital rich.

H.3 Pass-through Growth Not Just a Reporting Phenomenon

The rising top pass-through income documented in Section 5.1 partly reflects relabeling of business income, as businesses reorganized from C-corporation to pass-through form and entrants increasingly chose pass-through form following the Tax Reform Act of 1986. We now quantify how much of the rise in top pass-through income is in fact a real economic

79Owners of public firms are too numerous to plausibly each receive a W-2 from the firm in order to avoid taxes.

86 phenomenon. Figure I.11A uses public SOI aggregate statistics from 1980–2012 to plot the pass-through (S+P) share of three measures of total (C+S+P) corporate and partnership activity: the total number of firms, total profits, and total sales. Figures I.11B-D focus on the period 2001–2014 during which our linked firm-owner data are available. The pass-through share of total business sales—which rose from approximately 10% in the mid-1980s to 20% in 1990 to 35% in recent years—indicates that some share of rising top pass-through income is an artifact of changes in the organizational form through which business income is reported. Figure I.11B shows the rapid increase from 2001 to 2014 in the number of pass-throughs is due mostly to firms that are not owned by top earners. Figure I.11C decomposes the level of pass-through profits between 2001 and 2014 into actual pass-through profits and the share attributed to organizational form changes. To correct for the e↵ect of di↵erential net entry into the pass-through sector, the decomposition assumes the level of pass-through sales remains a constant share of total business sales (in- cluding S-corporations, C-corporations, and partnerships) throughout the time period. The top bars represent the share of pass-through profits due to pass-through firms having a higher share of total business sales relative to 2001. Figure I.11D applies the same transformation to decompose the growth in top 0.1% pass-through profits. Figure I.11C shows that in 2014, the share of profit levels due to organizational form changes was approximately 26%, while 74% of pass-through profits remain under the constant share assumption. In terms of growth, Figure I.11D shows that actual top profits tripled between 2001 and 2014 in real terms, while counterfactual profits rose roughly 240%. Thus, most of the growth in top profits remains after adjusting for corporate form reorganization.80

H.4 Appropriate Correction for Firm Reorganizations

An earlier draft of this paper reported 60.7% as the preferred estimate of the profit impact of top 1% owner deaths at S-corporations (Table 4A Column 2 of Smith, Yagan, Zidar and

80We consider an alternative approach to measuring the role of corporate form switching using the popu- lation of businesses that switch from C-corporation to S-corporation form between 2001 and 2014. We find that 70% of the growth in S-corporation profits is due to firms that did not switch from C-corporation form during this time.

87 Zwick 2017). The current version reports 72.9% (Table 4A Column 8) at pass-throughs (S-corporations and partnerships). Most of the discrepancy derives from an inappropriate handling of firm reorganizations (i.e., firm exits that are not shutdowns) in the earlier draft, rather than sample di↵erences. A back-of-the-envelope correction to the earlier draft’s esti- mate nearly yields the current version’s 72.9% estimate. The earlier draft found that 28.6% of firm exits were reorganizations. Thus when com- puting the preferred impact of an owner death on firm survival, that draft multiplied the naive estimate of 41.0% by .714, yielding 29.3% (Table 4A Column 1 of Smith, Ya- gan, Zidar and Zwick 2017). Multiplying by .714 was a sensible correction for the exten- sive margin impact, since only 71.4% of the naive extensive-margin impact was genuine. However, the earlier draft applied the same correction to the Column 2 analysis of profits, which was inappropriate. Column 2 of that table analyzed profits at all firms, regardless of whether they exited and even though 100% of the profit impact at surviving firms was gen- uine. An appropriate back-of-the-envelope correction would therefore have multiplied only the extensive-margin component of the profit impact by .714, not the full impact. Com- bining estimates from Columns 1-3 from that table, that correction would have yielded: .714 ( 12307+5090)/24015/.602 = 70.9%. ⇥ The current version appropriately handles firm reorganizations in a simpler and more straightforward way: we replace firm profit at each reorganized firm with the last observed profit for that firm following Chetty and Saez (2005). We then run regressions on the replaced data, with no need for post-regression multiplication of the surviving share of firms. See Section 3.1 for more detail.

88 I Appendix Figures

Figure I.1: Working-Age Pass-through Owners Prevail at the Top of the Income Distribution

A. Using Primary Earner’s Age B. Using Imputed National Income 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 Share of million-dollar earners of million-dollar Share earners of million-dollar Share with majority income of this source income majority with of this source income majority with 0 0 20-29 30-39 40-49 50-59 60-69 70-79 80-89 90+ 20-29 30-39 40-49 50-59 60-69 70-79 80-89 90+ Age Group Age Group

Wages Pass-through Wages Pass-through Other capital C-corporation dividends Other capital C-corporation dividends + RE Notes: Panel A replicates Figure 2B when we use the age of the primary tax filer. See the notes to that figure for details. Panel B replicates Figure 2B among million-dollar earners in imputed national income at the individual level.

Figure I.2: Top 1% and Top 0.1% Pass-through Owners are Working Age

A. Top 1% B. Top 0.1% 40 40 30 30 20 20 Share of earners top 1% Share 10 10 Share of earners top 0.1% Share with majority income of this source income majority with of this source income majority with 0 0 20-29 30-39 40-49 50-59 60-69 70-79 80-89 90+ 20-29 30-39 40-49 50-59 60-69 70-79 80-89 90+ Age Group Age Group

Wages Pass-through Wages Pass-through Other capital C-corporation dividends Other capital C-corporation dividends Notes: This graph replicates Figure 2B among the top 1% and among the top 0.1%. See the notes to that figure for details.

89 Figure I.3: Profit Distribution of Top-owned Firms by Firm Size and Industry

A. Profit Distribution by Firm Size Top 1% Top 0.1% 100 100 80 80 60 60 40 40 this organizational form (%) this organizational form (%) this organizational 20 20 Share of profits generated by of profits generated Share by of profits generated Share 0 0

$500k-$1m $1m-$5m $5m-$10m $10m-$50m $50m-$500m $500m+ $500k-$1m $1m-$5m $5m-$10m $10m-$50m $50m-$500m $500m+ Sales in 2014 Sales in 2014

C-corporations Top 1% owned pass-throughs C-corporations Top 0.1% owned pass-throughs

B. Distribution of Profits Across Industries Top 1% Top 0.1% 50 50 40 40 30 30 20 20 Share of total (%) Share of total (%) Share 10 10 0 0 Agriculture & ForestryConstruction &Manufacturing Mining Retail & WholesaleFin, Insur Trade & RealInfo Estate & ProfessionalHealth Svcs Care Entertnmt, FoodOther & Hotels Svcs Agriculture & ForestryConstruction &Manufacturing Mining Retail & WholesaleFin, Insur Trade & RealInfo Estate & ProfessionalHealth Svcs Care Entertnmt, FoodOther & Hotels Svcs

C-corporation profits Top 1% owned pass-through firms C-corporation profits Top 1% owned pass-through firms Number of workers Number of workers

Notes: This figure replicates Figure 3 for the top 1% and top 0.1%. See the notes to that figure for details.

90 Figure I.4: Profit Distribution of Top-owned Firms by Profit Bin (2014) A. Top 1% 80 60 40 20 this organizational form (%) this organizational Share of profits generated by of profits generated Share 0

$500k-$1m $1m-$5m $5m-$10m $250m+ $10m-$25m $25m-$50m$50m-$100m$100m-$250m Profits in 2014

C-corporations Top 1% owned pass-throughs

B. Top 0.1% 80 60 40 20 this organizational form (%) this organizational Share of profits generated by of profits generated Share 0

$500k-$1m $1m-$5m $5m-$10m $250m+ $10m-$25m $25m-$50m$50m-$100m$100m-$250m Profits in 2014

C-corporations Top 0.1% owned pass-throughs

Notes: This figure plots the distribution of profits earned by C-corporations and top-owned pass-through firms in 2014, by total profits and corporate form. The cumulative share of top 1% profits earned by firms with less than $10M in profits is 52.1%. The cumulative share of top 1% profits earned by firms with less than $50M in profits is 71.6%.

