<<

Financial Crowding Out Theory with an Application to Australia

ANDREW FELTENSTEIN*

HE AIM OF THIS PAPER is to analyze the extent to which public Tspending crowds out private production and capital formation. The analysis is carried out within the context of an intertemporal general equilibrium model, and a computational version of the model is developed and applied to Australia. The approach is especially relevant for policy analysis because it allows the con- sideration of disaggregated fiscal measures, such as changes in individual tax rates, and at the same time incorporates macro- economic aspects of , such as rules for deficit financing and the interaction between deficits, interest rates, and . In addition, by disaggregating the private sector, a comparison can be made of the extent to which individual indus- tries are affected by public sector spending policies. Crowding out has usually been examined in two different but related contexts. In the first, the public sector purchases large quantities of goods and them either by taxes or by borrowing. To the extent that the goods purchased are used to produce public goods, they will no longer be available for private sector production, which will therefore be forced to decline. The second context is "financial crowding out," which occurs when the government in- creases its borrowing requirements and thereby drives up the . Credit is thus made more expensive for the private sector, which is forced to curtail any capital formation that is not

* Mr. Feltenstein, a Senior in the Country Policy Department of The World Bank, was a member of the Fiscal Affairs Department of the Fund when this paper was written. Most of the research was carried out while the author was visiting the University of Melbourne, and a theoretical version of the paper was written while he was at the Stockholm School of . He would like to thank Lars Bergman, Willem Buiter, Ken Clements, Allan Powell, John Shoven, and Nicholas Stern for many helpful suggestions. The views expressed here do not necessarily represent those of The World Bank or the Fund. 60

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 61 self-financed. (Indirect crowding out may also occur because ris- ing interest rates may cause current consumption, and hence de- mand for the output of the private sector, to fall.) Financial crowding out has traditionally been analyzed within the context of aggregative macroeconomic models.1 There are severe limitations, however, to this approach. Borrowing require- ments differ among industries, so that one would also expect the effect of the government's borrowing on the private sector to vary. The aggregation of also precludes any analysis of the relative effects of fiscal policies on the of different con- sumer groups. In addition, because models are usually valid only for small changes, it is difficult, if not impossible, to estimate the effects of large increases in government borrowing. Finally, gov- ernments often attempt to increase tax revenue and borrowing simultaneously. Because aggregative macroeconomic models do not normally separate tax revenues from government expendi- ture, such policies cannot be dealt with properly.2 The question of resource crowding out is increasingly being examined within the framework of computational general equi- librium models of taxation. Such models, originally inspired by the work of Harberger (1962, 1966) on tax incidence, have been developed in Shoven and Whalley (1972, 1973), Shoven (1976), Fullerton (1982, 1983), Fullerton and others (1981), Miller and Spencer (1977), Piggott and Whalley (1983), Feltenstein (1983), and Whalley (1975, 1977, 1982), among others, to examine inci- dence and welfare implications of changes in tax and trade regimes. The advantages of these models in comparison with macroeconomic ones have been discussed at length in Shoven (1983); among them is the ability to deal with large changes in government policies, with disaggregated taxes, and with the analy- sis of the welfare implications of taxation on individual consumer categories. There are, however, a number of disadvantages in computational general equilibrium models. These models have been almost exclusively "real"; that is, the public sector is con- strained to have a balanced budget, owing to the absence of fi- nancial assets that could a deficit. Because there is no 1 Among such models are those of Blinder and Solow (1973, 1974), Brunner and Meltzer (1972), Buiter (1977), Christ (1968), Cohen and McMenamin (1978), Friedman (1978), Grämlich (1971), Infante and Stein (1976), Meyer (1975), Modigliani and Ando (1976), Spencer and Yohe (1970), and Tobin and Buiter (1976). 2 See Tanzi (1978) and Aghevli and Khan (1978) for models which do dis- tinguish between taxes and expenditures.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 62 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN , and hence no price level or interest rate, these models do not allow the analysis of financial crowding out. Research in which certain types of computational general equi- librium models are expanded to include financial assets has been carried out by several authors. Clements (1980) allowed for do- mestic credit expansion in a model of the United States, although such expansion was exogenous with respect to public sector ex- penditure and revenues. Feltenstein (1980), in a model of Argen- tina, permitted the existence of domestic and foreign financial assets, whose endogeneity of supply was dependent on the bal- ance of payments. Slemrod (1981) constructed a computational general equilibrium model incorporating portfolio choice by con- sumers. For the policymaker the major flaw in these models is that they do not permit both endogenous public deficits and private investment. The model constructed here is dynamic; it has two periods, with the notion of a past (before period 1) and a future (after period 2). Both consumers and firms have perfect foresight, so that the prices, tax liabilities, and transfers received from the government in period 2 are correctly anticipated in period I.3 The model is closed by assuming that, in period 2, consumers save—that is, hold debt—according to an exogenous savings rate.4 Firms in the private sector are constrained to cover current expenditures by current revenue, but capital formation is financed by the sale of bonds. The government, in contrast, sets its pro- gram of expenditure in real terms and is not required to cover costs from tax revenues; any deficit it incurs is covered by its issuing a combination of money and bonds. The government is sensitive, however, to the effect that its deficits may have on interest and inflation rates. Accordingly, it will gradually cut its spending as real interest and inflation rates rise above prede- termined targets. Consumers are required to hold money to cover transaction costs, and they purchase bonds in order to save for the 3 The model may thus be interpreted as generating a rational expectations equilibrium. The minimum needed to introduce a dynamic framework is two periods, but there would be no difficulty in extending the models to several periods. For a study of perfect foresight equilibria, see Brock and Turnovsky (1981). 4 This "closure" rule is made for purely technical reasons. One must allow for some future after the final period in order to avoid the requirement that in that final period all debt be fully paid off, so that no customer would hold debt. Alternative approaches would be to have infinitely lived consumers, or to intro- duce an overlapping generations structure. The closure rule will, in particular, ensure that the model does not generate Ricardian debt equivalence.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 63 future. With perfect foresight there is no risk, so that to the consumer private and government bonds are identical. The equi- librium condition on privately issued debt is that new capital pro- duced in period 1, which comes on line in period 2, must yield a return in period 2 equal to the obligations on the bonds that financed it. The government, in contrast, must add the debt obli- gations incurred in period 1 and coming due in period 2 to its current expenditures in the period. Consumers maximize intertemporal utility functions and derive a demand for bonds as a method of saving. As the interest rate rises, consumers tend to satisfy the Fisherian relation and shift their consumption to the future, releasing resources to the govern- ment. The private sector may thus suffer from both resource and financial crowding out.5 The model includes profit, income, and sales taxes and allows for direct transfer payments by the government to consumers. The price level is endogenous, so that the inflationary effects of vari- ous government policies may be analyzed. There is also an invest- ment function, with the level of investment being driven by the interest rate. Section I presents a formal description of the model, and Section II describes a computational version of the model and its application to Australian data. This exercise should serve not only to illustrate the workings of the model but also to allow certain qualitative judgments about Australian fiscal policies. Sec- tion III presents conclusions, a few qualifications, and some direc- tions for further research.

