<<

Omitogun, O. (2018). Investigating the Crowding Out Effect of Expenditure on Private Investment. Journal of Competitiveness, 10(4), 136–150. https://doi.org/10.7441/joc.2018.04.09

INVESTIGATING THE CROWDING OUT EFFECT OF GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE ON PRIVATE INVESTMENT ▪ Olawunmi Omitogun

Abstract This study investigates the crowding out effect of government expenditure on private invest- ment in Nigeria using annual data spanning from 1981-2015. The research is shaped by the high level of competition that investors are exposed to in the economy. Competitiveness is also supported by government plans to reduce investment burden by increasing expenditure in all strategic sectors of the economy. The present paper adds to the existing literature by investi- gating the effect of disaggregated government expenditure on private investment in Nigeria. The estimation techniques of the study include pre-and post-estimation, including descriptive statistics, correlation matrix, a unit root test and econometric estimation using the Auto Regres- sive Distributed Lag (ARDL) method. Government capital expenditures are estimated margin- ally, while recurrent expenditures are estimated in terms of elasticity, as the variables (recurrent expenditures) show a strict long tail to the right. It was observed in general that the effect of government expenditure on private investment depends on the components of the expenditure. Some were found to crowd out private investment while some crowd in private investment. This implies that not all government expenditure is channeled in such a way that it attracts private investment in the economy. It is therefore recommended that the policymakers should take into consideration the existence of private investors in expenditure plans.

Keywords: Recurrent Expenditure, Capital Expenditure, Private Investment, ARDL JEL Classification: H3

Received: March, 2018 1st Revision: June, 2018 Accepted: October, 2018

1. INTRODUCTION In recent years, a major discussion in has been taking place concerning the link be- tween and economic performance (Basar & Temurlenk, 2007). Recently, the challenges faced by the most developed economies in terms of and economic in- stances have been sparked by an increase in public spending (Bom, 2017). Such is also the case in developing countries such as Nigeria (Muhammad et al., 2012). This pattern of expenditure largely determines how private investors are motivated to invest more in the economy. Mah- moudzadeh et al., (2013) and Bom (2017) have confirmed that the of an economy

136 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 136 1.12.2018 11:18:06 determines the existence of investors in such economy. Studies have argued both in support as well as against increases in government spending. Some see an increase in government spending as a means of increasing economic activities through investment in basic needs (e.g. infrastructure) that attract private investors to invest more in an economy (see Mahmoudzadeh et al., 2013; Basar and Temurlenk (2007) and Nwosa et al., 2013). Some of these studies have also submitted their arguments in support of the neoclassical theory of investment, i.e. that the is determined by the level of savings, which has a con- nection to the pattern of expenditure in an economy with the assumption of (Sineviciene & Railiene, 2015). On the other hand, others have argued from the Keynesian view that government expenditure pattern complements private investments with a low interest rate (Fujii et al., 2013; Ferria & Voia, 2015; and Sineviciene, 2015). These outlooks are based on the different approaches as well as the time frame used to make conclusions. The majority of the studies used the Vector Auto-regressive Approach (VAR) and Error Correction Method (ECM) to analyze their findings. Nigeria has been faced several challenges in recent years in terms of its budget status. The country has been running on a budget deficit over several years, during which no option other than to consider in- ternal or external debt to finance the budget was possible. In this process, the question is “Does the pattern of financing or source of spending crowd in or out private investment in line with what the respective theory says?” This study therefore differs from previous ones by investigat- ing the crowding out effect of government expenditure pattern as a fiscal policy tool on private investment using the Auto-regressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) approach based on the nature of the pre-estimation test results covering the period 1981 to 2015. This study is also shaped by the effect that competitiveness government fiscal policy causes among various private investors in the economy. Private investors are challenged to re-strategize in order to remain in the , as most government policies are tailored towards increasing the number of investors in the economy, which aids competitiveness. The rest of the paper is divided into four sections. Section two contains the literature review, while the source of data, methodology and model specification is presented in section three; sec- tion four presents the analytical framework and discussion of results, with section five devoted to the conclusion and recommendations.

2. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND This section presents a theoretical and empirical understanding of the impact of government expenditure on private investment. Neoclassical theory advocates that an economy attains full employment and an increase in interest rates as its reserve ratio falls. According to this theory, there is either an increase in government expenditure, or investment crowds-out private invest- ment. Contrary to neoclassical thought, Keynesian theory is of the view that an increase in government spending facilitates a complement private investment, and the interest rate impact on investment is very low. In contrary to the neoclassical and the Keynesian approaches, the Ricardian Equivalence hypothesis states that there is no nexus between private investment and government spending pattern. This is because most government spending is a result of revenue

137

joc4-2018-v2.indd 137 1.12.2018 11:18:06 from tax, and when there is budget deficit, individuals still maintain their levels of consumption, savings and investment behavior in the economy. On the empirical front, Ho (2001) has confirmed that a significant substitution for private con- sumption by government is the spending which exists in the OECD countries, i.e. when the presence of real disposable income precludes the permanent income hypothesis for Keynesian expansionary fiscal policy. Sineviciene & Railiene (2015) have argued from their findings that in EU countries government size and the tax burden cannot be treated as the only detrimental factors for private investment. They contend that economic development is better explained by the differences in private investment level than by government size and the tax burden. Thus, the level of private investment depends on the particular countries’ economic development. In Fiji, Narayan (2004) noted that government investment crowded in private investment from 1950 to 1975, while between 1976 and 2001, there was a weak link between government spending and private investment. Basar & Temurlenk (2007) revealed that the pattern of government spend- ing in the economy of Turkey was found to have a small negative impact on private investment for the period after 1980. Majumber (2007) noted a crowding-in effect of public borrowings on private investment in Bangladesh. In South Africa, Kollaparambil & Nicolau (2011) noted that public spending indirectly influences private investment through the . Mahmoudzadeh et al. (2013) stated that for developed and developing countries the elasticity of private investment to government financing is positive in both developed and developing countries, but the enhancing effect is greater in the developed countries. The elasticity of private investment to government is negative in both groups, but the retarding effect is greater in the developed countries. In addition, it was observed that budget deficit has a negative and positive impact on private investment in developed and developing countries respectively. In Pakistan between 1974 and 2010, results by Rahman, Ullah & Jebran (2015) indicate a crowd- ing-in effect of expenditure on agriculture, health, and transport and communication along with on private investment, i.e. a crowding-out effect of community services and debt serving on private investment in the long-run and an insignificant positive and negative impact of education and defense respectively on private investment. Using panel data analysis for the economies of Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and Slovenia, Sineviciene (2015) has revealed that the impact of increasing government expenditure on private investment is low, but the negative impact dominates, except in the case of Bulgaria, where the impact of increasing private investment on government expenditure is very different than in the other analyzed countries. Using a fixed effect model for a panel data analysis of 5 selected West African countries (Ghana, Ivory Coast, Nigeria, Senegal and Sierra Leone), Omojolaibi et al. (2016) observed that a signifi- cant crowding-in effect of government capital expenditure and tax revenue exists while non-tax revenue showed a crowding-out effect. Recurrent expenditure and external debt also showed crowding out effects, but these were insignificant. The accelerator effect of output growth was also found to be insignificant across the countries over the time period. Dreger & Reimers (2016) explored the long-run relationship between public and private invest- ment in the euro area. In contrast to previous studies, a stock-flow approach was applied to con- trol for the different orders of integration between the stock and flow variables as well as panel econometric techniques allowing for international spillovers. Overall, the researchers noted that

138 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 138 1.12.2018 11:18:07 lack of public investment may have restricted private investment and GDP growth in the euro area. Their results have strong implications for the future direction of fiscal programs to combat the euro area debt crisis. Ferria & Voia (2015) noted for the economy of Canada that government expenditure between 1870 and 2011 showed an inverted U-shaped relationship with private output. The findings re- vealed that while government size complements the growth of the Canadian private investment in its early stages, recent experience is more consistent with the hypothesis that increases in government size have decreased rather than increased private per capita output. Regarding the Japanese economy, Fujii et al. (2013) submitted results that public investment confers different effects, both quantitatively and qualitatively, in individual sectors. This implies that public investment reaps different benefits in different sectors and that it can bring then unfavorable effect of resource misallocation in other sectors. In Nigeria, Dada (2013) observed that government expenditure initiates private consumption and output in the long-run. Government expenditure on education, health, and social security crowded in private consumption, while other components such as government spending on ad- ministration, construction, agriculture, transport and communication crowded out private con- sumption. The short-run result revealed that the variables used do not return to equilibrium after a short-run deviation in the private consumption equation. Results by Nwosa et al. (2013) show that specifically recurrent and government final consumption expenditure crowds in private in- vestment, while capital expenditure had a crowding out effect on private investment. Awolaja et al. (2015) suggest that government should give more priority to sectoral government investment expenditure rather than aggregate government investment expenditure. Of equal importance is the great need for government policy on investment spending to favour sectors that stimulate private sector capital formation. Apere (2014) concluded from his findings that the impact of domestic debt on private investment in Nigeria is linear and positive, and the application of the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is not possible in the case of Nigeria. Bello et al. (2012) indi- cate that effective macroeconomic management is needed to cushion the adverse effect of rising inflation on private investment. From these studies, conclusions were made which are a result of the relative approach, the period covered, and the series of variables used in the studies. This makes the present study differ in terms of method, time frame and data used. This study also argues in a different dimension then did existing studies considering the promotion of competition among private investors through government fiscal policies

3. RESEARCH OBJECTIVE, METHODOLOGY AND DATA The study investigates the crowding out effect of government expenditure pattern as a fiscal policy tool on private investment. In order to formulate the model and methodology for this study, Jogenson’s neoclassical theory of investment was applied. The neoclassical theory of investment of Jogenson (1963, 1967, and 1971) is based on the opti- mization problem of a firm. It is argued that profit maximization of each period will yield an

139

joc4-2018-v2.indd 139 1.12.2018 11:18:07 optimal capital stock result, assuming the production function to be written conventionally as;