91 Figure I.5: Spatial Allocation of Top-Owned Firms

A.Top1% B.Million-DollarEarners C.Top0.1%

CA CA NY

TX TX CA

NY NY TX

FL IL IL

IL FL FL

NJ MA MA

MA NJ NJ

PA PA PA

OH CT CT

MI OH MI 92 GA MI OH

CT GA WI

WI WI GA

MN MN MN

LA MO MO

Other Other Other 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 Share of population and profits by corporate form (%) Share of population and profits by corporate form (%) Share of population and profits by corporate form (%)

C-corporations Population C-corporations Population C-corporations Population Top 1% owned pass-throughs Millionaire-owned pass-throughs Top 0.1% owned pass-throughs

Notes: This figure uses our 2014 linked-firm-owner data and the SOI sample of C-corporations to show that top-owned pass-through profits are widely distributed across states, and roughly proportional to 2014 state population. State refers to the state listed on the business income tax return, typically the state of the firm headquarters. Owners are indexed by their fiscal income. The “other” category comprises all states not explicitly listed. Figure I.6: Profit Impacts of Owner Deaths and Retirements, Additional Top Groups

A. Owner Deaths Top1% Million-DollarEarners Top0.1% 20 20 20 0 0 0 -20 -20 -20 -40 -40 2014 Dollars (000s) Dollars 2014 (000s) Dollars 2014 (000s) Dollars 2014 -40 -60 -60 -60

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Years Since Owner Death Years Since Owner Death Years Since Owner Death

Impact 95% CI Impact 95% CI Impact 95% CI 93 B. Owner Retirements Top1% Million-DollarEarners Top0.1% 20 20 20 0 0 0 -20 -20 -20 -40 -40 -40 2014 Dollars (000s) Dollars 2014 2014 Dollars (000s) Dollars 2014 (000s) Dollars 2014 -60 -60 -60

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Years Since Owner Retirement Years Since Owner Retirement Years Since Owner Retirement

Impact 95% CI Impact 95% CI Impact 95% CI

Notes: The middle panels of this figure reproduce the two graphs of Figure 5. See the notes to that figure for details. The left and right panels of this figure repeat the middle panels for owners in the top-1% of the fiscal income distribution and for owners in the top-0.1% of the income distribution, respectively. Figure I.7: Are Top Earners Human-Capital Rich? Conservative Labor Share

A. Human-Capital Rich and Self-Made Shares of Top Earners (FI)

B. Human-Capital Rich and Self-Made Shares of Top Earners (INI)

Notes: This figure replicates Figure 7 except that it does not classify 75% of pass-through income as labor income. Instead, the top 1% bars classify 59.6% of pass-through income as labor income, the million-dollar- earner bars classify 81.6%, and the top 0.1% bars classify 71.7%. See Section H.2 and the notes to Figure 7 for details.

94 Figure I.8: How Do Million-Dollar Earners Earn Their Income? Conservative Labor Share

A. Top Labor and Capital Income (FI)

Labor Income=71% 72%

66%

44%

45%

Entrepreneurial Income=39%

B. Top Labor and Capital Income (INI)

49%

Labor Income=48%

36%

41% 36%

Entrepreneurial Income=36%

Notes: This figure replicates Figure 8 except that it does not classify 75% of pass-through income as labor income. Instead, the top 1% bars classify 59.6% of pass-through income as labor income, the million-dollar- earner bars classify 81.6%, and the top 0.1% bars classify 71.7%. See Section H.2 and the notes to Figure 8 for details.

95 Figure I.9: Are Top Earners Human-Capital Rich? Reclassified C-Corp Wages

A. Human-Capital Rich and Self-Made Shares of Top Earners (FI)

B. Human-Capital Rich and Self-Made Shares of Top Earners (INI)

Notes: This figure replicates Figure 7 except it classifies as capital income all wages of individuals whose highest-W2-payer was a private C-corporation. In the case of married tax units, we classify as capital income all wages of the tax unit if either spouse’s highest-W2-payer was a private C-corporation. See Section H.2 and the notes to Figure 7 for details.

96 Figure I.10: How Do Million-Dollar Earners Earn Their Income? Reclassified C-Corp Wages

A. Top Labor and Capital Income (FI) 2,000

1,500 556.5

118.2 1,000

Income (B) Income 403.6 241.3 Labor Income=63% 59.3 177.5 59% 134.5 263.0 41.3 500 58% 44% 208.9

325.4 87.7 45% 69.6 174.7 133.7 Entrepreneurial Income=39% 141.6 100.4 84.0 0 Top 1% Million-dollar earners Top 0.1%

Pass-through labor Non-owner wages Pass-through capital Owner wages C-corporation dividends Other capital income

B. Top Labor and Capital Income (INI) 3,000 643.0

90.7

783.9 2,000 338.4 49.0

261.3 43% Labor Income=47% 516.9 184.9 Income (B) Income 30.3 36%

638.5 172.3 376.6 39% 1,000 36% Entrepreneurial Income=36% 125.5 462.1 366.6 613.4 419.6 305.5 0 Top 1% Million-dollar earners Top 0.1%

Pass-through labor Non-owner wages Pass-through capital Owner wages C-corporation dividends Other capital income

Notes: This figure replicates Figure 8 except it classifies as capital income all wages of individuals whose highest-W2-payer was a private C-corporation. In the case of married tax units, we classify as capital income all wages of the tax unit if either spouse’s highest-W2-payer was a private C-corporation. See Section H.2 and the notes to Figure 7 for details.

97 Figure I.11: Growth in Pass-through Profits Accounting for Organizational Form Changes

A.Pass-throughShareofActivity B.NumberofPass-Throughs 8 80% 6 60% 4 40% Business Business Activity Pass-through Share of Share Pass-through 2 20% Number of Pass-throughs (M) of Pass-throughs Number 0% 0 2011 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 2013 2014 Year Year

Firms Profits Sales All Top 1-0.1% Owner Top 0.1% Owner

C. Total Pass-through Profits D. Top-0.1% Pass-through Profit Growth Adjusted for Org. Form Changes Adjusted for Org. Form Changes 2.5 1 .8 2 .6 .4 1.5 .2 Percentage of Pass-through Profits of Pass-through Percentage Growth Growth of Aggregate Top Firm 0.1% Profits 1 0 2011

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 2013 2014 Year Profits holding sales share fixed Profits from org. form changes Profits Profits holding profit share fixed

Notes: Panel A uses the SOI C-corporate, S-corporate, and Partnership study files to show the pass-through (S-corporation plus partnership) shares of total business activity since 1980 (measured as the sum of C- corporations, S-corporations, and partnerships). Panel B uses our linked-firm-owner data to show the number of pass-throughs by owner income group since 2001, which is the period for which the US Treasury tax files enable us to link firms and owners. Panel C uses our linked-firm-owner data along with the SOI files to decompose the level of pass-through profits between 2001 and 2014 into actual pass-through profits and the share attributed to organizational form changes. The decomposition assumes the level of pass-through sales is a constant share of total business (i.e., S-corporation plus C-corporation plus partnership) sales. The top bars represent the share of pass-through profits that are attributed to pass-throughs having a higher share of total business sales relative to 2001. Panel D uses our linked-firm-owner data along with the SOI files to apply the same transformation to decompose the growth in pass-through profits among those with top 0.1% owners. The first series shows how actual pass-through profits increased since 2001. The second series shows a counterfactual series, which assumes that pass-through sales are a constant share of total business sector activity equal to the initial psss-through share in 2001.