I. The Model In this section a formal description is given for production, consumption, government finance, and investment, as well as for the conditions of intertemporal equilibrium.

Production

The structure of production is Leontief in intermediate and final production, whereas value added is produced by smooth

5 The model does not, however, yield a mechanical one-to-one correspon- dence between public deficits and crowding out because the rising interest rate will not only have the above-mentioned effects but may also increase the overall level of private savings.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 64 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN production functions.6 Because the model incorporates perfect foresight in both production and consumption, production may be represented by a nonstochastic block-diagonal matrix whose com- ponents refer to goods that are different in their dating (see Debreu (1959) for a discussion of the use of dated commodities). If goods i = l,...,N refer to goods produced in period 1, and goods N + 1,...,2N refer to goods produced in period 2, then the structure of the production matrix for intermediate and final goods is

(1) The upper block of the matrix refers to first-period production, the lower block to second-period production. Corresponding to each activity is a continuous function fj(Ki,Li) that produces value added for the y'th activity using capital and labor from the corresponding stocks that exist in period i. To be specific, assume that the value-added functions are Cobb-Douglas in nature, hence of the form (2)

In addition, there are investment activities, H¿(Ki , L, ), that operate in period ¿, using inputs of capital and labor existing in that period, and that produce capital goods for period i + I.7 The investment is carried out by the private sector. Because the capital that is produced in one period becomes available only in the next, the investment firm must pay for the input costs of its production in the current period but will receive the revenue from that capital in the next period.8 To simplify demonstration of the existence of

6 This formulation is used because of the eventual goal of an empirical applica- tion and has been described in greater detail in, for example, Fullerton and others (1981) and Feltenstein (1980). 7 The investment function could also require intermediate and final goods as inputs, but for simplicity of exposition it will require only capital and labor. 8 It would also be possible to have investment activities distinguished by firms if firm-specific capital were available, as in specifications by Fullerton (1983) and Dervis, De Meló, and Robinson (1982).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 65 an equilibrium, it is assumed that the investment functions exhibit decreasing returns to scale9 and are of the form

(3) Capital in period 2 is then given by the depreciated initial capital stock, plus whatever new capital has been produced in period 1. If KQ is the initial stock of capital at the beginning of period 1, is the rate of depreciation, and L0 is the initial stock of labor, then (4) where K2 is the stock of capital at the beginning of period 2. The government also produces public goods through a smooth production function that uses capital and labor of the current period as inputs.10 Let Qi(Ki, L/) denote this function in period i and, for simplicity, also assume the function to be Cobb-Douglas in nature; hence, (5) The government is assumed to determine, at the beginning of period i, the real level of output of public goods to be produced: (6) where is the real quantity of public goods to be produced in period i, in-such a way as to minimize the cost of production.

Consumption

There is a single generation of consumers who live for the entire period of the model. Because they may have initial endowments of capital and financial assets, it is implicitly supposed that they

9 Decreasing returns to scale will allow the derivation of a single-valued in- vestment response. If desired, one could choose the parameters such that , with arbitrarily small. Any investment function with de- creasing returns to scale would be equally acceptable. 10 Rather than having the government operate its own production function, it would also be possible to have the government buy directly from the private sector. Introducing a government production function allows, however, the di- rect representation of changing public policy toward the relative importance of hiring capital or labor. If, for example, the government wished to increase employment, it could, in the model, change the weights given to capital and labor in its production function. A more sophisticated version of the model would have public goods enter consumers' utility functions directly, or increase productivity.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 66 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN were alive before period 1. The consumers perfectly anticipate all prices of period 2 while in period I.11 The individual consumer maximizes a utility function, t/, that has as arguments the levels of consumption in each of the two periods.12 Thus, (7) where xt (with ) refers to the /th consumption good in period 1, Xi (with ) refers to the ith consumption good in period 2, and LÍ refers to consumption of leisure in period i. To be specific, the utility function is assumed to be of the form (8) Suppose that (d¡) reflect the consumer's rate of time preference u, uniformly across goods, so that

(9) in addition, u is uniform across all consumers. Hence, leisure enters the utility function, but money, bonds, and capital do not.13 The consumer maximizes his utility function, subject to a set of intertemporal budget constraints, and it is assumed that capital markets are imperfect in that consumers cannot borrow against future income. A consumer has an initial allocation of money and bonds, and , at the beginning of period 1; if he is a shareholder in the capital goods-producing firm, the consumer 15 will also hold capital, . Let pKi, pLi, pm, andpBi represent the 11A rational expectations equilibrium is being defined in which consumers' expectations of period 2 are perfectly fulfilled. If the model contained more than two periods, it would be quite possible that information available for the time period after period 2 mignt be used to determine the consumers' choices in periods 1 ana 2. 12There are consumers in the model; to avoid unreadable subscripts, however, the consumer demand parameters will not be indexed. It should be noted that these parameters, along with initial allocations, are not uniform across consumers. One might also wish to include public goods in the consumers' utility function, although that has not been done here. 13 Proof of the existence of equilibrium does not depend on this form of the utility function; any continuous utility function would be valid. This particular form permits an analytic solution to the demand function. 14 Another approach—for example, in Grandmont (1977) and Grandmont and Laroque (1975)-—is to have consumers borrow from the central bank against future income but to have no borrowing by the central bank. Several technical problems are involved with allowing borrowing to go in both directions, which essentially is equivalent to the requirement of irreversibility of production. 15 It will be assumed that initial holdings of bonds, BQ, are entirely composed of government debt. Initial private debt would be inconsistent with the specified intertemporal investment decision.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 67 prices of capital, labor, money, and bonds, respectively, in period i, and let TR¿ represent whatever transfer payments the govern- ment pays to consumers during period i, whereas represents this particular consumer's share in those transfers. Bonds are considered to be long term, so that a consumer owning a bond receives its par value as an interest payment in each period that he owns the bond. Because this payment is made in units of money, his income from the bond in period i is pMi. He also has the possibility of selling the bond at prices pBi. The consumer's income in period 1, /i(pi), is then given by