( ) = F[ , ]= (1) ఈ ଵିఈ ௧ ௧ ௧ whereȆܻ (t) = P(t) Yܭ(t) Y isܮ(t) firm– sܣ(t)� Ioutput(t)ܮ – w(t) Lat(t) the time, K is capital at the time,(2) L(t) is labour at the time. Assuming = F[ , ]= (1) profit(*) Įmaximization, the current value of a firm, V(0) is written as; K = P Y/ c ఈ ଵିఈ (3) ௧ ௧ ௧ Ȇܻ (t) = P(t)ܭ Yܮ(t) – sܣ(t)� I(t)ܮ – w(t) L(t) (2) I = ( ) (4) * Į (at the time, P (t) is price of output at the time, (3) s (t) is price of capital at the time, and w(t כ ΠK (t)= ௉is� P௒ profitY/ c = F[ , ]= (1) (ݐ � ߬ (5 ܭ Į<஼ െ( ), represents wages atఈ ଵିఈthe time. To obtain the optimal capital stock (K) and investment function, I =௧ ௧ ௧( ) (4) eqnȆܻ (t) =(1) P(t) isܭ Ydifferentiatedܮ(t) – sܣ(t)� I(t)ܮ – w(t) partially, L(t) i.e.; (2) (6) כ ௉�௒ ( ) = F[ , ]= (1) (ݐ �ିఙ߬ (5 ܭ Į<஼ Įെכ* , K௜� = P Y/ ௜c� ௜ � ௜ � ఈ ଵିఈ (3) ܭ( ௧ =) ߮ ܲ௧ ܻ௧ ܥ Ȇܻ (t) = P(t)ܭ Yܮ(t) – sܣ(t)� I(t)ܮ – w(t) L(t) (2) ௣� [ , ] (6) WhereI (=௜) �= F K* - (optimal= ) capital output is a function of P (4)–(1) price of output and cost of capital, (c). (Į ିఙ (7 = כ*ܫ (௜ � ఈ ଵିఈ (3 כ K =௉� P௒ Y/ ௜c� Therefore,௜௧� ௧ investment௧ ௜� results from the change in the optimal capital between two periods; ܮ �ܣ ܥ ܻܮ ܲכܭଶ =)஼ ߮)ܭ ܻ (t) –ݐ �s(t)߬ I(t) – w(t) L(t) (5)(2)ܭȆ,௜� (t)Į<= P(t)െ௧ Y ܫ ௣� οܭ (8) I =*௜ � Į ( ) (4) Kܫ =௉ �P௒ Y/ c (7) (3) (ଶ ௜ � ଷ ௜ �+ ௜ � (6 כ௜� ଵ ௜� (9) ܷ + ܥοܻ + ߮ οܲ െ ߮ οכ ଶ =஼ ߮ܫ -to ]ݐthe=�ିఙ ߬neoclassical approach, the accelerator (5)(1) theory, which related to Keynesian ap,ܭ Į<= F[െ௧(כ Contrary,௜(� ܫ ௜� οܭ ௜� ௜� ௜� (8) I ܭ (௜=� =) ߮ଵ ܲ ௜ܻ�( ܥ ଶ)ఈ ௜ ଵିఈ� ଷ ௜ � ௞ ௜ 𝑖 ௜ � (4) proaches,ܫ ௧ =௉� ௒߮ οܻ௧ assumed௧+ ߮ οܲ fixed+ ߮ pricesܥ σin݇ߜ the ܨ investment� + ߤ function. (10) Therefore; (௜– � w (t) L ଷ (t) ௜ � ௜ � (6)(2 ܮ (t)ଶ� I (t)ܣ� – sכ(t)ܮY௜ ܭȆܻ௜�(t)௣�= P(t)ଵ ܫ( )==஼ F߮[ οܻ, +]= ߮ οܲ െ ߮ οܥ + + ܷ ( ) = F [ , ] = (9) (1) (1) (ݐ �ିఙ௝௝ ߬௧� ௞௞ ௧� ௧ (5 ܭ ௜௧Į<� െכܫ , ܲ�* ==Į ߙ + σ ߚ ܺ + σ � ܨ � + ߤ (7) (11) K௜�= P Y/ c௜� ௜ � ௜ � ఈ ଵିఈ ఈ (3)ଵିఈ (ଶ ௜� ଷ ௜ � ௞ ௧ ௜ 𝑖 ௧ ௜ � ௧ (1 =ܥ[௧, ௜ܻ�௧ܲכ௜(ଶ�௧) =) F ߮[ଵ)ܭ Ȇܻܫ (t)== P(t)߮ ܭοܻ Yܮ(t) +– s߮ܣ(t)� Iοܲ(t)ܮ – w+(t) ߮ L(t)ܥ σ ݇ߜ ܻ ܨ � + ܭ ߤ ܮ ܣ � (10) ܮ(2) ௜�௧ ௧௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ Ȇ (t) ௧ = P(t) ௧ Y (t) – ௧ s (t) I (t) (6) – w (t) L(t) (2) Iܲܫ is�௣ �investment,=οܭ ߚ + ܥ�ܦ Y+ ఈis ܥܧܵ ଵିఈoutput.+ ܥܵܵ + ܥܴܶ + ܺ + ߤ (8) (12) ௧௜� ௧ ௧ (௧ Į ( ିఙ௝௝ )௧� ௞௞ ௧ � ௧ * Į (4כ*ܫ= I KȆܻܲ௜�(t)� == P P(t) ߙY/ܭ+ Y௜c � ܮ (t)σ ௜ � – ߚ ௜s �ܣ (t) ܺ � I (t) ܮ+ – w σ (t) � L (t) ܨ � + ߤ (7) (11)(3)(2) ܭ௜�௧௉=�௒ ߮ଵ௧ܲ ௜ܻ� ܥ ௧ଶ ௜� ௧ ଷ ௜� ௧ ௜�K =௧ P Y/௧ c ௧ (3) 𝑅�+++ ܷ 𝑅� the+ ܺoptimal+ ߤ capital (9) model equation (3) to account for a ܥ𝑅� +et ߮al.+οܲ (2016) 𝑅�െ ߮+ transformedοכ +οܻכଶ� ==) ߮ ߚ)ܫܲ Omojolaibi ݐ � ߬ ܭ ௜�*௣� ஼ Įെ௧ panel,KܲPIܫ �௧Į<== οܭP dataߚY/௧+ +c characteristics ܥ( � ܦ ௧ + )PI ܥܧܵ + ௧ + as; ܥܵܵ ௧ + ܥܴܶ ௧ + + ܺ ௧ + ߤ ௧ (8) (12)(5)(3) + CSS + Iܫ ௜ܫ=�௜ �= ߮ଵοܻ௜� + ߮ଶοܲ ௜ � + ߮ ଷ ܥ ௜ � σ ݇ߜ I௞ = ܨ � ௜ 𝑖 + ߤ ௜ � ( ) (10) (4) (4) =௉�௒ ௣ ௝ భ ௝ మ (7) ௝య כ � ଶ ௜� ଷ ௜� ௜� ௉�௒כ௜� ଵ ௜ ௧ ଴_௧ ௤ୀ� ௧ଵ ௧𝑡 ௧ ௤ୀ_ � ଶ௧ + ௧𝑡௧ ௧௤ୀ � ଷ௧ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� (13)ସ ௧𝑡 𝐼� (9) (6)(4) σ ߚ ݊ܫ 𝐼� 𝑅� + ܺ σ + ߚߤ ܷ + ݊ܫ + + 𝑅� ߚ ܥοܻ+σ 𝑅�(+ ߮ߚ + )οܲ 𝑅� െ ߮ σ + οכଶ=� ==஼ ߮ ܿߚ ܫIܲ (ݐ � ߬ (5) (5 ܭ σݐ �௝௝ ߬௧� ௝σఱ ௞௞ ௧� ,௧ Į<஼ െܭ ௜� ௝௧రĮ<െ௧, (� + ߤ (8) (11ܨ ߚିఙܺ + � כ + ௒ ߙܭ௉=�ο כ�ܲܫ PI௜௜�௤ୀ� =� ହ[ଵ +௜,�௜�௜�] ௜௧�𝑡ଶ PI ௜� ௤ୀ+� ଷ଺ ௜�௧𝑡 ௧௞ ௜𝑖+ ௜� + CSS + ܭܫσ( )===஼ ߚF ߮߮ οܻܲܫ݊𝐼�ܻ+ܥ= ߮ +οܲ σ+ ߮ ߚ ܥ ܺ σ ݇ߜ ߝ ܨ � + ߤ (10) (1) the௣ݐ � distribution߬ PI ௝+భ parameter and +the௝మ constantCES (5) elasticity+ ௝య substitution+ between capital ܭφ, ( andĮ<) = െσ +is ௜� ௧ ଵ_௧ ௜� ௧ଶ ఈ ௜ �ଵିఈ ௧ ଷ _ ௜ �+ ௧ + ௜ � ௧ ௧ ௧ (6) (6) ܫܲ�௧௧௣=�= ߮ ߚ଴οܻ௧+ ܥ௧+௤ୀ௣� �ܦ߮ ଵ+οܲ ௧ܥܧܵ𝑡െ ߮+௤ୀοܥ ܥܵܵ� ௝ଶ+భ + ܷ ܥܴܶ௧𝑡+ ܺ ௤ୀ+ � ߤ௝ మ ଷ (9) (12)௧𝑡 ௤ୀ௝య� (13)ସ ௧𝑡 𝐼� net investmentσ ߚ component, the researchers݊ܫ𝐼�௧ σ+ onߚ the+݊ܫ௧ ܿand σlabourିఙ௝௝ ߚ ௧respectively.