98 Figure I.12: Robustness of Value Added Decomposition

A. Decomposing Entrepreneurial Income Growth (Without Adjustment for Org. Form Changes)

Top 1% (2001-2014) 29.4 35.8 34.7

Top 0.1% (2001-2014) 29.6 36.8 33.7

Top 1% (2004-2014) 42.7 35.5 21.8

Top 0.1% (2004-2014) 40.0 37.7 22.3

0 20 40 60 80 100 Share of Growth in Entrepreneurial Income Workers VA per Worker Owner Share

B. Falling Wages and Rising Entrepreneurial Income Since 2004 Top 1% Top 0.1% 60 60

6.5

45 9.3 45 8.5 10.9 30 30 55.6 52.1 51.7 45.5 47.9 38.6 39.9 33.5 15 15 Share of ValueShare (%) Added of ValueShare (%) Added 0 0 Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay Entrep. Inc. Worker Pay 2004 2014 2004 2014

Profits Owner Wages

Notes: Panel A replicates Figure 10C without adjusting for organizational form changes. Not accounting for changes in organizational form overstates the role of growth in scale in explaining the rise in entrepreneurial income in our analysis sample. Panel B replicates Figure 10D using 2004 as the baseline year. This figure suggests that our findings are robust to our baseline year of choice.

99 Figure I.13: Risk Decreases with Owner Income Rank .45 .4 .4 .3 .35 .2 P(2001 firm missing from 2014 data) .3 .1 Within-bin profits-per-worker Sharpe ratio 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 Fiscal income percentile

Firm exit rate 2001-2004 Sharpe ratio 2011-2014 Sharpe ratio

Notes: This figure plots measures of risk in the linked-firm-owner data by owner fiscal income percentile. The circles plot the share of 2001 pass-throughs within each fiscal income bin that had exited the sample by 2014, weighting by the firm’s 2001 number of employees. The squares and triangles plot a measure of the mean Sharpe ratio across firms. Our Sharpe ratio is defined as the average profits per worker at firms owned by individuals within the fiscal income bin divided by the standard deviation of profits per worker at those firms, weighting firms by their number of workers and then averaging ratios across the listed years.

100 Figure I.14: Pass-Through Income in Top 1% Imputed National Income (PSZ, 2018)

A. PSZ Appendix Figure S.34 B. Isolating mixed income 20 20 15 15 10 10 % of National Income % of National Income % of National 5 5 0 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Labor income Labor (excl. pass-through) Other pass-through labor S-corporation profits S-corporation profits Other pass-through capital Capital income (excl. S-corporation profits) Capital (excl. pass-through)

C. Pass-through income 20 15 10 % of National Income % of National 5 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Labor (excl. pass-through) Pass-through Capital (excl. pass-through)

Notes: This figure plots components of top income from imputed national income. Panel A replicates Appendix Figure S.34 from Piketty, Saez and Zucman (2018). Panel B modifies Panel A by applying shading to the components of labor and capital income that reflect allocations from mixed income. Panel C applies the same shading to S-corporation profits and the labor and capital components of PSZ. See Appendix C for further discussion.

101 Figure I.15: E↵ect of Updating Financial Accounts Wealth on Imputed Equity Income

S-corp income C-corp dividends C-corp retained earnings 325 325 325 275 275 275 225 225 225 102 175 175 175 Billions of USD Billions Billions of USD Billions of USD Billions 125 125 125 75 75 75 25 25 25 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

PSZ (2018) PSZ Updated PSZ (2018) PSZ Updated PSZ (2018) PSZ Updated

Notes: This figure shows the e↵ect of updating the equity income components in imputed national income to reflect actual aggregate wealth estimates for 2011–2014. See Appendix D for more detail. Figure I.16: E↵ect of Updating Financial Accounts Wealth on the Composition of Business Income Growth

A. Contributions to business income growth (1990–2014) B. Contributions to business income growth (2000–2014)

PSZ (2018) 0.29 0.22 0.18 0.31 PSZ (2018) 0.06 0.19 0.25 0.49

PSZ Updated 0.38 0.22 0.14 0.26 PSZ Updated 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.42 103

PSZ Updated, Mixed Income 0.35 0.28 0.13 0.24 PSZ Updated, Mixed Income 0.20 0.17 0.20 0.43

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Contribution to Top 1% Growth since 1990 Contribution to Top 1% Growth since 2000 S Divs Pships C Divs C Retained S Divs Pships C Divs C Retained

Notes: This figure shows the e↵ect of updating the equity income components in imputed national income to reflect actual aggregate wealth estimates for 2011–2014. Panels A and B quantify the relative contributions from S-corporation income, C-corporation income, and partnerships to overall business income growth over the periods 1990–2014 and 2000–2014, respectively. “PSZ Updated, Mixed Income” defines partnership income as total labor and capital mixed income, instead of fiscal partnership income. For each scenario, we compute the contribution of business income to top income growth (e.g., business income increased by 2.8% of national income from 1990 to 2014) and divide this amount into contributions from each source (e.g., S-corporation income increased by 1.1% of national income from 1990 to 2014, or 40% of the business income increase). See Appendix D for more detail. Figure I.17: Realized Capital Gains, C-Corporation Stock, and Retained Earnings

A. Realized Capital Gains Composition 50 40 30 20 10 Share of Share Total (%) Gains Capital Realized 0 1996-99 2003-07 2010-12

Stocks/Mutual Funds Hard Assets/Real Estate Pass-through Asset Sales Pass-through Gains Other/Unidentified

B. Realized Capital Gains vs. Retained Earnings 1000 800 600 400 Billions of Real USD (2014$) USD of Real Billions 200 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Year

Macroeconomic Retained Earnings Household Share of Macro Retained Earnings Total Fiscal Income Realized Capital Gains

Notes: Panel A plots the share of total realized capital gains accrued to /mutual funds, hard assets, pass-through asset sales, pass-through gains, and other assets in 1996–1999, 2003–2007, and 2010–2012. Hard assets includes net gains/losses for depreciable business personal property, depreciable business real property, farmland and other land, livestock, timber, residential rental property, and all residences. The graph focuses on non-recession years, as the cyclicality of realized gains can cause components of net gains to turn negative during downturns. Data comes from the Statistics of Income (SOI) Tax Stats table “Sales of Capital Assets Reported on Individual Tax Returns.” Panel B plots macroeconomic retained earnings, the household sector’s share of macroeconomic retained earnings (defined using C-corporation wealth estimates in the US Financial Accounts), and total fiscal realized capital gains over 1962–2014 (all in 2014 dollars). See Appendix E for more detail.

104 Figure I.18: Replication of Imputed National Income Equity Income Components

A.S-corpincome B.C-corpdividends C.C-corpretainedearnings 325 325 325 275 275 275 225 225 225 175 175 105 175 Billions of USD Billions Billions of USD Billions of USD Billions 125 125 125 75 75 75 25 25 25 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

Final Component in Replication Final Component in Replication Final Component in Replication Final Component in PSZ Final Component in PSZ Final Component in PSZ

Notes: This figure implements the formulas in Appendix F.1 and compares the replication of the final imputed income estimates to those in PSZ’s appendix spreadsheet, converted to dollars to aid comparison of alternative scenarios. Figure I.19: E↵ect of Alternative Capital Gains Assumptions on Imputed Equity Income

S-corp income C-corp dividends C-corp retained earnings 325 325 325 275 275 275 225 225 225 175 175 175 Billions of USD Billions Billions of USD Billions of USD Billions 125 125 125 75 75 75 25 25 25 106 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

PSZ Updated Divs only + 0.5 KGs PSZ Updated Divs only + 0.5 KGs PSZ Updated Divs only + 0.5 KGs Divs only + 0.25 KGs Divs only Divs only + 0.25 KGs Divs only Divs only + 0.25 KGs Divs only Fiscal Income + RE + Tax Fiscal Income + RE + Tax Fiscal Income + RE + Tax

Notes: This figure graphs S-corporation income, C-corporation dividends and retained earnings under alternative assumptions for using realized capital gains to impute equity income. These alternative assumptions reflect the possibility some realized capital gains are not due to the sale of C-corporation stock and thus should not be used to estimate the ownership of C-corporation stock. PSZ Updated updates the original PSZ series to reflect actual aggregate wealth estimates. Divs only, Divs only + 0.25 KGs and Divs only + 0.5 KGs respectively graph a dividends-only method, and scenarios that use dividends plus 25% or 50% of realized capital gains. We make these adjustments for wealth estimates used in both the allocation and total equity income components of the imputed national income (INI) formulas. Fiscal Income + RE + Tax uses INI ranks and household definitions to identify the top 1 percent, then uses fiscal income data for S-corporation dividends, partnership income, and C-corporation dividends. For C-corporation retained earnings, this scenario allocates a share of macroeconomic retained earnings in proportion to C-corporation dividends only. It then allocates corporate tax to each component in proportion to these pre-tax figures. See Appendix F.2 for discussion. Figure I.20: Top 1% Business Income Sources under Alternative Imputation Assumptions