(10) In addition, the consumer has a second-period budget con- straint. If he has purchased quantity xm of bonds in period 1, he then receives the coupon value of those bonds in units of money in period 2, this being equal to/?M2*£i. The consumer's income in period 2, /2(/?2), then becomes (n) where XM\ is the quantity of money that the consumer holds in period I.16 The consumer, in solving his utility-maximization problem, has two simultaneous budget constraints, as well as a closure rule to be described shortly. Suppose that the consumer faces ad valorem taxes on his purchases of consumption goods, and let

(12) where tt represents the vector of tax rates levied on the N inter- mediate and final goods produced in period /. Further, (13) denote the prices of the intermediate and final goods in each of the two periods. The consumer has, in addition, a money demand

16 The interpretation of the price of capital in capital /, pKi, is that it is a rental rather than a sales, or cost of production, price. There is no secondary market for capital, since the conditions on private investment are such that the rate of return on capital is always identically equal to the interest rate. Thus all savings decisions are made by purchases of bonds, and capital gains are realized by the sale of bonds.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 68 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN function, uniform across all consumers, in which demand for nom- inal cash balances depends on the value of current consumption and the nominal interest rate. Leisure is not included as a deter- minant in the because income taxes are with- held at the source. Suppose now that vf, the velocity of money, is not constant but is a function of the nominal interest rate. The nominal interest rate in period /, rt, is defined by (14) Suppose also that

(15) so that the velocity of money is directly related to the nominal interest rate. Hence, (16) or, in a somewhat more familiar form, (17) The total value of the consumer's consumption in period 1 and period 2 must be equal to or less than the corresponding income; hence (18) where PMÍ*MÍ is given by equation (16) and //(/?/) is given by equations (10) and (11). To close the model, some assumption must be made about consumers' holding debt in period 2. Accord- ingly, suppose that demand for bonds in period 2 is equal to the long-run savings rate of the economy, assumed to be constant. Thus, (19) where 1/z is equal to the long-run savings rate. One thus avoids making the assumption, equivalent to debt neutrality, that the consumer supposes that the portion of his savings held in govern- ment debt must eventually be repaid by higher taxes. The following maximization problem for the consumer there- fore results: (20)

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 69 such that

(21a)

(21b)

(21c) It is straightforward to solve equations (21) in the form of a Lagrangian to obtain the following solution:

(22)

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 70 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

The demand for money, xMi, is given by equation (16), whereas the demand for bonds, xBi, is derived from Walras's law in each period as

Having calculated the individual consumer's demand for all goods plus financial assets in each period, one may turn to the derivation of aggregate supply and, accordingly, excess demand functions.

Financing the Central Government and the Formation of Capital

Using the individual industry's value-added functions given in equation (2), cost-minimizing levels of the use of capital and labor for the yth sector in period i are obtained:

(23) where tKi and tLi represent the tax rates levied on capital and labor, assumed to be uniform across sectors, in the ith period, and VA, represents the required inputs of value added, in real terms, to the ;th sector. The interpretation of tKi is a profit tax levied on capital, whereas tLi may be thought of as an income tax that is collected at the source—that is, a withholding tax. The nominal value added, vdj, is given by

(24) and intertemporal Leontief prices, p (p), may be calculated as (25) Total demand for the/th intermediate and final good, xL¡, may be derived as (26)

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 71 where ;c; is the kth consumer's demand for intermediate or final goody, as in equation (22). The vector of activity levels, w, of the 2N activities required to produce this level of demand may then be derived as

(27)

Let yKpj, yLpj be the corresponding requirements of column / for capital and labor and let yKpi, yLpi be the total requirements for capital and labor by private industry in period i. The total taxes, TÍ , collected by the central government in each of the two periods may now be calculated. The government uses capital and labor to produce public goods in each of the two periods. Suppose that the real quantity of these public goods is given by Qi,Q2> The government has a Cobb- Douglas production function, given in equation (6). From this function may be derived the cost-minimizing quantities of capital and labor, yKGl>, yLGi, used by the government in producing Q¡, and the total cost to the government, G/, of producing Q¿. The deficit of the central government in period 1, Dl, is then given by (28) so that if D i is negative the government runs a surplus. It is assumed that a surplus is paid out as transfer payments to con- sumers, but financing must take place in the case of a deficit.17 Here one must first make a connection between real interest rates and the level of the government's real expenditures. It is possible for a particular program of expenditures to be technologically feasible—in the sense that it does not require inputs of capital or labor beyond the capacities of the economy—yet at the same time to lead to a deficit representing a level of real debt greater than what people are willing to hold. To avoid this problem of an unbounded supply of money and bonds, a functional relationship will be imposed between the real level of government expenditure and the instantaneous and rate of inflation. Accordingly, define Q/ in the following way: let ht be a continuous

17 These transfer payments are not identically equal to the sum of the transfer payments included in the consumer's budget constraints, although at equilibrium they will be.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 72 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN function and some fixed, target level of output of public goods, and let be the rate of inflation in the ith period.18 Thus,

(29) Real output of public goods will therefore be equal to the initial target if both the rate of inflation and the real interest rate RÍ are below corresponding target rates. As the real interest or inflation rates rise above target, the level of real government output of public goods approaches zero. The resultant deficit, given by equation (28), is financed by a combination of money and bonds. Accordingly, let yBGi be the government's bond issue in period 1, and let B¿ be a continuous function such that

(30) Thus, the nominal value of bond financing is a continuous func- tion of the nominal deficit, not including debt repayment, and no sale of bonds takes place if there is a surplus. The change in the supply of money, , is then given by (31) so that debt repayment is made in money. In period 2 the formation of the government deficit is somewhat different, since the government must pay not only for its current consumption but also for its debt obligations incurred in period 1. Accordingly, (32)

18 Here , where CP7, is a weighted average of the period-/ Leontief prices. It may be assumed that is exogenous (in practice, taken to be the actual inflation rate in that year).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 73

Of course Bl would equal B2 if the government chooses to main- tain the same financing rule in period 2 as in period I.19 It is assumed that capital formation is carried out by the private sector and that it is fully financed by the sale of bonds, which are identical to the bonds sold by the government. Suppose, then, that the rate of return on capital in period .20 The total return on quantity H/ of new capital that was formed in period i and that comes on line in period i + 1 is then/?*(/+1> H¡. If CHi is the cost-minimizing cost of producing Ht, then future debt obligations must be equal to the return on capital. Hence, (33) The investment firm, having found a level of investment H¿ such that Hi, CHi satisfy equation (31), then sets its sale of bonds, yBpi : (34)

Excess Demand Functions and the Conditions for Intertemporal Equilibrium

The presence of an intertemporal input-output matrix allows the vector of excess demand functions to be confined to the space of prices corresponding to capital, labor, money, bonds, and transfer payments, indexed by their time period. Accordingly, given an arbitrary vector of prices, p, the nominal value added per unit of output may be derived for each of the 2N sectors producing intermediate and final goods, as in equation (24). Equation (25) then gives Leontief prices for each of the two periods, and equa- tions (26) and (27) give total demand for intermediate and final goods, along with the corresponding level of production required of each activity in the Leontief matrix. The total inputs of capital and labor required in each period by the private production sec- tor and the government may also be derived. The requirements of capital and labor in each period also in- clude their use in investment, which is determined by equations (3) and (33). The total supplies of the capital and labor in period i—that is, yKi9yu—are then 19Thus, the interest obligations incurred by the government in period 1 are paid off in period 2 in units of money, rather than being rolled over in new bond sales. This form of payment is not essential to the model, but it does allow a simpler proof of the boundedness of the supply of bonds in period 2. 20 For i =2, assume that

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 74 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

(35) where are the aggregate inputs to public and private pro- duction and investment in period /, and HI is the level of real investment in period 1. The change in the money supply in period /, is given by equation (31), so that the total supply of money in each period, y MÍ, is (36)

The supply of bonds in each period, yBi, is given by (37) where yBGi is the government's bond issue in period /, and yBpi is private bond issue for investment financing. An aggregate supply vector y has now been derived, where (38) This supply vector is augmented by two additional dimensions, corresponding to transfer payments in each of the two time pe- riods. Accordingly, define >>(/?), the augmented supply vector, by

(39) where D¡ is the government deficit in period /. The derivation of an augmented demand vector x(p) is now straightforward. Because xKi = 0 and because equation (30) gives individual for leisure, money, and bonds in each pe- riod, summing across consumers gives the aggregate demands, The vector x is then defined by (40) Finally, the augmented demand vector x(p) is defined by (41) where TR¡ represents the proxy for government transfer payments that enters the consumer's maximization problem, as in equations (21). The aggregate excess demand function u(p) is then defined as

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 75

(42) therefore it must be shown that there exists some price p* such that

II. An Application to Australia

The Australian economy is a suitable example for application of the model because a trade sector may be introduced without modifications to the model's theoretical structure. In addition, it is also reasonable to make the assumption of a small country that is a price taker in world trade. To use the model for simulation analysis, it is necessary to demonstrate first that it replicates rea- sonably accurately the Australian economy for a particular bench- mark period. This section will therefore first describe the data used and then will give the results of the benchmark simulation for two successive years. The analysis will then proceed to vari- ous experiments with different rules for financing the govern- ment budget deficit, as well as for the level of real government expenditure. Until late 1982, Australia operated under a system of fixed exchange rates and capital controls. The model simultaneously derives a solution for two periods, so the years 1981-82 have been chosen for the benchmark solution. This choice avoids the prob- lem of having to construct a mechanism for deter- mination, and the capital account may be treated as exogenous. The model's technology for Australia is represented by a 30-by-30 input-output matrix, constructed for 1977, in which activities 29 and 30 are complementary and competing imports, respectively (Australia, Bureau of Statistics (1983)). The matrix was not up- dated for 1981 and 1982. The model's technology is thus repre- sented by a 60-by-60 block-diagonal matrix. The coefficients for the Cobb-Douglas functions representing production of value added in each period are given by the relative shares of capital and labor in each activity in the 1977 matrix (Australia, Bureau of Statistics (1983, Table 11)), with no technological change assumed between periods. Coefficients for capital and labor in the invest- ment function are also derived from relative shares of capital and labor aggregated across industries, as inputs to investment (Aus- tralia, Bureau of Statistics (1983, Table 18)). The resultant coeffi- cients—at, bt as in equation (3)—are

21 The proof of this result is available from the author upon request.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 76 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

(43) where the subscripts 1 and 2 refer to 1981 and 1982, respectively, here and in what follows. Thus, capital has a larger share as an input to investment than does labor, and no change in technology is assumed between periods. In computation, the coefficients are scaled proportionally so as to be slightly less than unity. Targets for real government expenditure on goods and services, as a percentage of gross national product (GNP), are taken to be the actual values for 1981-82 (Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 2.1)). Accordingly, (44) The coefficients for the government production of public goods function—ßf, 1 - ßf as in equation (5)—are derived by simply deducting the government wage bill from total government ex- penditures (Australia, Bureau of Statistics (1984b, Tables 1 and 25)). The corresponding coefficients for capital, ß, , in the two periods are thus (45) Finally, the rate of depreciation of capital—8 as in equation (4)—is taken to be ,22 The net effective rate of sales taxes was chosen to represent the uniform sales tax rate across sectors. This simplification seems justified because the Australian tax system charges uniform sales tax rates on all goods except private motor vehicles and certain household durables. The sales tax rates, t¡, in period i across sectors (Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 2.30)) are thus (46)

The tax rate on labor use, tu (an income tax withheld at the source), is taken to be the average personal income tax rate. The tax rate on capital, fe/, is taken to be the corporate income tax rate, which is a flat rate in Australia. The corresponding rates (Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 2.29)) are thus (47)

22 This figure is taken from the ORANI general equilibrium model of Australia (see Dixon and others (1982)).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 77