� σ௞௞ ߚ௧ �Concentratingכstock ௧ 𝑡 ௤ୀ �ିఙ ଷ (11)(2)௧𝑡 ௤ୀ (14)� ସ ௧𝑡 כ � ௤ୀ +� ߤଶ ܨ(௝wσఱ(t)௧𝑡 �L(t –+ ܮ(t)ܺ� Iଵ(t)ܣt)σ ௤ୀ–ߚ s�)ܮ Y +ܭȆܻܲ�(t)௝௜ర� =௧ P(t) ߙ οܲܫ௜�ర=� Ԃ ௜ � σ ௜ � ௜ � ߩ ο ܫ݊ ఱ σ ߩ ο ܥ ௜ � � ܦ ௜ � σ ௜ � ௜ � ߩ (7) (6) σ ߩ οܥܵܵ specifyܫ ܭܲσ(௜��௝௤ୀ௧===)� ߚ߮ ߮ହߚଵ ௧thatοܻܲܫ݊+௜𝐼�ܻ� 𝑅� +investmentܥ ௧߮𝑡௧ଶ+οܲ ௜𝑅�σ� +௤ୀ௝ ௧� ߮component+ߚଷ଺ܥ 𝑅�௜ܺ� ௧𝑡௧σ+݇ߜ ߝ𝑅�௧௞ܭ ( ܨ � ௧= ௜) 𝑖+ is ߮ + ܺ equal ܲ௧ ߤ + ௜ ܻ� ߤ ܥ ௧ to the (10) change in desired capital stock. + + ఙ௧𝑡 PI௤ୀ� +଺ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 + ௧ CESି + כ௤ୀ� =Įହכ*ଶ Kσ௜� ௣௧=� PߩY/௧ο௧ ܫ݊ c 𝐼� ௧ + σ ௧ ߩ οܺ ௧ � ݁ �௣ ௧݉ � ௧ ߝ ௧ (3) PIܲ௜�� = ߚ ++௜� ܥ௜��௜ܦ� +PI ܥܧܵ+ + ܥܵܵభ + ܥܴܶ ++ ܺ + ߤమ (12) + య CSSRSS ++ ܭܫ( ௜௧�=)οܭ ߮ ܲ ܻ ௣ܥ ௝௝ ௧� ௞௞ ௧௝� ௧ ௜ � ௝ (8) ௝ ܫ σ σ భ + +మ య (14) ܲ� ==௧ ߙ + σ ௣ ௤ୀ ߚ � ܺ ଵ + ௧ 𝑡� ௝ భ ܨ �σ ௤ୀ +� ߤ ଶ ܫ = ௧ 𝑡 ௝ మ σ ௤ୀ � ଷ (7) (11) ௧ 𝑡 σ௝ ௝ య ௤ୀ � ସ ௧ 𝑡 (7) οܲ௧௣ర�� ଴Ԃ_௧ ௧ߩଵ ο௧ܫ݊𝑡 ఱ௧ _ ଶ௧ +ߩ ο ܥ௧�𝑡௧ ܦ ௧ ଷ௧ ߩ ௧௧𝑡 (15)(13)ସߩ οܥܵܵ௧௧𝑡𝑡 ௤ୀ + � ߤ (4) ௤ୀ� כܺ + ௜� 𝑅�(௤ୀ� ଶ+) ௜𝑅� � ௝ + ଷ ௤ୀ 𝑅� � ௜ � + ௜𝑅� � ଶ+ כIܲ௜ ଶ�=�௝ = ߚଵ ܫ ௜ర�= ߮ܿହ οܻσ+ ߮௧ߚ𝑡οܲ െఱ ߮σοܥ଺ +ߚ௧+𝑡ܫ݊ ܷ𝐼� ௜𝑖σ ௧ ߚ ܫ݊ 𝐼� (9) σ ߚ Assumingܫσ௜�ܫ௝௤ୀ௧=௉�οܭ௒ߩ ௧ο௧ ܫ݊ 𝐼�a unitary ௧ + σsubstitution ௝ ௤ୀ ௧ � ߩ οܺ ௧ between � ௜ ݁� � ௧݉ capital ௧ ௧ ߝ ௧ and labour,(7) the model was re-stated as; (ߤ (8) (12) + CSSRSS + + (8 + ܺ + ܭο + ܫ௧ܴܶܥ + ௧𝑡ܵܵܥ ௤ୀ+�+଺ܵܧܥ ௧𝑡+PIܦ�ܥכ ++ PI�௤ୀ=� ߚହܲ ௜𝐼�� ݐ � ଶ߬+ ௜σ� ߚଷ ௜ܺ� ߝ ௞ ௜ 𝑖 ௜�ܭ݊ܫכσ௜ଶ� ஼ߚെଵ ܫ,௜� Į<= =߮௧οܻ+ +௣ ߮ οܲ +PI ߮ ௝ܥ+భ σ ݇ߜ ܨ� ++ ௝ߤమ CESRES (5) + ௝௝యయ ++ ௜�௧ ଵ௧ ௜� ௧ଶ ௜� ௧ ଷ ௜� ௧ ௜� ௜ � ௧ ଵ ௧ ௜ � ௧ ଶ (10)௜� ଷ ௜� ௜� ܫ ௧ οܭ଴_ ଵ ௧𝑡 _ +ଶభ + ௧ 𝑡 మ ଷ (8)௧𝑡 యయ (15)(13)ସ ௧𝑡 ܲܫ �௧== ߮ ܿߚ଴οܻ+σ 𝑅�+௤ୀ௣ �߮ߚଵ+οܲ 𝑅�௧𝑡െ ߮+σ௤ୀοܥ 𝑅�� ߚ௝ଶ+ܫ݊+ ܷ𝐼� 𝑅�ܫ ௧=𝑡+ ߮ ܺσοܻ௤ୀ+� +ߤߚ௝ ଷ ܫ݊ ߮ 𝐼� οܲ (9)௧ 𝑡െ ߮σοܥ௤ୀ௝௝�+ߚ+ସ ܷ ௧𝑡 (9) ௝௧ర ௧ ௤ୀ௝௝ � ௧ଵ� ௝ఱ ௧𝑡௞௞ ௧௤ୀ� � +ଶ௧ ௧𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧௧𝑡 ௤ୀ௤ୀ (16)(14)�� ସ ସ ௧௧𝑡𝑡 ܲPIοܲ௜� ర�= ߙହଵԂ+ ௜�σσ ߚ௧𝑡ܺߩଶ PI ο + ܫ݊௜ � σ + ఱ � ଷ ଺ ܨ �σ ௜௧ � 𝑡 + ߩ ߤ ௜௧ �ο 𝑅�ܥ � ܦ + σ ߩ (6)(11) + σ ߩCSSοܥܵܵ𝑅�+ Omojolaibiܫσ௜�௝௤ୀ=� ߚ߮ଵοܻܫ݊௜𝐼�� +et ߮al.ଶ οܲ+(2016) ௜σ� െ௤ୀ௝ �߮ augmentedߚଷοܥ௜ܺ� ++σ ܷߝ ௞ equation ௜ � ௜ 𝑖 ଵ (8)௜௜�� with ଶ (9)fiscal௜� policyଷ ௜� variables.௞ ௜𝑖 They௜ �disaggregated (� ++ + ߤ (10 ܨ ௝య σ ݇ߜܥ +�= ௜ 𝑖߮ + οܻ +௝ మߤ ௧ + ߮ οܲ CESRES (10)+ ߮ ܨ ܫ଺భ ௧𝑡 ݇ߜ+ܥ௤ୀ=� =߮ହ οܻ+ ௣+ ିఙ߮௧𝑡οܲ +PI௤ୀ ߮� ௝כ ܫ σ௜�௧ ߩ ଴_οܫ݊௜� 𝐼�௜௤ୀ� �௜� ଵ +௧ 𝑡σ ߩ௤ୀ_οܺ� ଶ + �݁௧�𝑡݉ ௤ୀ ߝ� ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� (13)ସ ௧𝑡 theܭPI௜�௧ =model ܿ߮ଵ௧ܲ+௜σ ܻ�by௣ܥ followingߚ௧ଶ PI௜� +௧ σtheଷ ௜ �workߚ௝௧భܫ݊ 𝐼�of௞ Malik௧ ௜𝑖+σ (2013).௧ ௜�ߚ௝మ௧ ܫ݊ Fiscal𝐼� policy+σ ௝௝wasయయߚ RSSdisaggregated+ in its revenue ܲ(�௝௧ర =) ߚ + ܥ�ܦ௝௝ +௧� ܥܧܵ௝ఱ +௞௞ ܥܵܵ௧� + ܥܴܶ௧ ௧ + ܺ + ߤ ௝௝ ௧ � (12) ௞௞ ௧� ௧ ܲܫ � ==௧ ߮ ߙ οܻ+ σ+௤ୀߚ ߮�ܺοܲଵ + +σ ௧߮𝑡� ܥభܨ� ௤ୀσ+� +݇ߜ ߤଶ ܨ � ௧ 𝑡 + + ߤ మ ௤ୀ � ଷ (10)௧௧𝑡 య௤ୀ (16)(14)� ସ ସ ௧௧𝑡𝑡 οܲ௣�� ହ Ԃ σ௣௤ୀ௧𝑡� ߩ οܫ݊ ଺௝ σ௧𝑡௤ୀ� ߩ௧οܲܥ��=ܦ ߙ +௝ σ௤ୀߚ � ߩܺ +(11) σ � σ௝ܨ௤ୀ� �ߩ+ο ߤܥܵܵ (11) andοܲ௤ୀ௝௧ర�� expenditure଴Ԃ_ ߩଵ componentsο௧ܫ݊𝑡௤ୀ௝ఱ� _ toଶ + accountߩ ο 𝑅�௧𝑡 for the ଷeffectߩ ௧of𝑡 different (15)ସߩ componentsο𝑅�௧𝑡 of fiscal policy σ ௝௜௧� ߚ ௧ܫ݊𝐼�௤ୀ� ௧ + σ ௝ ௧ ߚ ௤ୀܺ� ௧ ߝ ௧ ௧௤ୀ� ௧ ௤ୀ� ܲܫ�௤ୀ௧ర =�= ܿߚହ +σ 𝑅�௝௝ ௧ߚ𝑡+௧� 𝑅�PI௤ୀఱ �+σ௞௞ + ଺𝑅�ߚ௧௧�𝑡ܫ݊+𝐼� 𝑅�௧ +௜𝑖 ܺσ++௧ ߤߚ ܫ݊𝐼�CES +σ ߚ + ܲσ�௤ୀ௝௧==� ߩ ߙο௧+ ܫ݊ 𝐼�σ ߚ ௧ܺ + + σ ௝σ ௤ୀ ௧ �� ߩ ܨ οܺ � ௧ + ߤ � ݁ �௧ ௧݉ ௧௧ ߝ ௧ ௧ (7) (11) ௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ onܲPI�௤ୀ private=� ߚହ ++ investmentܥ௣�ܦ௧𝑡+PI ܥܧܵ௤ୀ +as�+ well଺ ܥܵܵ௧ 𝑡௝asభ + to ܥܴܶ ௧determineܲ� =++ ߚܺ ++ whether ܥߤ௝మ� ܦ + (12)thereܥܧܵ ++ is ܥܵܵa௝ యcrowding+RSS ܥܴܶ +in+ orܺ crowding+ ߤ out(12) ef- 𝐼� ଵPI+ σ +௧𝑡ߚ ܺ +ߝଶ +௧𝑡+ ଷ ௧𝑡 + (14)CSSସ ௧+𝑡݊ܫ+כ PIσଶ ௧=ߚ ௜� = ௧ +σ௣௤ୀ� PI ௝+భ σ௤ୀ� +௝మσ௤ୀ� RES +σ௝య௤ୀ� + fectܫοܲ௝௧ర� οܭonԂ ௧private௣ investment௧ߩ οܫ݊ ௝ఱ௧ ௝ భin the௧ ߩselectedο ܥ � ௧ ܦ West ௧ ௝ మ African ௧ ߩ (8) countries, ௝య theߩ ο ܥܵܵmodel was presented as; ܲ�௧ = ߚ଴_௧ + ܥ௤ୀ�ܦ� ௧ ଵ+ ܥܧܵ௧𝑡 ௧ +௤ୀ ܥܵܵ_ � ଶ௧భ ++ ܥܴܶ ௧𝑡௧ + ܺ௧௧௤ୀ+ � ߤమ௧ଷ ௧ (12)௧𝑡 ௧ ௤ୀయ (15)� ௧ସ ௧𝑡 ௧ ௧ ௧ ܲ�௧ = ܿହߚ଴_ +σ 𝑅�௤ୀ௣ �௧𝑡ߚଵ+ ௧𝑅�𝑡 +σ௤ୀ଺ _𝑅�� ߚ௧௝ଶ𝑡ܫ݊+𝐼� 𝑅�ܲ�௧𝑡=+௜𝑖 ߚ ܺσ௤ୀ++ � ௧ 𝑅�ߤߚ௝ଷ ܫ݊ 𝐼�+ 𝑅�௧𝑡 +σ ௤ୀ𝑅�௝� (13)ߚସ+ 𝑅�௧𝑡 + ܺ + ߤ ௤ୀ௝ర � ܿ σ ߚ ௝௤ୀఱ �σ ߚ ܫ݊+𝐼� σ+ ߚ ܫ݊ 𝐼� σ (16)ߚ σ௝ర ௧ ߩ οܫ݊𝐼�௤ୀ� ଵ+ σ௝ఱ ௧𝑡ߩ οܺ௤ୀ� ଶ�݁�݉ ௧𝑡 ߝ ௤ୀ� ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� ସ ௧𝑡 PIοܲ௜�௤ୀ௧ర�=� ହଵԂ௧+ ௜�σ ௧𝑡௧ߩଶ PIοܫ݊௜� ௤ୀ+ఱ௧� ଷ଺ σ௜௧�𝑡௧ ߩ௜௧�οPI𝑅�௧=+ +௧ σ ௧ ߩ PI ++ σ ߩCSSRSSο𝑅�++ + + CSS + ܲܫσ�௤ୀ௝==� ߚ߮ ହߚοܻܫ݊+𝐼� 𝑅�+ ௧߮𝑡 +οܲ+ 𝑅�σ௤ୀെ௝ �߮+ߚ଺οܥ 𝑅�ܺ௧+𝑡++ ܷ ߝ𝑅�௧ + ܺ + ߤ (9) σ ௤ୀ�ߚ=ହ ܫ݊+𝐼�௣ ௧𝑡+ σ PI௤ୀ�ߚ௝+భ଺ܺ ௧𝑡 ߝ ௜ 𝑖 ௝+మ ௧௣ RES +௝௝భ௝యయ + ௝మ ௝య σ௧ =ߩ ଴_οܫ݊+ 𝐼� ଵ +௧ 𝑡σPI ߩ+_οܺଶ + � ݁௧�𝑡 ݉ _+ ߝ ଷ CES௧𝑡 + _ (15)(13)ସ+ ௧𝑡 + PI௜�௧ = ܿ଴ଵ + ௜σ� ௤ୀ௣ � ߚଶଵPI௧௜𝑡� + σଷ௤ୀ௜� ߚ௝ଶభܫ݊𝐼�௞ ௧௧𝑡௜𝑖+଴σ௤ୀ௜��௤ୀߚ௝మଷ�ܫ݊𝐼�ଵ ௧௧𝑡𝑡 + σ௤ୀ௤ୀ�௝�య ߚଶସCSS௧𝑡௧𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� (13)ସ ௧𝑡 FPܫ ௝ర=itk is߮ܿ theοܻσ set+௣ of߮ߚ οܲK fiscal௝+ఱ ߮σ policyܥ ߚ௝భ ܫ݊σvariables݇ߜ𝐼� ܨ � including ܿ + σ ߤ σ ߚ௝ మ ܫ݊ ߚ government 𝐼� (10) σσ ௝capitalయߚߚܫ݊𝐼� expenditure,σ ߚ governmentܫ݊𝐼� σ ߚ ௝ ௧ ௤ୀ� ଵ ௝ ௧𝑡 భ ௤ୀ� +ଶ ௝ర ௧𝑡+మ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௝௧ఱ𝑡 య ௤ୀ (16)� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲ�௧ ହ Ԃ σ௣௤ୀ௧�𝑡ߩଵ οܫ݊ ௧𝑡଺௝ σ௧𝑡௤ୀ� +ߩଶ௧ο𝑅�௧𝑡+௝ σ௤ୀ � ߩ ଷ ௧𝑡 ௝σ௤ୀ (14)� ߩସ ο𝑅�௧𝑡 ௤ୀ௝௧ర � ହ଴_ σ ௧𝑡ଵ ௧𝑡௤ୀ௝ఱ� ଺_ σ௧𝑡ଶ + ௧ ௤ୀ௧𝑡� ହ σ ଷ௧𝑡 ௧𝑡௤ୀ � ଺σ (13)௧𝑡ସ ௧௧𝑡 recurrentσοܲ௝ర� ߚ Ԃܫ݊ 𝐼�expenditure,௤ୀ� ߩ+ο ܫ݊σ ௝ఱ directߚ௤ୀܺ� taxes,ߩߝ ο σ indirect ܥ � ܦ ߚ ܫ݊௤ୀ taxes,𝐼�� ߩnon-tax+ σ revenueߚ ௤ୀܺ� ߩ andοߝܥܵܵ external debt. ௤ୀ௧ర �=ܿହ +σ ௝௝ ௧ߚ𝑡௧� PIఱ௤ୀ�σ௞௞ +଺ ߚ௧௧�𝑡ܫ݊𝐼�௧ =௜𝑖σ++ ௧ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�CESRESPI +σ+ ߚ ++ + CES + + ܲσ�௝௤ୀ=� ߩ ହߙο+ܫ݊ 𝐼�σ ߚ௧𝑡ܺ ++ σ ௝σ௤ୀ��ߩ଺ܨοܺ�௧𝑡+ ߤ�݁�݉௜𝑖 ߝ௧ (11) σ σ భ మ యయ σ௤ୀ� ߩହοܫ݊𝐼�௣ ௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ߩ଺ οܺ௧𝑡௝ ௧�݁�݉ ߝ ௝௣ ௝௝ ௝భ ௝మ ௝య PI ௧=ߚ ܫ݊+ 𝐼�௤ୀ� ଵ+PI +௧𝑡ߚ ܺ ௤ୀ� +ߝଶ +௧ 𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ (14)(16)� RSSସ ସ+ ௧௧+𝑡𝑡 + For௧ the= ௧purpose+ σ௤ୀ�௧ of thePI ௧study+ σ objective,௤ୀ௧ � ௧ ௧this ௧model+ σ௤ୀ௤ୀ௧ � �is ଵmodified,CES ௧𝑡+ σ as௤ୀ ௤ୀ�we� concentrateଶ ௧+𝑡 more௤ୀ � on ଷ the௧𝑡 ef- ௤ୀ (14)� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲర� Ԃ σ௣ ߩ οܫ݊ ఱ ௝భ σ ߩ οοܲܥ𝑅���ܦ Ԃ ௝మ σσ ߩߩ οܫ݊ σ௝య σ ߩ ߩοܥܵܵ𝑅�οܥ�ܦ σ ߩ σ ߩ οܥܵܵ ܲ�௝ = ߚ + ܥ�ܦ + ܥܧܵ௝ + ܥܵܵభ + ܥܴܶ௝ర + ܺ + ߤమ (12)௝ఱ య ௧ ହ଴_ ௤ୀ௣ �௧𝑡ଵ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ଺_ � ௝௧ଶ𝑡+ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௤ୀ �௧ ௝ ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ௝ (15)� ସ ௧𝑡 fect௤ୀ௧� ofହ theσ government௧𝑡ଵ ௤ୀ௧ �expenditure𝑡σ ଺ ௧𝑡 +ଶ on௤ୀ �private௜௧𝑖𝑡ହσ+ ௧ investment ௧𝑡 ଷ ௧𝑡௤ୀ and� σ଺ determine (14)௧𝑡ସ ௧ 𝑡if௜ 𝑖expenditure௧ crowds σ௝ర ߩܿ οܫ݊𝐼�௤ୀ�ߚ + σ௝ఱ ߩ οܺߚ௤ୀܫ݊� 𝐼��σ݁�݉ ߩ οܫ݊ߝ𝐼�௤ୀߚ �ܫ݊𝐼�+ σ ߩ οܺ௤ୀ�ߚ �݁�݉ ߝ PIοܲ௧ర�= Ԃ௧+ σ ௧ߩPIοܫ݊ +ఱ௧ σ ௧ ߩ οPIܥ�௧=ܦ+ +௧ σ ௧ ߩ PI ++ σ ߩRSSοܥܵܵ + + + RSS + ܲ�௝௤ୀ=� ହߚ + 𝑅�௧𝑡 + 𝑅�௤ୀ௝ � +଺ 𝑅�௧𝑡 + 𝑅�௧ + ܺ + ߤ outσ orߚହ crowdsܫ݊𝐼� ௧in𝑡 +private σ ߚinvestment.଺భ ܺ ௧𝑡 ߝ ௜𝑖 మ ௧ య σ௤ୀ� =ߩ ο_ ܫ݊+𝐼�௣ + σPI௤ୀ� ߩ௝+_οܺ + �݁�݉ +௝ ߝ ௣ RES +௝భ௝ + ௝మ ௝య PI௧ = ଴ + ௤ୀ� ଵPI௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ� ଶ ௧௧𝑡 +଴_ ௤ୀ � ௤ୀଷ� ଵ ௧𝑡௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ௤ୀ_ � (15)� ଶସ+CSSRSS ௧ 𝑡௧+𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ (15)� ସ ௧𝑡 ర ܿ σ ௣ ߚ ఱ σ ߚ௝భܫ݊𝐼� ܿ σ σߚ௝మ ܫ݊ߚ𝐼� σσ ௝యߚߚܫ݊𝐼� σ ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� σ ߚ ௝ ௣ ௝ ௝భ ௝ర ௝మ ௝ఱ ௝యయ ௧ ௣௤ୀ� ଵ ௧𝑡 ௝ ௤ୀ� +ଶ ௧𝑡+௝ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 ௝ ௤ୀ (16)� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲ௤ୀ௧�� ହ଴Ԃ_ σ௤ୀ�௧𝑡ߩଵ ο௧ܫ݊𝑡௤ୀ� ଺௤ୀ_ �σ௧𝑡ଶ +ߩ ௧ο 𝑅�௤ୀ௧𝑡 � ହ ௤ୀ σ� ଷ௧𝑡ߩ ௧௧𝑡௤ୀ � ଺௤ୀσ � (15)(13)௧𝑡ସߩ ο𝑅�௧௧௧𝑡𝑡 σ௝ర ߚܿ Journalܫ݊𝐼�σ௤ୀ of� ߚ Competitiveness+ σ ௝ఱ σߚ௤ୀܺ � ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�ߝ σ ߚ σܫ݊௤ୀ𝐼�� ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�+ σ ߚσ௤ୀܺ�ߚ ߝ 14௝0ర =ܿ +σ ߚ ௝PIఱ σ + ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� = σ++ ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�RESPI +σ+ ߚ + + RES + + ௤ୀ௝ � ହ ௧𝑡 ௝௤ୀ� ଺ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௧ σ௤ୀ� ߩହοܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ߩ଺ οܺ௧𝑡భ ௧�݁�݉ ߝ మ య σ௤ୀ� ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�௣ + σ௤ୀ� ߚ ܺ ௝ +ߝ + ௝௣ ௝ ௝భ ௝మ ௝య ௧ = + ௤ୀ� ଵ PI௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ� ଶ ௧ ௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ ௤ୀ�� ଷଵCESRES௧𝑡 ௧𝑡+ ௤ୀ (16)௤ୀ� � ସ+ଶ ௧𝑡௧+𝑡+ + ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ (16)� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲర� Ԃ σ ߩ οܫ݊ ఱ σ ߩ οοܲ𝑅�� Ԃ σσ ߩߩ οܫ݊ σ σ ߩ ߩο𝑅�ο𝑅� σ ߩ σ ߩ ο𝑅� ௝ ௣ ௝ ௝భ ௝ర ௝మ ௝ఱ ௝௝యయ ௤ୀ௧� ହ ௤ୀ�௧𝑡ଵ ௤ୀ௧𝑡� ଺ ௤ୀ௧𝑡� +ଶ ௤ୀ�௜௧𝑖𝑡ହ + ௧ ௤ୀ �௧𝑡 ଷ ௧𝑡௤ୀ � ଺ ௤ୀ (16)(14)�௧𝑡ସ ௧𝑡௜𝑖 ௧ σοܲ�௧ ߩ Ԃοܫ݊𝐼�σ௤ୀ� ߩଵ+οܫ݊ σ ௧𝑡ߩ οܺσ௤ୀ� ߩଶ�οσ݁ܥ��݉ܦߩ௧𝑡οܫ݊ߝσ𝐼�௤ୀ� ߩଷ + σ௧𝑡 ߩσοܺ௤ୀ�ߩସοܥܵܵ�݁�௧݉𝑡 ߝ οܲ௝ర� Ԃ ߩ οܫ݊ ௝ఱ ߩ ο𝑅� ߩ ߩ ο𝑅� σ௤ୀ� ହ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଺ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௧ PIσ =ߩ ο+ܫ݊𝐼� PI+ σ + ߩ οܺ �݁�݉ + ߝ + RSS + joc4-2018-v2.indd 140 ௣ ௝భ ௝మ ௝య 1.12.2018 11:18:12 _ _ + (15) ௧ ଴ σ௤ୀ� ଵ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଶ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଷ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ସ ௧𝑡 ௝ర ܿ ߚ ௝ఱ ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� ߚ σ௤ୀ� ହ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଺ ௧𝑡 ௧ =ߚ ܫ݊+𝐼� + PI ߚ +ܺ ߝ + RES + + ௣ ௝భ ௝మ ௝య + + (16) ௧ σ௤ୀ� ଵ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଶ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଷ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲ௝ర� Ԃ ߩ οܫ݊ ௝ఱ ߩ ο𝑅� ߩ ߩ ο𝑅� σ௤ୀ� ߩହοܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ߩ଺οܺ௧𝑡 �݁�݉௜𝑖 ߝ௧ ( ) = F[ , ]= (1) ఈ ଵିఈ ௧ ௧ ௧ Ȇܻ (t) = P(t)ܭ Yܮ(t) – sܣ(t)� I(t)ܮ – w(t) L(t) (2)