A. Pass-through income 600 500

229 174 400 174 174 202 174 174 198 174 175

300 157 Billions USD Billions

200 332 306 276 258 269 273 268 229 233 233 208 100 0

PSZ (2018) Divs OnlyAdd Pships PSZ Updated PS (2003) RanksDivs Only (A+W) Divs Only, Pships Divs + 0.5 CapG (A+W) Fiscal Income + RE + Tax Divs + 0.25 CapG (A+W) Divs Only (A+W), Pships

S-corp Dividends Partnership Income

B. C-corporation income 600 500

400 270 245 228 215 300 210 206 170 173

Billions USD Billions 167 147

200 135

234 212 182 198 186 179 100 150 145 150 122 116 0

PSZ (2018) Divs OnlyAdd Pships PSZ Updated PS (2003) RanksDivs Only (A+W) Divs Only, Pships Divs + 0.5 CapG (A+W) Fiscal Income + RE + Tax Divs + 0.25 CapG (A+W) Divs Only (A+W), Pships

C-corp Dividends C-corp Retained Earnings

107 Notes to Figure I.20: This figure plots business income sources in 2014 under alternative assumptions for imputing national income. We consider the following scenarios: 1. PSZ (2018). Original imputed national income (INI) numbers from PSZ. 2. PSZ Updated. For the years from 2011 through 2014, PSZ extrapolate top 1 S-corporation and C-corporation wealth: they start with the 2010 values and then grow them using the growth rate of aggregate household equity wealth. This scenario updates the INI series from PSZ to reflect actual aggregate wealth estimates. 3. Fiscal Income + RE + Tax. Use imputed national income ranks and household defintions from PSZ to identify the top 1%. Then use fiscal income data for S-corporation dividends, partnership income, and C-corporation dividends. For C-corporation retained earnings, allocate a share of macroeconomic retained earnings in proportion to C-corporation dividends. Then allocate corporate tax to each component in proportion to these pre-tax figures. 4. PS (2003) Ranks. Use the Raw Data + Tax method for fiscal income data for top 1 percent households identified using the Piketty and Saez (2003) method of sorting households by fiscal income excluding capital gains. 5. Divs Only (A+W) (“A” for Allocation, “W” for Wealth). Use only fiscal C-corporation dividends (not capital gains) to compute C-corporation dividend and C-corporation retained earnings allocation factors and in the computation of top 1% equity income. 6. Divs Only + 0.25 CapG (A+W). Use fiscal C-corporation dividends plus 25% of realized capital gains to compute C-corporation dividend and C-corporation retained earnings allocation factors and in the computation of top 1 equity income. 7. Divs Only + 0.5 CapG (A+W). As above, but uses fiscal C-corporation dividends plus 50% of realized capital gains. 8. Divs Only. Use fiscal C-corporation dividends only to compute C-corporation dividend and C-corporation retained earnings allocation factors, but leave top 1% equity income unchanged. 9. Add Pships. Add fiscal partnership income as a fourth allocation component and to top 1% equity income. 10. Divs Only, Pships. Use both the Divs Only method for allocation and the Add Pships method to include partnership income. 11. Divs Only (A+W), Pships. Use the Divs Only method for both allocation and the computation of top 1% equity income and the Add Pships method to include partnership income. Scenarios 5–11 all apply the extrapolation fix in scenario 2. Scenarios 1, 2, and 5–8 use raw partnership income without a corporate tax imputation. Appendix F.3 provides additional discussion of this analysis.

108 Figure I.21: Top 1% Business Income Growth under Alternative Imputation Assumptions

A.S-corpincome B.C-corpdividends C.C-corpretainedearnings 325 325 325 275 275 275 225 225 225 175 175 175 Billions of USD Billions of USD Billions of USD Billions 125 125 125 75 75 75 25 25 25 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

PSZ (2018) PSZ Updated PSZ (2018) PSZ Updated PSZ (2018) PSZ Updated Fiscal Income + RE + Tax PS (2003) Ranks Fiscal Income + RE + Tax PS (2003) Ranks Fiscal Income + RE + Tax PS (2003) Ranks Divs Only Add Pships Divs Only Add Pships Divs Only Add Pships Divs Only, Pships Divs Only (A+W), Pships Divs Only, Pships Divs Only (A+W), Pships Divs Only, Pships Divs Only (A+W), Pships

D. Contributions to business income growth (1990–2014) E. Contributions to business income growth (2000–2014)

109 PSZ (2018) 0.29 0.22 0.18 0.31 PSZ (2018) 0.06 0.19 0.25 0.49

PSZ Updated 0.38 0.22 0.14 0.26 PSZ Updated 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.42

Fiscal Income + RE + Tax 0.35 0.32 0.11 0.22 Fiscal Income + RE + Tax 0.28 0.23 0.12 0.38

PS (2003) Ranks 0.41 0.32 0.08 0.19 PS (2003) Ranks 0.27 0.29 0.10 0.34

Divs Only (A+W) 0.41 0.26 0.11 0.21 Divs Only (A+W) 0.25 0.19 0.21 0.34

Divs + 0.25 CapG (A+W) 0.39 0.23 0.14 0.24 Divs + 0.25 CapG (A+W) 0.22 0.20 0.20 0.39

Divs + 0.5 CapG (A+W) 0.38 0.23 0.14 0.25 Divs + 0.5 CapG (A+W) 0.20 0.19 0.19 0.41

Divs Only 0.44 0.22 0.11 0.22 Divs Only 0.19 0.19 0.22 0.40

Add Pships 0.36 0.27 0.12 0.25 Add Pships 0.19 0.21 0.19 0.41

Divs Only, Pships 0.41 0.29 0.10 0.20 Divs Only, Pships 0.19 0.22 0.21 0.38

Divs Only (A+W), Pships 0.40 0.29 0.10 0.20 Divs Only (A+W), Pships 0.25 0.24 0.20 0.32 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Contribution to Top 1% Growth since 1990 Contribution to Top 1% Growth since 2000 S Divs Pships C Divs C Retained S Divs Pships C Divs C Retained

Notes: This figure plots the growth of business income sources under alternative assumptions for imputing national income. For detail on these assumptions, see the note to Figure I.20 and the discussion in Section F.3. Panels A–C plot the time series of S-corporation income, C-corporation dividends, and C-corporation retained earnings from 1990 to 2014. Panels D and E quantify the relative contributions from S-corporation income, C- corporation income, and partnerships to overall business income growth over the periods 1990–2014 and 2000–2014, respectively. For each imputation scenario, we compute the contribution of business income to top income growth (e.g., business income increased by 2.8% of national income from 1990 to 2014) and divide this amount into contributions from each source (e.g., S-corporation income increased by 1.1% of national income from 1990 to 2014, or 40% of the business income increase). See Appendix F.4 for discussion. J Appendix Tables