The tariff rate on complementary imports is zero, but on com- peting imports it was 0.16 in 1981 and 0.15 in 1982, uniformly across goods (Australia, Bureau of Statistics (1984a, Table 13)). The model has three consumer categories: high-income Austra- lian, low-income Australian, and rest of world. One first needs to derive initial allocations of capital, labor, money, and bonds for each of these categories. Initial allocations are taken to be hold- ings at the end of 1980. Total initial allocations of capital and labor are taken to be the aggregate gross operating surplus and the total wage bill for 1980. Thus, a unit of capital or labor is defined as that which earned $A 1 in 1980 (Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 5.5)). It is assumed that this income is divided entirely among Australian consumers, with shares derived from survey data giving sources of income by income level (Aus- tralia, Bureau of Statistics (1981, Table 11)). Initial holdings of money were, for the Australian consumers, taken to be the stock of M2 at the end of 1980 (International Monetary Fund (1984)). The shares in this stock of money were assumed to be equal to the relative shares of wage plus capital income for the two Australian consumer categories. The initial allocation of money for the rest of the value of exports will come about only through changes in Australian export prices. There is no wealth effect for the rest of the world. In particular, changes in the exchange rate are repre- sented by corresponding changes in the rest of the world's initial allocation of money. A 10 percent devaluation would be repre- sented by a 10 percent increase in the rest of the world's initial holdings of money, and there would also be a corresponding in- crease in the quantity of domestic money needed to import one unit of foreign goods. Finally, the initial holdings of bonds by the Australian consumer categories are taken to be the interest obli- gations on Australian government securities on issue in 1980.23 Thus, a bond is defined as that security which earned $A 1 of interest in 1980, corresponding to the definitions of capital and labor in terms of earning flows. The initial allocations are then as shown in Table 1. To obtain budget elasticities for consumption of intermediate and final goods, the addilog estimates of marginal budget shares given in Bewley (1982) were used. These estimates are made for two categories of consumers: those with weekly household in- 23 See Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 2.22). Recall the assumption that there are no outstanding initial holdings of privately issued bonds.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 78 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

Table 1. Initial Allocations (In millions of 1980 Australian dollars)

Australian 1 Australian 2 Rest of Good (Low-Income) (High-Income) the World Capital 9,488 29,477 0 Labor 22,670 39,050 0 Money 15,350 40,410 11,500 Bonds 580 1,810 0 Source: Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984). comes of $A 50 and $A 350 based on 1976 data. The categories of low-income and high-income Australian consumers and the corre- sponding distribution shares are thus made to correspond to the 1980 nominal values of these income levels. There is a somewhat higher level of aggregation in these budget shares than in the input-output matrix, and it was decided to assign input-output categories to each of the consumption categories rather than con- struct a transformation matrix. Marginal budget shares are also treated as being equal to average shares so that marginal shares correspond to the specification of the consumer's utility functions. Average budget shares are taken to be equal in both 1981 and 1982 and are shown in Table 2.24 In addition, there is assumed to be an elastic labor supply, with each Australian consumer having an elasticity of demand for leisure of 5 percent. This figure was not empirically derived but was determined by fitting the overall model to the benchmark years. The final element in the structure of the consumer's demand system is a money demand function, as in equation (16). A partial adjustment mechanism is assumed, whereby the money stock ad- justs with a lag to the level desired by consumers. Accordingly, (48) where M, Af-i are the stocks of broad money in the current and past period, Md is the current quantity of money demanded, and

24 Within a particular consumption category, the elasticities for the input- output sectors are derived from relative consumption shares. Budget shares for the rest of the world are taken to be the shares in total exports of goods of each input-output category.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 79

Table 2. Average Budget Shares (In percent)

Corresponding Input-Output Low-Income High-Income Commodity Sector Australian Australian Rent 24,25 19.6 2.0 Fuel 12 2.2 0.2 Food 1,2,4,5 22.0 5.3 Alcohol, etc. 6 4.4 5.0 Clothing 7,8 8.2 5.8 Durables 9, 10, 11, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 21, 22 8.3 9.5 Health 27 2.7 1.0 Transport 23 15.2 20.9 Recreation 28 8.5 14.4 Miscellaneous 26 9.0 14.2 Source: Bewley (1982).

ß is the unobserved speed of adjustment. Equation (16) converts into logarithmic form as (49) where r is the current interest rate, and C is the nominal value of current private consumption including taxes. Substituting and set- ting oi = 1 allows the condition required for homogeneity to be obtained: (50) Equation (50) was estimated using annual Australian data for the period 1950-82. The interest rate is the nominal yield on short-term (two-year) Australian Treasury bonds (all data come from International Monetary Fund (1984 and various issues)). The resultant equation estimate is

(51) The figures in parentheses are t -statistics; DW is the Durbin- Watson test statistic; R2 is the coefficient of determination. With

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution ou ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

M assumed to equal M_i, the required condition for long-run stability, parameters may then be identified. Thus, (52) Returning to the form of equation (16), , allows one to obtain (53) Values now exist for all required parameters in the model, and attention may turn to the simulation of the benchmark years. A key instrument of government policy that is allowed to be endo- genous to the model is the choice of the mix between money and bonds used to finance the government's budget deficit. It was determined in solving the model that weights of 40 percent money and 60 percent bonds in 1981, and 60 percent money and 40 percent bonds in 1982, yielded the most accurate approximation of the actual macroeconomic variables in those years. A version of Merrill's (1972) fixed-point algorithm was used to solve the model. Merrill's method relies on a shrinking subdivision of the price simplex, and the theoretical structure of the version used here is based on Shoven (1974). The algorithm operates on the space of excess demands for capital, labor, money, bonds, and transfer payments in each of two periods while there is identical market clearing in the markets for intermediate and final goods. A similar methodology is described in Feltenstein (1979). The algorithm stopped when all excess demands were less than 0.1 percent of the corresponding total supply. The initial solution yields equilibrium relative prices for scarce factors and financial assets as shown in Table 3. The interest rate in period i is then defined as the inflation rate in period 2, , is given by

(54)

(There is no definition of an endogenous first-period inflation rate because there is no endogenous price level prior to period 1.) Here pLj is the Leontief price of the ;th intermediate or final good; Wj is the corresponding weight in the Australian gross do- mestic product (GDP) deflator; PMÍ.PBÍ are the ith period prices

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 81

Table 3. Equilibrium Prices, Benchmark Case Price Good (Index numbers)a 1981 Capital 86.7 Labor 80.1 Money 100.0 Bonds 94.6 Transfer payments 0.0 1982 Capital 68.3 Labor 97.1 Money 89.0 Bonds 80.0 Transfer payments 0.0 a Prices are normalized, with the price of 1981 money being the numeraire. In particular, the zero price of transfer payments in both periods indicates that there is a budget deficit. for money and bonds, respectively; goods 1-30 refer to 1981 inter- mediate and final goods; and goods 31-60 refer to 1982 goods. Actual and simulated interest and inflation rates can now be com- pared, as is done in Table 4. National income in period i, GDP,, may then be defined as the value of expenditure in period i in terms of money in period ¿, as in Table 5.