K* = PĮY/ c (3)

I = ( ) (4) ௉�௒ (1) =[ כ , ]F = ݐ � ߬ ܭ ஼ െ ( ) , Į<ఈ ଵିఈ (5) Ȇܻ ௧ = P(t)ܭ ௧Yܮ௧ – sܣ� I ܮ – w L (2) (t) (t) (t) (t) (t) (t) (6) Į ିఙ כ* K௜� = P Y/ ௜c� ௜ � ௜ � (3) ܭ( =) ߮ ܲ ܻ ܥ I =௣ � ( ) (4) ܫ௜� (7) כ ௉�௒= (ݐ � ߬ (5 ܭ כଶ Į<஼ െ, ܫ௜� οܭ௧ (8) (6) ܫ௜� = ߮[ଵοܻ,௜� +] ߮ଶοܲ௜� െ ߮ଷοܥ௜�++ ܷ௜� (9) (F =ିఙ (1 = (כ) ௜� ௜� ௜� ௜� ఈ ଵିఈ ܭ(௜� =) ߮ଵ ܲ ௜ܻ� ܥ ଶ ௜� ଷ ௜� ௞ ௜𝑖 ௜� ܻܫ ௧ = ߮ ܭοܻ௧ ܮ௧+ ߮ܣ�οܲܮ + ߮ ܥ σ ݇ߜ ܨ � + ߤ (10) Ȇ(t)௣�= P(t) Y(t) – s(t) I(t) – w(t) L(t) (2) ௜� ܫ*௧= Į ௝௝ ௧ � ௞௞ ௧ � ௧ (7) PܲK� =is= Pthe ߙY/+ privatec σ ߚ ܺ investment + σ � ܨ � at the + ߤ time, X is the control (11)(3) variables which include inflation, ex- tj כ ଶIt changeܫ௜�௧ οܭ௧ ௧rate and௧ the rate௧ of growth௧ in ௧ the ௧country, ௧ FP (8) is the fiscal variables which include the ܲI =� = ߚ + ܥ(�ܦ +) ܥܧܵ + ܥܵܵ + ܥܴܶ + ܺ + ߤ (12)(4) -recurrentଶ ௜� expendituresଷ ௜� ௜of� government in the economy. U is the error term. We there כcapital௜� ௉�௒ ଵand௜� ܲܫ �௧== ߮ ߚ௧οܻ+ 𝑅�+ ߮௧ +οܲ 𝑅�െ ௧߮+οܥ 𝑅�++௧ + ܷ 𝑅�௧ + ܺ௧ + ߤ ௧ (9) :ݐ � ߬ the model into two to capture the components(5) of government expenditure ܭ fore, Į<஼ disaggregateെ PI = + PI + + + CSS + ܫ௜� = ߮ଵοܻ௜� + ߮ଶοܲ௜� + ߮ଷܥ௜� σ ݇ߜ௞ ܨ � ௜ 𝑖 + ߤ ௜ � (10) capital( ) = F [and, recurrent.௣]= The ௝ భ models are therefore ௝ మ presented (1) below௝య as; ௧ ଴_ ௤ୀ� ଵ ௧ 𝑡 ௤ୀ _ � ଶ + ௧ 𝑡 ௤ୀ � ଷ (6)௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� (13)ସ ௧𝑡 ௧ ܿ σ ௝௝ ߚ ௧�ఈ ଵିఈ σ௞௞ ߚ௧�ܫ݊𝐼�௧ σ ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� σ ߚ (� + ߤ (11)(2 ܨ ௝wσఱ �L – ܮ+ � Iܺܣσ௧ –ߚ sିఙܮ ௧Y +ܭర = P(t) ߙכȆܻ�௝௧ܲ σܭ௜௤ୀ(t)� =� ߮ହ ܲ௜�ܻ(t)௜�ܥ௧௜�𝑡(t) (t) σ௤ୀ(t)� ଺(t) ௧𝑡 ௧ ( )=ߚ ܫ݊+𝐼� + PI ߚ +ܺ ߝ + CES + + *௧௣� Į ௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ ௧ PIܲK�t =implies= P ߚY/+ c ܥ private ௣ � ܦ + ܥܧܵinvestment + ܥܵܵ ௝ భ which + ܥܴܶ is + captured ܺ + ߤ ௝ మ as gross (12)(3) capital௝య formation as a percentage of ௜� + + (14) οܲܫ =�௧ Ԃ σ ௤ୀ � ߩ ଵ ο ܫ݊ ௧ 𝑡 σ ௤ୀ � ߩ ଶ ο ܥ � ܦ ௧ 𝑡 σ ௤ୀ � ߩ ଷ (7) ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ߩସοܥܵܵ௧𝑡 GDP௝௧ర at௧ the time,௧ CAD௝ఱ௧ t is the௧ capital௧ expenditure௧ ௧ on administration at the time, CESt is the 𝑅�] + 𝑅� + 𝑅� + 𝑅� + ܺ + ߤ ,+ כ]ଶ� = ߚܲ I (=) = Fହ ( =௧𝑡) ଺ ௧ 𝑡 ௜ 𝑖 ௧ (4)(1) σ௜�௤ୀ� ߩ ௧οܫ݊𝐼� + σ௤ୀ� ߩ οܺ �݁�݉ ߝ capitalPIܫ ௉=�οܭ௒ expenditure+ PIఈ ଵିఈon+ economic services + at the time, (8) CSS +t is the capitalCSSRSS ++expenditure on social ௧כ ௧ ௧ w(t) L௝(t)భ ௝ మ (2) ௝௝యయ – ܮ(t)߬� I(t)ܣt)௣ ݐ– �s)ܮܭY ܭȆܻ (t) =஼ P(t)െ services,௜� ௧Į<଴ଵ_ at௜ �the௤ୀ� timeଶଵ ௧௜ 𝑡�and CTRଷ௤ୀ_ �௜�t ଶis+ the௜� capital௧𝑡 ௤ୀexpenditure � ଷ (5)௧𝑡 on transfer௤ୀ� (15)(13)ସ at௧ 𝑡the time. Xt includes the ܫ( ௧)== ߮Fܿ଴[ οܻ,σ௤ୀ+]= �߮ߚଵοܲ௧𝑡െ ߮σ ௤ୀ οܥ � ߚ + ଶ+ ܫ݊ ܷ𝐼� ௧ 𝑡 σ ௤ୀ � ߚ ଷ ܫ݊ 𝐼� (9) (1)௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ�ߚସ ௧𝑡 ௝*ర Į ௝ఱ controlK = P ହY/ macro-economic c ௧ 𝑡 ఈ ଵିఈ ଺variables ௧ 𝑡 ௧such as inflation rate, (3) and lending rate at the time, while μt is σ௜�௤ୀ௧ � ߚହଵܫ݊௧ 𝐼�௜� ௧ ௧𝑡ଶ + ௜σ � ௤ୀ � ߚ ଷ଺ ܺ ௜� ௧ 𝑡 ߝ ௧ ௞ ௜ 𝑖 ௜ � (6) Ȇܫܻ (t)== =P(t)߮ ܭοܻ +Yܮ(t)+ – s߮ܣ(t)� οܲI(t)ܮ – +PIw(t) ߮ L(t)+ܥ σ ݇ߜ ܨ � + + ߤ CES RES (10) (2) + ++ (error F[ ,term]=ିఙ at the time. (1= (כ)the I =௜� ௜� ௜(�௣ ௜� ) ௝ భ ௝ మ (4) ௝௝యయ ܭ( *௧ =௧) Į߮ ܲ ܻ ௤ୀܥ ௝௝ � ଵ௧�ఈ ଵିఈ௧𝑡௞௞ ௧௤ୀ� � +ଶ ௧ ௧𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ (16)(14)� ସ ௧𝑡 ܲKοܲ�௧ �=௉௧=� P௒ ߙY/Ԃ+௧ c σ ௧ ௤ୀ ߚ � ܺߩ ଵ ο + ܫ݊ σ ௧ 𝑡 � ܨ σ � ௤ୀ +� ߩ ߤଶ ο 𝑅�ܥ � ܦ ௧ 𝑡 σ ௤ୀ � ߩ ଷ (11)(3)௧𝑡 σ ௤ୀ�ߩସοܥܵܵ𝑅�௧𝑡 ;w௝ఱ(t) Lexpenditure(t) is presented below (2) as – ܮ(t)recurrent� I(t)ܣ for – s כ(t)ܮY ܭ(TheȆܻ ௝(t)௣ర �= model P(t (ݐ �௧𝑡߬ σ௤ୀ� ଺ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௧ (5 ܭ σ ௤ୀ௜Į<� �஼ ହെ, PIσܫ௧==ߩ ο௧+ ܫ݊ 𝐼� ௧ PI + σ + ௧ ߩ οܺ ௧ � ݁ � ௧݉ + ௧ ߝ ௧ (7) + RSS + ܲKI =�* == P ĮߚY/+ c ܥ ( � ܦ + ) ܥܧܵ + ܥܵܵ + ܥܴܶ + ܺ + ߤ (12)(3)(4) భ మ య כ ଶ ௣ ௝ ௝ ௝כ ௉�௒ ௜�௧ ଴௧_௧ ௤ୀ� ௧ଵ ௧ 𝑡 ௧ ௤ୀ _ � ଶ௧ + ௧ 𝑡 ௧ ௧ ௤ୀ � ଷ௧ (6)௧𝑡 ௤ୀ (15)� ସ ௧𝑡 gross 𝐼� (8) fixedσ capitalߚ formation as a percentage ݊ܫ 𝐼� 𝑅� is captured + ܺσ + ߚߤ as+݊ܫσ private𝑅�ݐ �ߚ߬+ investment𝑅� σ+ 𝑅�ߚ whichܭ+ ߚെܿ ܭ� implies=஼ο ܫPIܲ (tరĮ<( ିఙ ) ௝ఱ (5כ௝ , I = ହ ௜� ௜� ௧𝑡 ଺ ௧ 𝑡 ௧ (4) PI௜�௜௤ୀ� =� ଵ + ௜� ௜� ଶ PI ௜� ௤ୀ+� ଷ ௜� ௜� + + CSS + t is+ +the ܷߝ government recurrent expenditure on administration at theܺܥ߮ time,οܲ+ σ െRAD߮ߚ ο ܥ+the כat𝐼�ܻ ܲ݊ܫσ( =GDP௉=)� ߚ௒߮ ߮ οܻܭ ܫof = + ௣ PI ௝+భ +௝మ RES (9) + ௝య + ௣� ஼ (6) is௤ୀ௣ݐ the� ߬ଵ government௧𝑡 ௤ୀ_ � ௝recurrentଶభ + ௧𝑡 expenditure ௤ୀ � ௝మଷ on (5) ௧economic𝑡 ௤ୀ௝�య (13) servicesସ ௧𝑡 at the time, RSS is the ܭ _time,, ௧Į< RES଴െ 𝐼� σ ߚ t݊ܫ 𝐼�௞ ௜𝑖 σ+ ௜�ߚ+݊ܫ ௜� ܿଵ ௜σt� ିఙߚଶ ௜� σଷ ௜� ߚכ௜� ܫ ܫ௝ర=௧ ߮ οܻ + ௤ୀ �߮ ଵ οܲ ௝+ ఱ ௧ ߮𝑡 ܥ ௤ୀ σ � ݇ߜ ଶ ܨ � ௧ 𝑡 + ߤ ௤ୀ � ଷ (7)(10) ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ (16)� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲ௜�ర� Ԃ ௜� σ௜� ௜� ߩ οܫ݊ ఱ σ ߩ ο𝑅� σ ߩ σ ߩ ο𝑅� governmentσ ܭ( ௤ୀ௝ =�) ߚ ߮ହ ܫ݊ܲ 𝐼�ܻ recurrentܥ௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ௝ expenditure� ߚ଺ ܺ௧𝑡 ߝ௧ on social services at tie and RTRt is the government recurrent + + (௧𝑡 PI ௤ୀ � +଺ ௧ 𝑡 ௜ 𝑖 + ௧ CES (6 + כ ଶ௤ୀ� =ହ ܫσ௜�௧௣� οܭߩ ௧οܫ݊𝐼�σ ௝௝ ௧+� σσ ߩ௞௞ οܺ௧� �௧ ݁�݉ ߝ the�௝భ time.