110 Table J.1: Summary Statistics on S-Corporations and Their Owners

A. Firm Summary Statistics A. All Firms B. Firms with Top 1-0.1% Owner C. Firms with Top 0.1% Owner Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Sales 1,824 21 264 2,639 4,267 56 1,256 9,937 22,520 61 3,581 49,917 Profits 93 -27 14 183 234 -26 125 691 1,597 -80 283 3,681 Profit margin 0.05 -0.19 0.05 0.40 0.11 -0.03 0.08 0.43 0.12 -0.02 0.08 0.45 Assets 919 0 54 922 1,878 12 311 3,742 14,163 40 1,427 22,068 Employees 13.9 0.0 2.0 25.3 32.8 0.0 7.0 70.6 103.0 0.0 10.6 190.5 Employees Employees > 020.41.05.037.143.01.212.889.4150.82.334.9267.4 Entrepreneurial| income 147 -14 38 311 400 -9 294 . . -47 467 . Numberofowners 1.6 1.0 1.0 2.4 2.2 1.0 1.2 4.0 3.4 1.0 2.0 6.1 Sales per worker 195.1 22.7 88.3 362.2 323.5 31.3 139.8 647.0 865.2 29.4 190.9 1,241.0 Profits per worker 18.4 -5.5 4.2 47.6 39.7 -2.0 10.6 111.7 139.9 -4.8 11.8 186.9 Profits per worker, employees-weighted 5.5 -1.7 1.0 16.0 6.3 -0.4 1.5 17.6 12.3 -0.0 2.7 28.4 Profits per owner 57.3 -18.9 10.6 132.9 153.7 -14.3 74.0 465.0 827.4 -37.8 127.5 2,071.0 Entrep. income per owner 92.2 -10.3 28.1 219.6 249.5 -4.8 180.0 652.4 959.3 -22.1 206.8 2,426.0 Entrep. income per worker 36.1 -1.2 13.5 85.0 72.8 0.4 25.3 208.8 190.6 -1.7 20.1 302.4 111 Entrep. income / profit 1.69 0.31 1 4.08 2.05 0.93 1.14 4.24 1.57 0.77 1 2.25 Entrep. income / sales 0.13 -0.19 0.13 0.61 0.20 -0.05 0.17 0.70 0.16 -0.12 0.11 0.79 Numberoffirm-years 43,898,440 4,933,977 1,367,487

B. Owner Summary Statistics A.AllOwners B.Top1-0.1%Owners C.Top0.1%Owners Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Income 213 15 98 423 646 391 560 1,076 4,511 1,549 2,391 7,486 Age 50.0 34.7 49.8 66.3 52.1 38.8 51.5 66.9 54.9 40.9 54.4 70.9 Numberoffirmsowned 1.1 1.0 1.0 1.7 1.3 1.0 1.0 2.0 1.8 1.0 1.0 3.1 Wageincome 71 0 31 157 205 0 148 489 743 0 249 1,749 S-corporation income 60.04 -15.78 8.85 132.37 198.26 -4.34 127.40 548.25 1536 -4.70 749.34 3358 Entrepreneurial income 100 -8 27 229 322 0 285 760 . 0 . . S-corp income / entrep. income 0.68 0.03 1 1 0.72 0.12 0.86 1 0.82 0.34 1 1 Wageincome/income 0.64 0 0.29 0.95 0.33 0 0.25 0.82 0.21 0 0.09 0.70 Entrep. income / income 0.73 -0.08 0.39 1.01 0.50 0 0.51 1 0.48 0 0.49 0.98 Business income / income 0.22 -0.17 0.16 0.84 0.38 0 0.40 0.82 0.53 0 0.64 0.92 Onlyearnspassiveincome 0.08 0 0 0 0.07 0 0 0 0.05 0 0 0 Numberofowner-years 61,764,812 5,966,540 1,103,585 Notes: This table replicates Table 1, restricting to S-corporation observations only. Dollar values are in thousands of 2014 dollars. The main sample comprises firm-owner-year observations with positive sales and non-zero profits. Panel A pools distinct firm-year observations. Panel B pools distinct owner-year observations. All statistics are unweighted, unless otherwise specified. Table J.2: Summary Statistics on Partnerships and Their Owners

A. Firm Summary Statistics A. All Firms B. Firms with Top 1-0.1% Owner C. Firms with Top 0.1% Owner Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Sales 1,767 4 136 2,040 2,434 5 366 4,895 11,233 8 634 14,468 Profits -152 -45 6 240 244 -74 24 796 1,609 -244 40 2,608 Profitmargin 0.06 -0.77 0.05 0.80 0.13 -0.56 0.10 0.91 0.15 -0.52 0.11 0.93 Employees 10.2 0.0 0.0 17.9 17.5 0.0 0.0 38.4 38.5 0.0 0.0 74.0 Employees Employees > 030.31.37.758.444.42.013.692.9112.92.828.6208.1 Entrepreneurial| income 135 -35 6 217 212 -54 22 712 . -161 28 . Numberofowners 4.4 1.0 2.0 4.0 4.0 1.0 2.0 7.1 27.8 1.0 3.0 21.2 Sales per worker 202.2 12.5 72.0 370.0 277.0 16.5 109.6 523.8 504.0 15.1 98.5 781.2 Profits per worker 2.5 -11.7 2.1 60.4 38.7 -11.3 5.8 117.8 77.5 -34.9 2.7 157.6 Profits per worker, employees-weighted -22.1 -3.8 0.7 30.7 9.2 -2.4 1.1 32.3 24.6 -2.6 2.1 79.5 Profits per owner -275.5 -20.6 2.6 106.5 87.6 -26.7 8.5 324.4 362.1 -61.2 8.5 798.9 Entrep. income per owner 34.9 -16.1 2.8 95.3 70.0 -19.6 7.6 292.7 229.0 -40.1 5.8 587.6 Entrep. income per worker 20.6 -8.5 3.1 61.7 39.0 -7.5 6.7 116.9 68.1 -21.8 2.5 145.4

112 Entrep. income / profit 0.95 0.50 1 1 0.93 0.41 1 1 0.82 0.23 0.99 1 Entrep. income / sales 0.06 -0.82 0.06 0.81 0.14 -0.67 0.10 0.94 0.13 -0.82 0.09 0.95 Numberoffirm-years 15,035,028 2,445,622 1,097,116

B. Owner Summary Statistics A.AllOwners B.Top1-0.1%Owners C.Top0.1%Owners Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Mean p10 p50 p90 Income 263 10 97 548 664 396 581 1,102 4,845 1,569 2,466 8,247 Age 52.6 33.6 52.3 73.6 52.7 39.1 52.0 68.0 54.0 40.4 53.3 69.9 Numberoffirmsowned 1.4 1.0 1.0 2.0 1.7 1.0 1.0 3.0 2.6 1.0 1.4 5.5 Wageincome 83 0 1 177 201 0 71 587 1,102 0 178 2,745 Partnershipincome 39.98 -8.16 0.34 76.69 132.41 -6.81 7.50 508.35 658.49 -22.16 11.02 1962 Entrepreneurial income 43 -8 0 87 138 -6 8 522 670 -22 12 . Pship income / entrep. income 0.98 1 1 1 0.98 1 1 1 0.99 1 1 1 Wageincome/income 0.63 0 0 0.95 0.31 0 0.12 0.93 0.26 0 0.06 0.94 Entrep. income / income 3.85 -0.08 0.01 0.79 0.21 -0.01 0.01 0.90 0.18 -0.01 0 0.87 Business income / income 0.22 -0.09 0.02 0.97 0.36 -0.01 0.25 0.97 0.42 -0.01 0.45 0.96 Onlyearnspassiveincome 0.16 0 0 1 0.14 0 0 1 0.09 0 0 0.30 Numberofowner-years 46,810,812 5,826,709 1,225,439 Notes: This table replicates Table 1, restricting to partnership observations only. Dollar values are in thousands of 2014 dollars. The main sample comprises firm-owner-year observations with positive sales and non-zero profits. Panel A pools distinct firm-year observations. Panel B pools distinct owner-year observations. All statistics are unweighted, unless otherwise specified. Table J.3: Firm and Owner Counts by Industry for S-Corporations and Partnerships