Table 4. Simulated Versus Actual Values for Interest and Inflation Rates, Benchmark Case (In percent)

Item Simulated Actual 1981 Interest rate3 5.8 11.5 Inflation rateb 10.0 10.0 1982 Interest rate 11.3 13.1 Inflation rate 11.2 10.4 aThe two-year Australian Treasury bill rate is used for the actual figures. See Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 2.27). bThe 1981 simulated inflation rate is taken to have its actual value for the purpose of the conditions for boundedness in equation (29).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 82 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

Table 5. Simulated Versus Actual Values, Benchmark Case In Billions of Australian Dollars In Percentage of GDP Item Simulated Actual Simulated Actual 1981 GDP 130.8a 130.8 100.0 100.0 Tax revenues15 43.0 45.2 32.8 34.6 Government expenditure0 48.0 49.8 36.7 38.0 Budget surplus (deficit) -5.0 -4.6 -3.9 -3.5 Gross private investment0 20.8 21.7 15.9 16.6 Exports of goods0 20.0 18.7 15.3 14.3 Imports of goodsd 22.8 19.2 17.4 14.7 Trade balance -2.8 -0.5 -2.1 -0.4 1982 GDP 149.8 147.9 100.0 100.0 Tax revenues5 50.9 52.6 34.0 35.6 Government expenditure15 57.0 57.4 38.1 38.8 Budget surplus (deficit) -6.1 -4.8 -4.1 -3.2 Gross private investment0 21.4 26.9 14.3 18.2 Exports of goods0 18.7 19.1 12.5 12.9 Imports of goodsd 25.9 22.4 17.3 15.1 Trade balance -7.2 -3.3 -4.8 -2.2 aThe simulated figures are normalized so that 1981 simulated and actual (GDP) are equal. bSee Norton, Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia (1984, Table 2.1). °Ibid. (Table 5.7a). dlbid. (Table 1.1).

Table 5 shows that the model gives a reasonably close approxi- mation of the actual outcomes in Australia for 1981-82.25 The difference between the model's results and those normally re- ported in applied general equilibrium work is also noteworthy. Interest and inflation rates are particular to this model, as are budget deficits financed by money and bonds and balance of payments deficits financed by losses in reserves. The model, of course, also generates supply of and demand for scarce factors and financial assets, as well as intermediate and final goods, in- dexed by time period.

25 That the simulated interest rate in 1981 is lower than the corresponding actual rate is primarily a result of the decision to take the initial allocation of bonds as comprising only outstanding government debt and not incorporating private debt. Inclusion of initial private debt (which, as a fixed cost, is technically not feasible) would tend to lower the 1981 price of bonds and raise the interest rate.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 83

The analysis turns to two counterfactual simulations. For the first example, suppose that a single change has taken place: in both 1981 and 1982, the target for government expenditure as a percentage of GDP has risen by 10 percent. Thus, government expenditures on goods and services are targeted at 38.4 percent of GDP in 1981 and 39.0 percent in 1982. The solution shown in Table 6 for the macroeconomic variables is the result. Note from Table 6 that, compared with the benchmark case, both real and nominal interest rates have increased sharply in response to higher government deficit financing. As might be expected, the rate of inflation has risen, and the trade balance and budget deficit have deteriorated. The rate of growth in real GDP has risen from 3.3 percent in the initial example to 3.9 percent in this case, whereas gross private investment has remained approx- imately constant as a percentage of GDP. The reason for this apparent absence of crowding out can be seen by observing the equilibrium relative prices for factors and financial assets, pre- sented in Table 7.

Table 6. Counterfactual Simulation 1:10 Percent Increase in 1981 1982 In In In In billions of percent- billions of percent- In Australian age In Australian age Item percent dollars of GDP percent dollars of GDP Interest rate 14.7 23.0 — Inflation 3 rate 17.2 — — 17.8 — — GDP — 153.6 100.0 — 187.0 100.0 Tax revenues — 51.1 33.3 — 64.6 34.6 Government expenditure — 60.6 39.5 — 78.8 42.2 Budget surplus (deficit) — -9.5 -6.2 — -14.2 -7.6 Gross private investment — 22.1 16.1 — 26.9 14.4 Exports of goods — 20.0 13.0 — 18.6 10.0 Imports of goods — 25.5 16.6 — 30.7 16.4 Trade balance — -5.5 -3.6 — -12.1 -6.4 aThe inflation rate is calculated with respect to the price level generated in the benchmark simulation (see Table 3).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 84 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

Table 7. Equilibrium Prices Under Counterfactual Simulation I (Index numbers)

Price Price Good (Benchmark) (Simulation I) 1981 Capital 86.7 105.8 Labor 80.1 97.5 Money 100.0 100.0 Bonds 94.6 87.2 Transfer payments — — 1982 Capital 68.3 79.3 Labor 97.1 111.0 Money 89.0 79.0 Bonds 80.0 64.2 Transfer payments — —

The money prices of capital and labor have risen relative to the benchmark case. In particular, the higher wage rate has caused the supply of labor to increase. This outcome depends critically, however, on the choice of an elastic labor supply. The higher price of capital in 1982 indicates that, although the cost of investment has risen (reflected by the higher interest rate), the rate of return on capital has also risen, and the two changes approximately cancel each other out. There is also a demand effect as the higher interest rate causes consumers to reduce their money holdings, increasing consumption. Thus, tax revenues have increased as a percentage of GDP; that is, an inflation tax is evident. For the final example, suppose that government expenditure on goods and services stays the same in real terms as in the bench- mark case, the results of which are reported in Table 5, but that the government's rule for financing its budget deficit changes. Under the new rule, 100 percent of the deficit will be financed by the sale of bonds, so that the deficit is not monetized. This exam- ple will indicate whether changes in financing rules can have an impact on the real economy, and the results are presented in Table 8. The rate of growth of real GDP is 3.4 percent, or approximately what it was in the benchmark case. Note that the nominal and real interest rates have risen, the latter somewhat more than in the case of increased government spending. Gross private investment

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 85 as a percentage of GDP has fallen in both years, compared with the benchmark case, primarily because there has been insufficient demand stimulus and corresponding increased returns on capital to outweigh the increased interest costs to investors. Thus, a mod- erate degree of crowding out of the private sector does take place under a government deficit wholly financed by bonds.