+ ߤ X t include ௝ మ the control (8) (11) variables௝య such as inflation rate andܨ ߙ + ௣onߚିఙ ܺtransfer+ �at = כexpenditureܲ� ܫ௜�௜�= ௜ � ௜ � ௜ � + + (7) (14) ܭ( =௧) ߮ ܲ ܻσ௤ୀܥ � ଵ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଶ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଷ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ସ ௧𝑡 lendingοܲ௜�௝௧ర� ଵԂ௧ rate௜� at the௧ߩଶ ο time,ܫ݊௜� ௝ఱ௧ whileଷ ௜� ௧μt theߩ௜�ο ܥerror�௧ ܦ term௧ at௧ theߩ time. ߩ οܥܵܵ (ߤ (9) (12 + ܺ + ܴܶܥ ܷ +++ܵܵܥܥെ ߮+ οܵܧܥ ߮ +οܲܦ �+ܥ +οܻכଶ�௣=�= ߮ ߚܫܲ ௜�௤ୀ� ହ௧ ௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� ଺ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௧ ܫσܫ௜� οܭߩ οܫ݊𝐼� + σ ߩ οܺ � ݁ � ݉ ߝ (8) UsingPI௜�௧== equationଵ௧+ ௜ � ௧ ଶ11 PI and ௜ � + ௧12, ଷ we ௜ � specify ௧ ௞ the ௧ ௜ 𝑖 + ARDL ௧ ௜ � ௧ model (7) for+ this studyRSS as; + ܲܫ � == ߮ ߚοܻ+ 𝑅�௣+ ߮ +οܲ 𝑅�+ ߮+௝ܥ భ𝑅� σ+݇ߜ 𝑅� ܨ � + + ܺ ௝ ߤమ+ ߤ (10) ௝య (௜� ଶ ௜� ଷ _ ௜�+ + ௜� (15 כ_௜ଶ� ଵ PIܫ௜�௧== ߮଴௧οܻ+ σ௤ୀ+ �߮ ଵοܲPI௧𝑡െ+߮σ௤ୀοܥ� ଶ+ ܷ ௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ଷ (9)௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ସCSS ௧𝑡 + ܫ ௝௧ర οܭܿ ௝௝ ߚ ௧� ௝ఱ ௞௞ ߚ௧�ܫ݊𝐼�௧ ߚ ܫ݊ 𝐼� (8) ߚ ܲ� = ߙ + σ ߚ ܺ + σ � భܨ� + ߤ మ (11) య ௜�௤ୀ� ହଵ ௜� ௣ ௧𝑡ଶ ௜� ௤ୀ� ଷ଺௝ ௜�௧𝑡 ௧௞ ௜𝑖 ௝ ௜� ௝ σ ௧ ߚ ଴_ܫ݊𝐼� ଵ+ ௧σ𝑡 ߚ _ܺ ଶσ+ ߝ ௧𝑡 ଷ ௧𝑡 (13)ସ ௧𝑡 ܫ௜� = =߮ܿଵοܻ+௜σ� ௤ୀ+ �߮ߚଶοܲ௜� +PI ߮σଷ௤ୀ+ܥ �௜ߚ� ܫ݊݇ߜ𝐼�௜� ܨ � + σ + ௤ୀ ߤ � ߚ ܫ݊ 𝐼� RES (10) +σ௤ୀ� ߚ + ܫ ௝௧ర= ߮ ௧οܻ + ߮௧ οܲ ௝െఱ ௧߮ οܥ +௧+ ܷ ௧ ௧ ௧ (9) ܲ� = ߚ + ܥ௣�ܦ + ܥܧܵ + ܥܵܵ௝భ + ܥܴܶ + ܺ + ߤ௝మ (12) ௝య Equationσ௤ୀ௧ � ߚହ ܫ݊ 𝐼�13σ is௧௝௝ 𝑡the+௧� ARDLσ௤ୀσ� ߚ଺௞௞ longܺ௧𝑡௧� run+ߝ௧ ௧ model for+ capital expenditure (16) components ADC, ESC, SSC, ܲ௜� ௧== ߙଵ ++ ௜�σ௤ୀߚ� ܺଶଵ +௜� PI௧𝑡�ଷ+ܨ௜�σ�௤ୀ+� ߤଶ ௞ ௜𝑖௧𝑡 + ௜σ� ௤ୀ � ଷ CES (11)௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ସ ௧𝑡 + ܫοܲ௝௧ర�= ߮Ԃ௧οܻ + ߮௧ߩοܲοܫ݊+௝ఱ ௧߮ ܥ ௧σߩ݇ߜο 𝑅� ܨ � ௧ + ௧ ߤ ௧ ߩ (10) ߩ ο𝑅� TRCܲ� = andߚ + macro-economic 𝑅�௣ + 𝑅� + 𝑅�indicators௝భ + 𝑅� X+ - lendingܺ + ௝ߤమ rate and inflation௝య rate. σ௤ୀ௧ � ହ ௧ ௧𝑡௧ σ௤ୀ௧ � ଺ ௧௧𝑡 + ௧ ௜𝑖 ௧+ ௧ ௧ (14) ܲPI�௧ ௧=ߩ ߚο+ܫ݊+𝐼� σܥ௤ୀ�ܦ௝௝ � +ଵ௧PI+� ܥܧܵ +௧𝑡+ߩ௞௞ ܥܵܵοܺσ௧௤ୀ� +� ܥܴܶଶ�௧ ݁�݉++௧ 𝑡ܺ +ߝσ ߤ௤ୀ� ଷ (12)௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� CSSସ ௧+𝑡 ܲοܲ�௝ర�= ߙԂ+ σ ߚ ܺߩ ο+ܫ݊ σ௝ఱ � ܨ� +ߩ ߤοܥ�ܦ ߩ (11) ߩ οܥܵܵ Equation 14௣ presents the short-run௝భ model of௝ మthe capital expenditure௝య components and the macro- σ௤ୀ௧ � ߩହο_௧ ܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡௧ + σ௤ୀ௧� ߩ଺_οܺ௧𝑡௧ + �݁�݉௧ ௜𝑖 ௧ ߝ௧ ௧ (13) ܲPI�௧ = ܿߚ଴௧++σ 𝑅�௤ୀ� ߚ௧ଵ+PI ௧𝑅�𝑡 +௧ σ+௤ୀ 𝑅�� ߚଶ௧ ܫ݊+𝐼� 𝑅�௧𝑡௧ ++ ܺσ௧௤ୀ+� ߚߤ௧ଷܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ߚସ RSS௧𝑡 + economicܲ�௝ర = ߚ + indicators ܥ�ܦ + ܥܧܵ ௝Xఱ -+ lending ܥܵܵ + rate ܥܴܶ and+ inflationܺ + ߤ rate. (12) PI = + ௣ PI + ௝భ + ௝మ + ௝య CSS + σ௤ୀ� ߚହ_ܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ߚ଺_ܺ௧𝑡 + ߝ௧ (15) ௧ =ܿ଴௧ +σ௣௤ୀ� ߚ௧ଵ ௧𝑡PI௧ σ௤ୀ௝+భ � ߚଶ௧ܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡௧ σ௧+௝௤ୀమ � ߚଷ௧ ܫ݊𝐼�CES௧𝑡 +σ௝௤ୀయ � ߚସ ௧𝑡 + ܲ�௝௧ర = ߚ଴_ + 𝑅� ଵ+ ௧𝑅�𝑡௝ఱ + _𝑅�ଶ + 𝑅�௧𝑡+ ܺ + ߤଷ ௧𝑡 (13)ସ ௧𝑡 ܿ σ௤ୀ௣ � ߚ σ௤ୀ� ߚ௝భܫ݊𝐼� σ௤ୀ� ߚ௝మ ܫ݊𝐼� σ௤ୀ௝య� ߚ ௝௤ୀర � ହ ௧𝑡 ௝௤ୀఱ � ଺ ௧𝑡 ௧ PIσ ௧=ߚ ܫ݊+ 𝐼�௤ୀ� ଵ+PI σ +௧𝑡ߚ ܺ ௤ୀ� +ߝଶ +௧𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ (14)� CSSସ ௧+𝑡 οܲ� =ହԂ + σ ௧𝑡ߩ οܫ݊PI ଺+ σ௧𝑡 ߩ ௧οܥ�ܦ + σ ߩ RES +σ ߩ οܥܵܵ + σ௝௤ୀర � ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�௣ + σ௤ୀ௝ఱ� ߚ௝భ ܺ ߝ ௝మ ௝య = _ + ௣ PI +_ ௝భ + + ௝మ CES + ௝య (13) + σ௤ୀ௧ � ߩܿହ଴οܫ݊σ𝐼�௤ୀ�௧ߚ𝑡ଵ +௧ 𝑡σ௤ୀ�σߩ௤ୀ଺οܺ� ߚ௧ଶ𝑡ܫ݊+𝐼��݁�௧𝑡݉௜𝑖σ+௤ୀߝ�௧ ߚ ଷܫ݊ 𝐼�௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� (16)ߚସ ௧𝑡 EquationPIοܲ௝ర�௧= Ԃ+ 15σ ௣௤ୀis �theߩଵPIο ARDLܫ݊௝ఱ+௧𝑡 longσ௤ୀ௝భ run� ߩଶ modelο𝑅�+௧𝑡 for theσ௝௤ୀమ recurrent� ߩଷ ௧𝑡+ expenditureσ௝௤ୀయ � ߩRSSସο𝑅� components௧+𝑡 ADC, ESC, ௝ర ௧ ହ ௧𝑡 ଵ ௝ఱ௧𝑡଺ ௧𝑡 +ଶ௧ ௧𝑡+ ଷ ௧𝑡 (14)ସ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� σ௣௤ୀ� σ௤ୀ� ௝భ σ௤ୀ� ௝మ σ௤ୀ� σ௝య௤ୀ� SSC,οܲ௝௤ୀర�� ߚTRCହԂܫ݊𝐼� and௧ 𝑡macro-economicߩ+ο ܫ݊ ௝௤ୀఱ �ߚ ଺ܺ ௧𝑡 indicatorsߩߝ ο ܥ � ܦ ௜ 𝑖 X -௧ lendingߩ rate and inflationߩ οܥܵܵ rate. σ ௧ =ߩ ଴ο_ ܫ݊+𝐼�௤ୀ� ଵ +௧ 𝑡σPI ߩ௤ୀ+_οܺ� ଶ + � ݁�௧𝑡݉ +௤ୀ ߝ� ଷ CES௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ (15)� ସ ௧𝑡 + ܿହ σ ௧ߚ𝑡 σ ଺ ߚ௧𝑡ܫ݊𝐼� ௜𝑖σ ௧ ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� σ ߚ σ௤ୀ௝ర � ߩ οܫ݊𝐼�௣ + σ௝௤ୀఱ � ߩ οܺ௝భ �݁�݉ ߝ ௝మ ௝య PI = + PI + + + + + (14)RSS + σοܲ௤ୀ�௧� ߚହԂܫ݊𝐼�σ௤ୀ௧�𝑡ߩଵ+ο ܫ݊σ௤ୀ௧�𝑡ߚ଺ ܺσ௧𝑡௤ୀ� ߩߝଶ௧οܥ�ܦ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ߩଷ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ߩସοܥܵܵ௧𝑡 ௝ర = + ௣ PI௝ఱ ௝+భ +௝మ RES + ௝య + ௧ ହ଴_ ௧𝑡ଵ ௧𝑡 ଺_ ௧ଶ𝑡+ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௧ ଷ ௧𝑡 (15)ସ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� σ௤ୀ௣ � σ௤ୀ�σ௤ୀ� ௝భ σ௤ୀ� ௝మ σ௤ୀ௝య� ௝ర ߩܿ οܫ݊𝐼� ߚ + ௝ఱ ߩ οܺߚ ܫ݊𝐼��݁�݉ ߝ ߚ ܫ݊𝐼� ߚ PI ௧= + ௤ୀ� ଵPI +௧𝑡 ௤ୀ� +ଶ +௧𝑡+ ௤ୀ � ଷ ௧𝑡 + ௤ୀ (16)� RSS ସ ௧+𝑡 οܲ� ହԂ σ ௧𝑡ߩ οܫ݊ ଺ σ௧𝑡 ߩ ௧ο𝑅� σ ߩ σ ߩ ο𝑅� σ௤ୀ௝ర � ߚ ܫ݊𝐼�௣ + σ௤ୀ௝ఱ� ߚ௝భ ܺ ߝ ௝మ ௝య Equation= _ + 16 presentsPI the +short-run_ + model +of capital RES expenditure + (15) components + and the macro- σ௤ୀ௧ � ߩܿହ଴οܫ݊σ𝐼�௤ୀ�௧ߚ𝑡ଵ +௧ 𝑡σ௤ୀ�σߩ௤ୀ଺οܺ� ߚ௧ଶ𝑡ܫ݊𝐼��݁�௧𝑡݉௜𝑖σ௤ୀߝ�௧ ߚଷܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ߚସ ௧𝑡 ௝ర ௣ ௝ఱ ௝భ ௝మ ௝య economic indicators X - lending +rate and inflation+ rate. (16) σοܲ௤ୀ�௧� ߚହԂܫ݊𝐼�σ௤ୀ௧�𝑡ߩଵ+ο ܫ݊σ௤ୀ௧�𝑡ߚ଺ ܺσ௧𝑡௤ୀ� ߩߝଶ௧ο𝑅�௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ߩଷ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ߩସο𝑅�௧𝑡 ௝ర = + PI௝ఱ + + RES + + ହ ௧𝑡 ଺ ௧𝑡 ௜𝑖 ௧ σ௤ୀ� ߩ οܫ݊𝐼�௣ + σ௤ୀ� ߩ οܺ௝భ �݁�݉ ߝ ௝మ ௝య + + (16) ௧ σ௤ୀ� ଵ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଶ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ଷ ௧𝑡 σ௤ୀ� ସ ௧𝑡 οܲ௝ర� Ԃ ߩ οܫ݊ ௝ఱ ߩ ο𝑅� ߩ ߩ ο𝑅� σ௤ୀ� ߩହοܫ݊𝐼�௧𝑡 + σ௤ୀ� ߩ଺οܺ௧𝑡 �݁�݉௜𝑖 ߝ௧ 141