Top 0.1% Owners Top 1-0.1% Owners Industry(NAICS) SFirms SOwners PFirms POwners Industry(NAICS) SFirms SOwners PFirms POwners Lessors of real estate (5311) 12573 18150 115664 200328 Oces of physicians (6211) 41975 63386 7463 36957 Activities related to real estate (5313) 10911 14973 47793 92785 Lessors of real estate (5311) 33466 56383 277828 684343 Automobile dealers (4411) 5236 7927 1418 2287 Activities related to real estate (5313) 25314 39844 96502 258321 Oces of physicians (6211) 4711 5817 1333 2440 Other professional/technical svc (5419) 22841 32287 13018 32316 Restaurants (7225) 4471 6133 5978 10986 Oces of dentists (6212) 18413 21199 2120 3737 Other professional/technical svc (5419) 4291 5672 4443 8179 Restaurants (7225) 16300 26823 10520 29476 Other financial investment actvty (5239) 4030 6215 61477 349033 Legal svc (5411) 13240 16808 8987 52849 Management/techncl consulting svc (5416) 2785 3684 3114 5657 Management/techncl consulting svc (5416) 11746 16754 8525 22143 Indie artists, writers, performers (7115) 1992 2251 787 1235 Oces of other health practitioners (6213) 9978 13583 3186 10286 Other specialty trade cntrctr (2389) 1968 2688 663 952 Insurance agencies/brokerages (5242) 9753 14568 3172 7382 Legal svc (5411) 1929 2241 1615 9871 Other specialty trade cntrctr (2389) 9737 14483 2265 3936 Insurance agencies/brokerages (5242) 1832 2434 951 1531 Computer sys design/related svc (5415) 9607 14422 4502 10605 Computer sys design/related svc (5415) 1760 2444 1431 2403 Other financial investment actvty (5239) 9022 15163 60593 578995 Misc. durable goods merch whlsl (4239) 1697 2402 849 1318 Architectural/engineering svc (5413) 7516 11811 1900 3851

113 Residential building constr (2361) 1566 2231 2840 4467 Other personal svc (8129) 6599 9188 5269 10472 Traveler acmdtn (7211) 1552 2602 4227 7848 Oces of real estate agents/brokers (5312) 6397 8230 2797 5595 Other personal svc (8129) 1483 1873 1592 2521 Residential building constr (2361) 6256 8736 6390 12037 Oil/gas extraction (2111) 1394 2045 7003 43202 Building equipment cntrctr (2382) 5601 8697 745 1395 Other miscellaneous mfg. (3399) 1341 1999 777 1376 Misc. durable goods merch whlsl (4239) 5389 8584 2198 4452 Nonresidential building constr (2362) 1210 1813 709 1134 Accounting/bookkeeping svc (5412) 4968 7101 2953 14982 Other fabricated metal prod mfg. (3329) 1171 1821 212 379 Health/personal care stores (4461) 4758 7120 1560 3780 Nondepository credit intrmd (5222) 1163 1667 1743 3700 Automobile dealers (4411) 4504 9005 1278 2759 Health/personal care stores (4461) 1110 1509 490 805 Nonresidential building constr (2362) 4371 7178 2022 4129 Oces of other health practitioners (6213) 1088 1294 721 1166 Traveler acmdtn (7211) 4207 8964 6645 22047 Architectural/engineering svc (5413) 1085 1581 435 743 Indie artists, writers, performers (7115) 4162 4886 1517 3131 Building equipment cntrctr (2382) 1076 1509 209 287 Other miscellaneous store retailers (4539) 3968 5910 1734 2985 Misc. nondrbl gds merch whlsl (4249) 1040 1567 563 981 Advertising, pr,/related svc (5418) 3922 5529 2162 4488 Machinery/equipment rental and leasing (5324) 1031 1453 2092 3834 Other miscellaneous mfg. (3399) 3569 6448 1705 4830 Other amusement/recreation indies (7139) 1007 1363 2285 4306 Auto repair/mntnce (8111) 3544 4937 1363 2507 Other miscellaneous store retailers (4539) 991 1363 609 891 Gasoline stations (4471) 3439 4889 886 1561

Notes: This table presents counts of the number of firms and owners by 4-digit industry, ranked by the level of S-corporation profits for firms owned by the top 0.1% and the top 1-0.1% respectively. The first column shows the number of S-corporations in 2014. The second column shows the number of S-corporation owners in 2014. The third and fourth columns show the same statistics, but for partnerships. We exclude firms in the residual category NAICS 5511 (Management of Companies and Enterprises), as in Section 2.1. Table J.4: Industry-Level Correlates of Top Pass-through and C-corporation Profits

Panel A. Top 1-0.1% Profits by Corporate Form Pass-through C-corp Pass-through C-corp Pass-through C-corp Pass-through C-corp Skill Share of Workers 0.57 0.22 0.67 0.33 0.67 0.33 0.50 0.33 (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.08) (0.11) (0.08) AverageWages 0.35 0.27 0.43 0.25 0.43 0.25 0.26 0.29 (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.08) Ocer Share of Wages 0.60 -0.21 0.75 -0.19 0.75 -0.19 0.80 -0.03 (0.05) (0.06) (0.04) (0.07) (0.04) (0.07) (0.06) (0.09) ShareUsingaComputer 0.36 0.33 0.41 0.39 0.41 0.39 0.20 0.60 (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.11) (0.09) Capital per Worker -0.20 0.76 -0.26 0.78 -0.26 0.78 -0.20 0.79 (0.06) (0.04) (0.06) (0.04) (0.07) (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) R&D -0.08 0.08 -0.16 0.17 -0.16 0.17 -0.11 0.00 (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.08) Concentration -0.21 0.17 -0.27 0.05 -0.27 0.05 -0.24 0.02 (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07)

Weight by Sales Yes Yes Weight by Profits Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Size >100M Yes Yes Yes Yes Control for 1-D NAICS Yes Yes

Panel B. Top 0.1% Profits by Corporate Form Pass-through C-corp Pass-through C-corp Pass-through C-corp Pass-through C-corp Skill Share of Workers 0.27 0.22 0.41 0.33 0.41 0.33 0.35 0.33 (0.04) (0.07) (0.05) (0.07) (0.05) (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) AverageWages 0.68 0.27 0.66 0.25 0.66 0.25 0.55 0.29 (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) (0.07) (0.05) (0.07) (0.05) (0.08) Ocer Share of Wages 0.43 -0.21 0.58 -0.19 0.58 -0.19 0.59 -0.03 (0.06) (0.06) (0.05) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.09) ShareUsingaComputer 0.50 0.33 0.54 0.39 0.54 0.39 0.37 0.60 (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.07) (0.10) (0.09) Capital per Worker 0.02 0.76 0.05 0.78 0.05 0.78 0.08 0.79 (0.06) (0.04) (0.07) (0.04) (0.07) (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) R&D -0.07 0.08 -0.14 0.17 -0.14 0.17 -0.11 0.00 (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.08) Concentration -0.09 0.17 -0.10 0.05 -0.09 0.05 -0.08 0.02 (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07)

Weight by Sales Yes Yes Weight by Profits Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Size >100M Yes Yes Yes Yes Control for 1-D NAICS Yes Yes

114 Notes: This table presents correlations among top owned firms. Panel A shows correlations for top-1-0.1%- owned pass-through businesses and all C-corporations. Panel B shows correlations for top-0.1%-owned pass- through businesses and C-corporations. The industry-level correlates are the following: Total profits are the 2000-2014 average level of profits in 2014 dollars. Top profits are total profits among firms with top 1-0.1% and top 0.1% owners. Skill share is the 2000-2014 average share of workers in a 4-digit industry who have at least some college in the CPS. Average wages is the 2014 top pass-through and C-corporation wages divided by the number of employees at top-owned firms and total C-corporation employees, respectively. Aggregate employee counts and payroll for C-corporations are taken from the County Business Patterns produced by the Census Bureau. Ocer share is the share of labor compensation (the sum of salaries and wages paid to employees, employee benefit programs such as health insurance, and contributions to pension and profit-sharing plans) that accrues to ocers. Specifically, on Form 1120 and 1120S it is line 7 divided by the sum of lines 7, 8, 17, and 18. We use the S-corporation ocer share for partnerships, as Form 1065 does not divide ocer compensation and labor compensation. Share using a computer is the share of 2000– 2014 average share of workers who use a computer as part of their role, following Autor, Levy and Murnane (2003). Capital per worker is total book value of depreciable assets less accumulated depreciation divided by aggregate W-2 payees. Capital is measured as the average for all S-corporations and C-corporations respectively in the IRS SOI corporate sample between 2000 and 2014, weighted to represent the population. Aggregate W-2 payees is measured directly for the population of S-corporations. R&D is the industry’s average share of total R&D expenditure in Compustat between 2000 and 2014. Concentration is the sum of the sales shares of the four largest S and C corporations relative to total S + C industry sales, averaged over the years 2000-2014. Weight by Sales denotes that total sales by corporate form are used to weigh the correlation regression. Weight by Profits denotes that total profits by corporate form are used to weigh the correlation regression. Size > 100M restricts the sample to industries with at least $100M in total profits, with the restriction applied separately for each corporate form.