III. Conclusions and Qualifications The paper has presented an intertemporal general equilibrium model that can be used to analyze crowding out of the private sector. The model is disaggregated in both production and con- sumption and assumes perfect foresight for all agents. For a trac- table empirical application, the model posits a time horizon of two periods with a single generation of consumers, although there would be no difficulty in extending the model to multiple periods. Private investment is financed wholly by debt and competes for private savings with government debt, which is issued with money to finance the deficit. The exchange rate is fixed, and capital flows

Table 8. Counterfactual Simulation II: 100 Percent Bond-Financed Deficit 1981 1982 In In In In billions of percent- billions of percent- In Australian age In Australian age Item percent dollars of GDP percent dollars of GDP Interest rate 12.7 24.5 — Inflation rate 11.0 — — 16.6 — — GDP — 144.5 100.0 — 174.1 100.0 Tax revenues — 48.0 33.2 — 60.2 34.6 Government expenditure — 52.6 36.4 — 67.2 38.6 Budget surplus (deficit) — -4.6 -3.2 — -7.0 -4.0 Gross private investment — 22.7 15.7 — 24.3 13.9 Exports of goods — 20.0 13.9 — 18.6 10.7 Imports of goods — 24.6 17.1 — 29.4 16.9 Trade balance — -4.6 -3.2 — -10.8 -6.2

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 86 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN are assumed to be exogenous. A particular closing rule that is not debt neutral was assumed, and an intertemporal equilibrium was proven to exist. A fixed-point algorithm was derived to solve the model, and an application was made to Australian data. A benchmark solution was calculated for 1981-82, the last two years during which the Australian exchange rate was fixed, and yielded a reasonably accurate approximation to the actual outcomes of the Australian economy during those years. Two counterfactual simulations were then carried out. In the first, an increase in government expen- diture brought about a slight increase in real income, with no significant change in the proportion of income allocated to private investment. There was, however, a significant increase in the real interest rate and in the government's budget deficit, as well as a loss in reserves through the trade account. In the second simu- lation, an increase in the debt-financed proportion of the govern- ment's deficit was found to have no significant effect on real income, although there was a decrease in both years in the level of private investment. Thus, a degree of crowding out does take place. The results of the model are quite sensitive to the elasticity of the labor-leisure choice, as well as to the closing rule for holding debt in the second period. Some of the simulation results would not hold in a model with a longer time horizon. In particular, continued increases in government expenditure and deficit would not continue to stimulate real income as inflation accelerates. Future research, therefore, might extend the time horizon, possi- bly in the form of an intergenerational model, as well as introduce a and an endogenous capital account.

REFERENCES

Aghevli, Bijan B., and Mohsin S. Khan, "Government Deficits and the Infla- tionary Process in Developing Countries," Staff Papers, International Mon- etary Fund (Washington), Vol. 25 (September 1978), pp. 383-416. Australia, Bureau of Statistics, Income Distribution Australia, 1978-79: Individ- uals (Canberra, 1981). , Australian : Input-Output Tables, 1977-78 (Canberra, 1983). (1984a), Customs and Excise Revenue Australia, Annual Summary Tables, 1982-83 (Canberra). (1984b), Australian National Accounts: National Income and Expenditure (Canberra).

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 87

Bewley, R.A., "On the Functional Form of Engel Curves: The Australian Household Expenditure Survey, 1975-76," Economic Record (Melbourne, Australia), Vol. 58 (March 1982), pp. 82-91. Blinder, Alan S., and Robert M. Solow, "Does Fiscal Policy Matter?" Journal of (Amsterdam), Vol. 2 (November 1973), pp. 319-37. , "Analytical Foundations of Fiscal Policy," in The Economics of Public Finance: Essays by Alan S. Blinder and Robert M. Solow, George F. Break, Peter O. Steiner, Dick Netzer (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1974), pp. 3-115. Brock, William A., and Stephen J. Turnovsky, "The Analysis of Macroeconomic Policies in Perfect Foresight Equilibrium," International Economic Review (Osaka), Vol. 22 (February 1981), pp. 179-209. Brunner, Karl, and Allan H. Meltzer, "Money, Debt, and Economic Activity," Journal of (Chicago), Vol. 80 (September-October 1972), pp. 837-51. Buiter, Willem H., "'Crowding Out' and the Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy," Journal of Public Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 7 (June 1977), pp. 309-28. Christ, Carl F., "A Simple Macroeconomic Model with a Government Budget Restraint," Journal of Political Economy (Chicago), Vol. 76 (January- February 1968), pp. 53-67. Clements, Kenneth W., "A General Equilibrium Econometric Model of the Open Economy," International Economic Review (Osaka), Vol. 21 (June 1980), pp. 69-88. Cohen, Darrel, and J. Stuart McMenamin, "The Role of Fiscal Policy in a Financially Disaggregated Macroeconomic Model," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking (Columbus, Ohio), Vol. 10 (August 1978), pp. 322-36. Debreu, Gerard, Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equi- librium (New York: Wiley, 1959). Dervis, Kemal, Jaime De Meló, and Sherman Robinson, General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982). Dixon, Peter B., B.R. Parmenter, J. Sutton, and D.P. Vincent, ORANI: A Multisectoral Model of the Australian Economy (Amsterdam: North- Holland, 1982). Feltenstein, Andrew, "Market Equilibrium in a Model of a Planned Economy of the Soviet Type: A Proof of Existence and Results of Numerical Simu- lations," Review of Economic Studies (Edinburgh, Scotland), Vol. 46 (Octo- ber 1979), pp. 631-52. , "A General Equilibrium Approach to the Analysis of Trade Restric- tions, with an Application to Argentina," Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 27 (December 1980), pp. 749-84. , "A Computational General Equilibrium Approach to the Shadow- Pricing of Trade Restrictions §nd the Adjustment of the Exchange Rate," Journal of Policy Modeling (New York), Vol. 5 (November 1983), pp. 333-61. , "Money and Bonds in a Disaggregated Open Economy," in Applied General Equilibrium Analysis, ed. by H.E. Scarf and J.B. Shoven (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1984), pp. 209-42.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 88 ANDREW FELTENSTEIN