joc4-2018-v2.indd 141 1.12.2018 11:18:17 From equations 13, 14, 15 and 16, β1 – β6 represent long-run multipliers of the variables. While,

ρ1 – ρ5 reprsent the short-run multipliers of the variables, while the long-run and short-run in-

tercept of the models are c0 and 0 and j1 – j5 are the optimal lags length of each of the variables as revealed in the results. ϑ The data used for the study include private investment proxy as gross fixed capital formation, recurrent and capital expenditure on: administration, economic services, social services, trans- fers; Inflation rate and Lending rate. Gross fixed capital was used as a proxy for private invest- ment as used in Jalloh (2002), Majumber (2007), Sineviciene et al. (2012) and Omojolaibi et al. (2016) study. It explains the contribution of private investment to the growth of an economy. The aforementioned conditioning variables were chosen because of their strong theoretical and empirically proven relationship with private investment (Omojolaibi et al., 2016). In line with previous studies such as Bello et al., (2012), Nwosa et al. (2013), Dada (2013), and Omojolaibi et al., (2016), fiscal policy is disaggregated to capture the crowding in/out effect on private invest- ment in Nigeria within the time period under study. The data used for the study are secondary in nature and are sourced from the Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN) Statistical Bulletin (2015) and World Development Indicators (WDI) (2015).

4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION The analysis of the study is presented separately.

4.1 Descriptive Statistics Analysis The descriptive statistics is used to measure data variability and the spread of the distribution of the set of data. This facilitated the decision on the normality of the variables employed in the study and also helped to identify the variables that needed to be transformed into the natural log. Skewness was used to measure the asymmetry of the distribution around its mean. For the capital expenditure model, it was revealed that all the variables show a long tail to the right. This implies that they are positively skewed to the right, by which h limits the estimation of the model to take place in linear form. Kurtosis revealed that gross fixed capital formation, lending rate, infla- tion rate, and capital expenditure on transfer are peaked to normal, which implies that they are leptokurtic, as they have values greater than 3. Capital expenditure on administration, economic services, and social services are flat relative to normal, which implies that they are platykurtic, as they have values lower than 3. The Jaque-Bera statistics reveal that the variables are not all normally distributed, as they show a probability value lower than 10% level of significance except for capital expenditure on economic service, which is greater than 10% (see Table 1). For the recurrent expenditure model, it was revealed that recurrent expenditure on administra- tion, transfer, economic services and social services show a long tail to the left, which implies that they are negatively skewed in that direction. The need to transform the variables by taking a natural log of the variables is present. Gross fixed capital formation, lending rate and inflation rate show a long tail to the right, which implies they are positively skewed and there is no need to take a natural log of the variable (see Table 2). Further, for the capital and recurrent expenditure

142 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 142 1.12.2018 11:18:17 model, it was revealed that all the variables display a mean lying between their minimum and maximum levels. This implies that they fall within the expected changes over the period under study. It can be also inferred that all the variables are well-behaved within the period (see Table 1 and 2).

Tab. 1 – Descriptive Statistics for Capital Expenditure Model. Source: author computation GCF INFLR LNDR CTR CAD CES CSS Mean 12.72 19.71 17.81 53.40 90.87 172.70 45.08 Maximum 35.22 72.84 31.65 265.90 291.66 506.01 154.71 Minimum 5.46 5.38 8.92 0.01 0.26 0.66 0.24 Std. Dev. 6.41 17.94 5.04 69.24 105.67 175.15 54.57 Skewness 2.01 1.63 0.18 1.69 0.75 0.54 0.97 Kurtosis 7.44 4.37 3.43 4.86 1.93 1.91 2.47 Jarque- 52.27 18.17 0.44 21.13 4.96 3.41 5.85 Bera Prob 0.00 0.00 0.80 0.00 0.08 0.18 0.05 Obs 35 35 35 34 35 35 35

Tab. 2 – Descriptive Statistics for Recurrent Expenditure Model. Source: author´s computation GCF INFLR LNDR LRAD LRES LRSS LRTR Mean 12.712 19.72 17.81 3.99 2.52 3.11 4.58 Maximum 35.22 72.84 31.65 7.14 6.33 6.74 7.33 Minimum 5.46 5.38 8.92 -0.11 -1.76 -1.24 1.22 Std. Dev. 6.42 17.94 5.04 2.53 2.69 2.79 2.04 Skewness 2.01 1.63 0.18 -0.29 -0.21 -0.29 -0.28 Kurtosis 7.44 4.37 3.43 1.65 1.66 1.70 1.73 Jarque- 52.27 18.17 0.44 3.15 2.88 2.93 2.81 Bera Probability 0.00 0.000 0.80 0.21 0.24 0.23144 0.25 Observa- 35 35 35 35 35 35 35 tions

4.2 Correlation Matrix The correlation test is used to test for presence of multicollinearity among the variables to avoid a contradictory result. For this study, the correlation result will be validated based on the argu- mant by Iyoha (2004) that multicollinearity among variables occurred when the result of the correlation coefficient is greater than 0.95. Following the estimated models of the study, the results reveal that the independent variables had a weak negative correlation with the dependent variable. This implies that the variables are independent of each other and free of the multicol- linearity problem (see Table 3 and 4).

143

joc4-2018-v2.indd 143 1.12.2018 11:18:17 Tab. 3 – Correlation Matrix for Capital Expenditure. Source: author´s computation GCF INFLR LNDR TRC ADC ESC SSC GCF 1 -0.093 -0.52 -0.09 -0.16 -0.26 -0.15 INFLR -0.09 1 0.40 -0.20 -0.41 -0.43 -0.38 LNDR -0.52 0.40 1 0.11 -0.02 0.04 -0.01 CTR -0.09 -0.20 0.11 1 0.57 0.65 0.52 CAD -0.16 -0.41 -0.02 0.57 1 0.94 0.97 CES -0.26 -0.43 0.04 0.65 0.94 1 0.92 CSS -0.15 -0.38 -0.01 0.52 0.97 0.92 1

Tab. 4 – Correlation Matrix for Recurrent Expenditure. Source: author´s computation LO- GCF INFLR LNDR LADR LOGSSR LOGTRR GESR GCF 1 -0.081 -0.54 -0.48 -0.45 -0.46 -0.47 INFLR -0.08 1 0.37 -0.27 -0.27 -0.25 -0.25 LNDR -0.54 0.37 1 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.38 LRAD -0.48 -0.27 0.357 1 0.99 0.99 0.99 RES -0.45 -0.27 0.36 0.99 1 0.98 0.98 LRSS -0.46 -0.25 0.36 0.99 0.98 1 0.98 LRTR -0.47 -0.25 0.38 0.99 0.98 0.98 1

4.3 Selection of optimal Lag In order to determine the lag length, the Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC) was need. Fol- lowing the SIC, we used the optimal lag of 1 for the ARDL estimates, as can be seen here in Table 5.

Tab. 5 – Optimal lag selection for CE and RE models. Source: author´s computation CE Model RE Model Lag SIC SIC 0 61.8531 26.4107 1 60.55725* 22.41707*

4.4 Pre-Estimation Diagnostic Test It is also important to discuss the preliminary diagnostic tests that are generally used in cross- sectional data analysis, namely the unit root test and co-integration test, before the empirical results are presented.

4.4.1 Unit root Result The unit root test is used to test for the presence of stationarity among variables. It helps to

144 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 144 1.12.2018 11:18:18 determine if the variables are mean reverting, that is if they are predictable. The results are vali- dated at their order of integration. The order of integration explains the number of times the series is differenced to achieve stationarity. All the variables are expected to be stationary at I(0) or at most I(1). From this result, it was revealed that the variables are stationary at these levels and at the first difference, which implies a problem of unit root presence among the variables (see Table 6).

Tab. 6 – Unit root Test Results. Source: author´s computation Order of Variable At Level 1st Difference Integration Trend & Trend & None None Intercept Intercept GCF -3.02*** -3.62*** -3.64*** -4.08*** I(0) INFLR -1.85 -2.93 -5.44*** -5.29*** I(1) LNDR -0.19 -2.14 -6.48*** -6.53*** I(1) CAD 0.55 -1.99 -5.83*** -6.07*** I(1) CES -0.41 -3.40 -7.50*** -7.45*** I(1) CSS -0.63 -2.49 -6.67*** -6.53*** I(1) CTR -1.72 -4.35 -8.45*** -8.27*** I(1) RAD 2.09 -1.81 -5.51*** -7.86*** I(1) RES 0.65 -2.56 -6.08*** -7.09*** I(1) RSS 0.96 -3.45 -6.48*** -7.58*** I(1) RTR 2.76 -2.11 -5.38*** -7.88*** I(1) ***, **, * implies the significance level at 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively.

4.5 Bounds test for the Models For the two models, the F-statistics determined that the greater value was found to be greater than the critical values of I(0) (Lower bound) and I(1) (Upper bound) bounds. This implies that there is a co-integration among the variables (see Table 7 and 8).

Tab. 7 – Bounds test for Capital Expenditure Model. Source: author´s computation Model for Estimation F-Statistics Lower-Upper bound at 5% CAD/CES/CSS/CTR/INFLR/LNDR 5.19* 2.87-4 * implies cointegrating factors at 5% level of significance.

Tab. 8 – Bounds test for Recurrent Expenditure Model. Source: author´s computation Model for Estimation F-Statistics Lower-Upper bound at 5% RAD/RES/RSS/RTR/INFLR/LNDR 6.17* 2.87-3.6 * implies cointegrating factors at 5% level of significance.

145

joc4-2018-v2.indd 145 1.12.2018 11:18:18 4.6 Short run Coefficient Result The results show that capital expenditure had a negative and insignificant impact on private investment in the short-run, which implies that the shocks in private investment in the previous year in Nigeria were corrected by 69% annually by capital expenditure, while recurrent expendi- ture had a positive and significant impact on private investment in the short-run, which implies that approximately 41% of disequilibrium in private investment in the previous period was cor- rected by recurrent expenditure (see Table 9 and 4.10).

Tab. 9 – ECM for Capital Expenditure. Source: author´s computation

Coefficient Std Error t-statistics Prob

ECM(-1) -0.690091 0.592837 -1.164048 0.2569

Tab. 10 – ECM for Recurrent Expenditure. Source: author’s computation

Coefficient Std Error t-statistics Prob

ECM(-1) 0.408228 0.153289 2.663136 0.0136

4.7 Long-run Coefficient Results These results are presented based on the model on the disaggregation of government expendi- ture: Capital and Recurrent expenditure.

Tab. 11 – Long-run Coefficient Result for Capital Expenditure Model. Source: author’s compu- tation

CAD CES CSS CTR INFLR LNDR

Coefficient 0.10 -0.02 -0.01 0.04 -0.06 0.38 t-stat (-3.62) (-1.43) (-0.23) -2.41 (-1.75) (-2.23) Prob 0.002 0.173 0.818 0.029 0.099 0.040

From this result, it was revealed that capital expenditure on economic services and social serv- ices had a negative and insignificant impact on private investment in the long-run, whereas inflation rate also had a negative but significant impact on private investment at a 10% level of significance. Capital expenditure on administration, transfer and lending rates showed a positive and significant impact on private investment at a 5% level of significance. Table 11 presents the long run coefficient result for recurrent expenditure (see Table 11 above).

146 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 146 1.12.2018 11:18:18 Tab. 12 – Long run Coefficient Result for Recurrent Expenditure Model. Source: Author’s Computation

InRAD InRES InRSS InRTR INFLR LNDR Coefficient -4.24 -3.72 2.83 3.19 -0.05 0.05 t-stat (-1.19) (-3.25) -0.99 -1.36 (-1.52) -0.23 Prob 0.257 0.007 0.341 0.199 0.153 0.820 Based on the recurrent expenditure results, it was revealed that recurrent expenditure had a negative and insignificant impact on private investment on administration, while recurrent ex- penditure on economic services had a negative and significant impact on private investment. It was also revealed that recurrent expenditure on social services, transfer, as well as the inflation rate had a positive and insignificant on private investment (see Table 12 above).

5. Discussion This result was found to be in conformity with some previous studies and went against the results of others. In line with Bom (2017), the result divulges that the complex dynamics of pri- vate capital formation, as well as its sensitivity to key parameters and financing mode, may help explain the mixed empirical evidence on the private-public investment relationship. Based on this interpretation, the effect of public spending depends on the type of expenditure. This study diverges from neoclassical theory that government expenditure crowds out private investment. Keynesian approaches project that government expenditure strictly crowds in private invest- ment, a result which is shown in the work of some previous studies in the developing countries such as Omojolaibi (2016), i.e. that capital and recurrent expenditure as a whole crowd in private investment. In conformity with the work of Mohammad et al. (2012), however, the actual impact of government spending on private sector investment varies depending on the type of govern- ment expenditure under consideration. Moreover, having a sound expenditure management and allocation policy together with other fiscal policy is imperative in determining private investment in the developing countries such as Nigeria. Also, in agreement with Fujii et al. (2013), public investment has differential effects in each industry, such as the productive externality of public capital, which consists of accumulating public investment and differences in wealth or shock. They explain that the components of government expenditure display various impacts on the investments in a country, a result which we also found under the same conditions for Nigeria. From the coefficients of the expenditure results, the study also agrees with the work of Nwosa (2013) that the pattern of spending of the government largely determines the functioning of private investment in the economy. This is because one of the major determinants of growth and development is the expenditure pattern of the government of an economy, which private investors consider before investing in the economy in order to avoid loss. In support with the findings of Apere (2014), the study also argued that the Ricardian equivalence theory does not hold in the case of Nigeria, as government expenditure is found to have a great impact on private investment. In support of the Keynesian view, lending rate positively reacts in a low way to pri- vate investment and is not significant. This implies that government expenditure policies in the Nigerian economy greatly influence competiveness among private investors in the economy.

147

joc4-2018-v2.indd 147 1.12.2018 11:18:18 5. CONCLUSION The study investigates the disaggregated effect of government expenditure on private invest- ment in Nigeria from 1981 to 2015 using the ARDL approach. It was observed from the findings that the effect of public expenditure on private investment varies with regard to the components of the expenditure. We therefore conclude that a major determinant of improved private invest- ment in Nigeria is the pattern of government expenditure. Based on these findings, we recommended that an expenditure plan should be designed in such a way that macro-economic variables such as inflation rate and lending rate are taken into con- sideration as a factor that determines the interest of private investors in the economy, since as more is pumped into the economy, prices of goods and services tend to increase as well as savings, which may lead to an increase in the cost of capital as well as discourage investors from investing in the economy, as the cost of capital is high. Therefore, policies toward determining the appropriate amount of funding to release in the economy should be considered in terms of facilitating and increasing private investment.

References 1. Apere, T. O. (2014). The Impact of Public Debt on Private Investment in Nigeria: Evidence from a Nonlinear Model. International Journal of Research in Social Sciences, 4 (2), 130–138. 2. Awolaja, G., Oluwalaiye O. B., Lawal, E. (2015). The Effect of Sectorial Public Investment Expenditure on Private Investment in Nigeria: An Error Correction Analysis. European Journal of Business and Social Sciences, 4 (4), 87–104. 3. Basar, S., & Temurlenk, M. S. (2007). Investigating Crowding-Out Effect of Government Spending For Turkey: A Structural VAR Approach. İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Dergisi, 21 (2), 96–104. 4. Bello, M. Z., Nagwari, A. B., & Saulawa, M. A. (2012). Crowding In Or Crowding Out? Government Spending and Private Investment: The Case of Nigeria. European Scientific Journal, 8 (28), 9–22. http://dx.doi.org/10.19044/esj.2012.v8n28p%25p 5. Bom, P. R. D. (2017). Factor-Biased Public Capital and Private Capital Crowding Out. Journal of , 52 (2017), 100–117. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2017.03.002 6. Dada, M. A. (2013). Composition Effects of Government Expenditure on Private Consumption and Output Growth in Nigeria: a Single-Equation Error Correction Modeling. Romanian Journal of Fiscal Policy, 42 (7), 18–34. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/107949 7. Dreger, C., & Reimers, H. E. (2016). Does public investment stimulate private investment? Evidence for the euro area. Economic Modelling, 58, 154–158. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.econmod.2016.05.028 8. Ferris, J. S., & Voia, M. C. (2015). The effect of federal government size on private economic performance in Canada: 1870–2011. Economic Modelling, 49, 172–185. https://doi. org/10.1016/j.econmod.2015.04.006 9. Fujii, T., Hiraga, K., & Kozuka, M. (2013). Effects of public investment on sectoral private investment: A factor augmented VAR approach. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 27, 35–47. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jjie.2012.11.003

148 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 148 1.12.2018 11:18:18 10. Haliu, F. (2015). Crowding in or Crowding out? Government Expenditure and Private Investment in Ethiopia (1980-2012). Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development, 6 (9), 59–66.

11. Ho, Thug-W. (2001). The Government Spending and Private Consumption: A Panel Co- integration Analysis. International Review of Economics and Finance, 10, 95–108. https://doi. org/10.1016/S1059-0560(00)00073-3

12. Jalloh, M. (2002). An Analysis of the Macroeconomic Determinants of Private Investment in Sierra Leone. Addis Ababa University School of Graduate Studies, 1, 78–81.

13. Jorgenson, D. W. (1963). Capital Theory and Investment Behaviour. American Economic Review, 53 (2), 247–259. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1823868

14. Jorgensen, D. (1967). The Theory of Investment Behaviors, in Determinants of Investment. National Bureau of Economic Research, 129–155. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c1235

15. Jorgenson, D. W. (1971). Econometric studies of investment behaviour: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 1111–1147. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2721137

16. Kollamparambil, U., & Nicolaou, M. (2011). Nature and association of public and private investment: Public policy implications for South Africa. Journal of Economics and International Finance, 3 (2), 98–108.

17. Mahoudzadeh, M. Sadeghi, S., & Sadeghi S. (2013). Fiscal Spending and Crowding out Effect: A Comparison between Developed and Developing Countries. Institutions and Economies, 5 (1), 31–40. http://ajba.um.edu.my/index.php/ijie/article/view/4873

18. Majumder, A. (2007). Does Public Borrowing Crowd-out Private Investment? The Bangladesh Evidence. Policy Analysis Unit (PAU). Working Paper Series: WP 0708. 2–26.

19. Malik, A. (2013). Private Investment and Fiscal Policy in Pakistan. Journal of Economic Development, 38 (1), 89–91.

20. Muhammad, Z. B., Aminu, B. N., & Mubarak, A. S. (2012). Crowding In Or Crowding Out? Government Spending and Private Investment: The Case of Nigeria. European Scientific Journal (ESJ), 8 (28). http://dx.doi.org/10.19044/esj.2012.v8n28p%25p

21. Narayan, P. K., (2004). Do public investments crowd out private investments? Fresh evidence from Fiji. Journal of Policy Modeling, 26, 747–753. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.jpolmod.2004.06.002

22. Nwosa P. I., Adebiyi O. O., & Adedeji A.O. (2013): An Analysis of the Relationship between Public Spending Components and Private Investments in Nigeria. Journal of Finance & Economics, 1 (2), 14–27.

23. Omojolaibi, J. A., Okenesi, T. P., & Mesagan, E. P. (2016). Fiscal Policy and Private Investment in Selected West African Countries. CBN Journal of Applied Statistics, 7(1b), 277–309.

24. Rahman, M., Ullah, I., & Jebran, K. (2015). Effects of Government Expenditure on Private Investment: Evidence from Pakistan. Journal of Basic and Applied Scientific Research, 5 (2), 14–23.

149

joc4-2018-v2.indd 149 1.12.2018 11:18:18 25. Sineviciene, L., & Railiene, G. (2015). The Nexus between Government Size, Tax Burden and Private Investment. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, 213, 485–490. https://doi. org/10.1016/j.sbspro.2015.11.438 26. Sineviciene, L., & Vasiliauskaite, A. (2012). Fiscal Policy Interaction with Private Investment: The Case of the Baltic States. Inzinerine Ekonomika-, 23 (3), 233–241. http://dx.doi.org/10.5755/j01.ee.23.3.1934 27. Sinevičienė, L. (2015). Testing the Relationship between Government Expenditure and Private Investment: The Case of Small Open Economies. Journal of Economics, Business and Management, 3 (6), 628–632. http://dx.doi.org/10.7763/JOEBM.2015.V3.256

Contact information

Olawunmi Omitogun, PhD. Olabisi Onabanjo University,Ogun State, Nigeria Faculty of Social Sciences Department of Economics Nigeria Email: [email protected]

150 Journal of Competitiveness

joc4-2018-v2.indd 150 1.12.2018 11:18:18