115 Table J.5: Construction of the Owner Deaths Analysis Sample

Step Sample Size at End of Step Distinct firms 2005-2010 9,489,180

Restrict to firms with one owner 349,039 death 2005-2010

Restrict to dying owners in the 64,589 top 1%

Restrict to dying owners under 18,933 age 65

Restrict to firms with t 1sales 4,676 >$100K and positive sales in [t 4,t 1] Restrict to firms with at least 3,273 one pre-period worker

Restrict to firms with dying 2,496 owner’s ownership share 20% Match to at least one 2,436 counterfactual firm

Notes: This table lists the sample sizes at each of eight steps in the construction of the top-1% owner deaths analysis sample, detailed in Section 3.1. The analysis sample of million-dollar-earner deaths is a subset of the top-1% sample. The sample construction begins with all distinct pass-throughs in the 2005-2010 subset of our linked-firm-owner data. The second step restricts to “owner-death” firms: those with one firm- owner-year observation in our main sample 2001-2014 in which the owner died in the year of or immediately following the observation, as well as to firms in which that one firm-owner-year observation lies in a year t 2005 2010. The third step restricts to firms with dying owners in the top 1% of the t 1 U.S. fiscal income2 distribution. The fourth step restricts to dying owners aged under 65 on December 31 of year t.The fifth step further restricts to firms with at least $100,000 in sales in 2014 dollars in t 1 and positive sales in all years [t 4,t 1]. The sixth step restricts to firms with positive employment in some year [t 4,t 1]. The seventh step restricts to firms in which the dying owner had an ownership share of at least 20%. The eighth step restricts attention to owner-death firms with at least one match to a “counterfactual” firm that met the same [t 4,t 1] firm requirements, match the owner-death firm on organizational form (S-corporation or partnership), three-digit industry, and t 1 sales decile, and have a year-t owner who matches the dying owner on t 1 income bin and five-year age bin.

116 Table J.6: Construction of the Inferred Owner Retirement Analysis Sample

Step Sample Size at End of Step Distinct firms 2005-2010 9,489,180

Restrict to firms with an inferred 191,656 retirement

Restrict to firms with top 1% 21,616 owner in t 1 Restrict to firms with t 1sales 18,115 >$100K and positive sales in [t 4,t 1] Restrict to firms with at least 18,115 one pre-period worker

Restrict to firms with working 16,827 owner’s ownership share 20% Match to at least one 16,548 counterfactual firm

Notes: This table lists the sample sizes at each of eight steps in the construction of the top-1% owner retirements analysis sample, detailed in Section 3.2. The analysis sample of million-dollar-earner retirements is a subset of the top-1% sample. The sample construction begins with all distinct pass-throughs in the 2005-2010 subset of our linked-firm-owner data. The second step restricts to “owner-retirement” firms: those with at least one owner receiving a W-2 [t 4,t 1] and no owner receiving a W-2 [t, t+1] while still have positive sales, with t in [2005, 2010]. The third step restricts to firms with retiring owners in the top 1% of the t 1 U.S. fiscal income distribution. The fourth step further restricts to firms with at least $100,000 in sales in 2014 dollars in t 1 and positive sales in all years [t 4,t 1]. The fifth step restricts to firms with positive employment in some year [t 4,t 1]. The sixth step restricts to firms in which the dying owner had an ownership share of at least 20%. The seventh step restricts attention to owner-retirement firms with at least one match to a “counterfactual” firm that met the same [t 4,t 1] firm requirements, match the owner-retirement firm on organizational form (S-corporation or partnership), three-digit industry, and t 1 sales decile, and have a highest-earning year-t owner in the same t 1 income bin as the highest-earning year-t owner who received a W-2 in the retirement firm and also in the same five-year age bin. There is no age restriction in the owner retirements sample. The restriction on pre-period workers does not reduce the sample size by construction.

117 Table J.7: Impact of Owner Death on Firm Outcomes

Profits per Firm pre-period worker survival ($/worker) (pp) Profits per pre-period worker ($/worker) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) A. Top 1% Owner Death Impact -12,920 -0.182 -7,001 -9,667 -15,572 3,011 -12,087 (1,831) (0.009) (2,108) (2,373) (2,702) (2,112) (1,961)

Surviving firms only X Minority owner X Majority owner X Death before 65 X X X X X X Death after 75 X S-corporations only X

Observations 2,609,973 2,609,973 958,158 910,899 1,699,074 114,021 2,358,207 Owner deaths 2,436 2,436 1,305 1,094 1,342 1,601 2,093 R2 0.004 0.064 0.001 0.001 0.006 0.000 0.003

Meanofcounterfactualfirms 27,258 0.889 28,290 26,162 28,151 14,911 25,287 Dying owners ownership % 65.0% 65.0% 56.7% 39.7% 85.7% 58.5% 67.9% Preferred percentage impact -72.9% -31.6% -43.7% -93.1% -64.6% 34.5% -70.4%

B. Top 0.1% Owner Death Impact -29,543 -0.205 -16,625 -11,761 -43,206 8,506 -32,584 (10,582) (0.023) (12,916) (11,698) (16,382) (5,662) (12,597)

Surviving firms only X Minority owner X Majority owner X Death before 65 X X X X X X Death after 75 X S-corporations only X

Observations 194,787 194,787 84,717 72,990 121,797 41,661 180,153 Owner deaths 435 435 213 189 246 496 378 R2 0.005 0.071 0.001 0.001 0.010 0.001 0.005

Mean of counterfactual firms 48,221 0.878 53,194 41,948 53,040 19,273 50,955 Dying owners ownership % 66.4% 66.4% 58.9% 40.1% 86.6% 60.2% 68.7% Preferred percentage impact -92.3% -35.1% -53.1% -69.9% -94.1% 73.4% -93.1%

Notes: This table repeats Table 4A for the (fiscal-income) top 1% and top 0.1%. See the notes to that table for details.

118 Table J.8: Impact of Inferred Owner Retirements on Firm Outcomes

Profits per Firm pre-period worker survival ($/worker) (pp) Profits per pre-period worker ($/worker) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) A. Inferred Top 1% Owner Retirement Impact -17,150 -0.283 -9,280 -11,799 -19,088 -17,806 (1,027) (0.004) (1,329) (1,849) (1,228) (1,052)

Surviving firms only X Minority owner X Majority owner X S-corporations only X

Observations 1,432,179 1,432,179 693,306 371,043 1,061,136 1,361,682 Owner retirements 16,548 16,548 9,150 4,400 12,148 15,485 R2 0.005 0.122 0.002 0.003 0.006 0.006

Meanofcounterfactualfirms 37,780 0.930 40,878 33,808 39,219 38,498 Retiring owners ownership % 76.2% 76.2% 76.5% 41.0% 88.9% 77.6% Preferred percentage impact -59.6% -40.0% -29.7% -85.2% -54.7% -59.6%

B. Inferred Top 0.1% Owner Retirement Impact -45,861 -0.265 -24,104 -37,020 -49,112 -48,288 (7,286) (0.009) (8,845) (13,993) (8,535) (7,334)

Surviving firms only X Minority owner X Majority owner X S-corporations only X

Observations 255,897 255,897 122,715 65,682 190,215 246,024 Owner retirements 3,176 3,176 1,763 854 2,322 2,988 R2 0.003 0.106 0.002 0.002 0.004 0.004

Meanofcounterfactualfirms 84,573 0.921 95,282 74,282 88,359 84,478 Retiring owners ownership % 75.6% 75.6% 76.5% 40.2% 88.6% 76.8% Preferred percentage impact -71.7% -38.0% -33.0% -123.9% -62.7% -74.5%

Notes: This table repeats Table 4B for the (fiscal-income) top 1% and top 0.1%. See the notes to that table for details.

119 Table J.9: Dollar-Weighted Impact of Owner Deaths and Retirements on Firm Profits

Pre-period profit weighted Equal weight log pre-profits Full Sample <50M in <10M in weight pre-period pre-period profits profits (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) A. Owner Deaths Impact -12,920.0 -18,247.3 -35,421.1 -31,033.8 -22,033.3 (1,831.2) (2,198.0) (8,166.8) (7,338.7) (4,930.7)

Meanofcounterfactualfirms 27,068.4 33,465.5 64,188.2 62,418.5 50,092.9 Dying owners ownership % 65.0% 64.8% 57.4% 57.1% 60.1% Percentageimpactinsample -73.4% -84.2% -96.1% -87.1% -73.2%

Scenarios to bound e↵ects for large firms Low impact (% impact = 0) -62.4% -38.1%

120 Medium impact (% impact = .5) -76.6% -62.1% Highimpact(%impact=1) -90.8% -86.1%

B. Owner Retirements Impact -17,150.3 -26,525.9 -83,798.2 -74,484.4 -52,499.9 (1,027.0) (1,288.2) (11,761.0) (9,467.5) (4,124.1)

Meanofcounterfactualfirms 36,642.6 50,120.7 102,842.2 96,658.6 86,082.5 Retiring owners ownership % 76.2% 75.9% 69.3% 69.3% 70.2% Percentageimpactinsample -61.5% -69.8% -117.7% -111.1% -86.9%

Scenarios to bound e↵ects for large firms Low impact (% impact = 0) -79.6% -45.2% Medium impact (% impact = .5) -93.8% -69.2% Highimpact(%impact=1) -108.0% -93.2%

Notes: This table estimates the e↵ects of owner deaths and retirements under alternative weighting specifications. Panel A and B use the owner death and retirement samples, repectively. Column 1 replicates the equal-weighted result from Column 8 of Table 4. Column 2 weighs all owner death pairs in our analysis sample by the log of their mean pre-period profits (i.e., mean profits from t 4tot 1). Column 3 uses the level of mean pre-period profits as weights. Columns 4 and 5 also dollar-weight using pre-period profits, but restrict the sample to firms with average pre-period profit below $50M and $10M, respectively. The mean of counterfactual firms is the pre-period profit weighted mean four years after owner death, scaled by the ratio of average pre-period profits of the counterfactual firm to average pre-period profits of firms whose owner died. The ownership share of dying owners is measured in the year before owner death and is also the pre-period profit weighted mean. Table J.10: CEO and Entrepreneurial Income, Own Firm Size, and Reference Firm Size

ln (Total compensation) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Top 1000 Top 500

Panel A. Gabaix and Landier (2008)

ln(Firmsize) 0.21*** .37*** .37*** .26*** .38*** .32*** .23*** (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.06) (0.04) (0.04) (0.07) ln(Firmsizeof#250) .72*** .66*** .78*** .73*** .73*** .84*** (0.053) (0.054) (0.052) (0.084) (0.085) (0.080)

Observations 9,777 7,936 7,936 7,936 4,156 4,156 4,156 R2 .439 .23 .29 .6 .2 .29 .63 Year fixed e↵ects X Industry fixed e↵ects XX X Firm fixed e↵ects XX

Panel B. Estimates in Smith, Yagan, Zidar and Zwick (2018) sample

ln(Firmsize) 0.80*** 0.78*** 0.79*** 0.82*** 0.62*** 0.72*** 0.78*** (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04) ln(Firmsizeof#250) 0.27*** 0.30*** 0.23*** 0.42*** 0.34*** 0.31*** (0.05) (0.04) (0.04) (0.08) (0.06) (0.05)

Observations 13,445 13,445 13,445 13,445 6,654 6,654 6,654 R2 0.558 0.124 0.477 0.875 0.091 0.468 0.872 Year fixed e↵ects X Industry fixed e↵ects XX X Firm fixed e↵ects XX Notes: This table replicates Table I and Table II in Gabaix and Landier (2008) using the full population of S-corporations and partnerships. Panel A reproduces the results from Gabaix and Landier (2008) for the sake of comparability. We regress the log of entrepreneurial income (i.e., pass-through income plus wages from their firm) in year t on the log of the firm size in year t 1, and the log of the 250th firm size in year t 1. Gabaix and Landier use a di↵erent measure of firm size. Their baseline measure of firm size uses total market value (debt plus equity), which we present in Columns 2-7, but their Table I shows similar results using sales as a measure of firm size. Since we cannot measure total market value for pass-throughs, we measure firm size using total sales across all specifications. Firm size information is defined in year t 1. Following Gabaix and Landier, we select each year the top n 500, 1000 largest firms. All nominal quantities are converted into 2014 dollars. Industries are defined at2 the{ 4-digit} NAICS level. Section 1 describes our data. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses (⇤⇤⇤p<0.01,⇤⇤ p<0.05,⇤⇤ p<0.1).

121 Table J.11: Entrepreneurial Income, Own Firm Size, and Reference Firm Size

ln (Total compensation) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Top 1000 Top 500

Panel A. S-corporations in Smith, Yagan, Zidar and Zwick (2018) sample

ln(Firmsize) 0.88*** 0.83*** 0.87*** 0.95*** 0.81*** 0.87*** 0.86*** ln(Firmsizeof#250) 0.32*** 0.29*** 0.21*** 0.38*** 0.25*** 0.26*** (0.05) (0.04) (0.04) (0.07) (0.06) (0.06)

Observations 13,859 13,859 13,859 13,859 6,892 6,892 6,892 R2 0.490 0.157 0.396 0.833 0.147 0.422 0.848 Year fixed e↵ects X Industry fixed e↵ects XX X Firm fixed e↵ects XX

Panel B. Partnerships in Smith, Yagan, Zidar and Zwick (2018) sample

ln(Firmsize) 0.77*** 0.91*** 0.76*** 0.88*** 0.72*** 0.67*** 0.75*** ln(Firmsizeof#250) -0.05 0.26*** 0.11*** -0.00 0.37*** 0.20*** (0.05) (0.04) (0.03) (0.07) (0.05) (0.04)

Observations 12,395 12,395 12,395 12,395 6,233 6,233 6,233 R2 0.655 0.168 0.585 0.900 0.103 0.573 0.899 Year fixed e↵ects X Industry fixed e↵ects XX X Firm fixed e↵ects XX Notes: This table replicates Table J.10 for the full population of S-corporations and partnerships separately. See the notes of Table J.10 for details.

122 Table J.12: Changes in Entrepreneurial Income and Reference Firm Size

GabaixandLandier(2008) Smith,Yagan,Zidar,andZwick(2018) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) S-corporations Partnerships Top 1000 Top 500 Top 1000 Top 500

D.ln(Firmsize) 1.14*** (0.28) D.5ln(Firmsizeof#250) 1.04*** 1.23*** 0.81*** 0.83*** (0.08) (0.13) (0.11) (0.15) 123 D.10ln(Firmsizeof#250) 0.16 -0.18 0.20 -0.19 (0.21) (0.29) (0.26) (0.30)

Observations 34 6,283 2,367 3,087 1,169 4,388 1,460 2,377 837 R2 .29 0.031 0.000 0.040 0.000 0.011 0.000 0.011 0.000 Notes: This table estimates the e↵ect of lagged firm size changes on log entrepreneurial income for the full population of S-corporations and partnerships. Column 1 reproduces analogous results for log CEO pay, which are estimated in Table IIII of Gabaix and Landier (2008). Gabaix and Landier use a di↵erent measure of firm size. Their baseline measure of firm size uses total market value (debt plus equity), which we present in Column 1, but their Table 1 shows similar results using sales as a measure of firm size. Since we cannot measure total market value for pass-throughs, we measure firm size using total sales across all specifications. Firm size information is defined in year t 1. Following Gabaix and Landier, we select each year the top n 500, 1000 largest S-corporations and partnerships. D.5 and D.10 denote five- and ten-year lags, respectively. Section 1 2{ } describes our data. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses (⇤⇤⇤p<0.01,⇤⇤ p<0.05,⇤⇤ p<0.1).