Friedman, Benjamin M., "Crowding Out or Crowding In? The Economic Con- sequences of Financing Government Deficits," Brookings Papers on Eco- nomic Activity: 3 (1978), pp. 593-641. Fullerton, Don, "On the Possibility of an Inverse Relationship Between Tax Rates and Government Revenues," Journal of Public Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 19 (October 1982), pp. 3-22. , "Transition Losses of Partially Mobile Industry-Specific Capital," Quar- terly Journal of Economics (Cambridge, Massachusetts), Vol. 98 (February 1983), pp. 107-25. , and others, "Corporate Tax Integration in the United States: A General Equilibrium Approach," American Economic Review (Nashville, Tennes- see), Vol. 71 (September 1981), pp. 677-91. Grämlich, Edward M., "The Usefulness of Monetary and Fiscal Policy as Dis- cretionary Stabilization Tools," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking (Columbus, Ohio), Vol. 3 (May 1971), pp. 506-32. Grandmont, Jean-Michel, "Temporary General Equilibrium Theory," Econo- metrica (Evanston, Illinois), Vol. 45 (April 1977), pp. 535-72.' , and Guy Laroque, "On Money and Banking," Review of Economic Studies (Edinburgh, Scotland), Vol. 42 (April 1975), pp. 207-36. Harberger, Arnold C., "The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax," Journal of Political Economy (Chicago), Vol. 70 (June 1962), pp. 215-40. , "Efficiency Effects of Taxes on Income from Capital," in Effects of Corporation Income Tax, ed. by Marian Krzyzaniak (Detroit, Michigan: Wayne State University Press, 1966). Infante, Ettore F., and Jerome L. Stein, "Does Fiscal Policy Matter?" Journal of (Amsterdam), Vol. 2 (April 1976), pp. 473-500. International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics (Washington, 1984 and various issues). Jorgenson, Dale W., "Econometric Studies of Investment Behavior: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature (Nashville, Tennessee), Vol. 9 (December 1971), pp. 1111-47. , "Investment and Production: A Review," in Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Vol. 2, ed. by Michael D. Intriligator and David A. Kendrick (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1974), pp. 341-75. , "Econometric Models for General Equilibrium Analysis," in Applied General Equilibrium Analysis, ed. by H.E. Scarf and J.B. Shoven (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983), pp. 139-202. , and James A. Stephenson, "Issues in the Development of the Neo- classical Theory of Investment Behavior," Review of Economics and Statis- tics (Cambridge, Massachusetts), Vol. 51 (August 1969), pp. 346-53. Merrill, Orin H., "Application and Extensions of an Algorithm That Computes Fixed Points of Certain Non-Empty Convex Upper Semi-Continuous Point to Set Mappings" (doctoral dissertation; Ann Arbor: University of Michi- gan, 1972). Meyer, Lawrence H., "The Balance Sheet Identity, the Government Financing Constraint, and the Crowding-Out Effect," Journal of Monetary Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 1 (January 1975), pp. 65-78.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FINANCIAL CROWDING OUT 89

Miller, Marcus H., and John E. Spencer, "The Static Economic Effects of the U.K. Joining the EEC: A General Equilibrium Approach," Review of Economic Studies (Edinburgh, Scotland), Vol. 44 (February 1977), pp. 71-93. Modigliani, Franco, and Albert Ando, "Impacts of Fiscal Actions on Aggregate Income and the Monetarist Controversy: Theory and Evidence," in Monetarism, ed. by Jerome L. Stein (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1976), pp. 17-42. Norton, W.E., P.M. Garmston, and Reserve Bank of Australia, Australian , 1949-50 to 1982-83, Part I: Tables (Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia, 1984). Piggott, John, and John Whalley, Economic Effects of U.K. Tax-Subsidy Poli- cies: A General Equilibrium Appraisal (London: Macmillan, 1983). Shoven, John B., "A Proof of the Existence of a General Equilibrium with ad Valorem Commodity Taxes," Journal of Economic Theory (New York), Vol. 8 (May 1974), pp. 1-25. , "The Incidence and Efficiency Effects of Taxes on Income from Capi- tal," Journal of Political Economy (Chicago), Vol. 84 (December 1976), pp. 1261-83. , "Applied General-Equilibrium Tax Modeling," Staff Papers, Interna- tional Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 30 (June 1983), pp. 394-420. , and John Whalley, "A General Equilibrium Calculation of the Effects of Differential Taxation of Income from Capital in the U.S.," Journal of Public Economics (Amsterdam), Vol. 1 (November 1972), pp. 281-321. , and John Whalley, "General Equilibrium with Taxes: A Computational Procedure and an Existence Proof," Review of Economic Studies (Edin- burgh, Scotland), Vol. 40 (October 1973), pp. 475-89. Slemrod, J., A General Equilibrium Model of Taxation with Endogenous Fi- nancial Behavior, NBER Working Paper 799 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, November 1981). Spencer, Roger W., and William P. Yohe, "The 'Crowding Out' of Private Expenditures by Fiscal Policy Actions," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 52 (October 1970), pp. 12-24. Tanzi, Vito, "Inflation, Real Tax Revenue, and the Case for Inflationary Fi- nance: Theory with an Application to Argentina," Staff Papers, Interna- tional Monetary Fund (Washington), Vol. 25 (September 1978), pp. 417-51. Tobin, James, and Willem H. Buiter, "Long-Run Effects of Fiscal and on Aggregate Demand," in Monetarism, ed. by Jerome L. Stein (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1976), pp. 273-309. Whalley, John, "A General Equilibrium Assessment of the 1973 United King- dom Tax Reform," Económica (London), Vol. 42 (May 1975), pp. 139-61. , "The United Kingdom Tax System 1968-1970: Some Fixed Point Indica- tions of Its Economic Impact," Econometrica (Evanston, Illinois), Vol. 45 (November 1977), pp. 1837-58. , "An Evaluation of the Recent Tokyo Round Trade Agreement Using General Equilibrium Computational Methods," Journal of Policy Modeling (New York), Vol. 4 (November 1982), pp. 341-61.

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution