Fiscal Federalism 151

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Fiscal Federalism 151 Fiscal federalism 151 Fiscal federalism own-source revenues to finance the services logi- cally assigned to them. Richard M. Bird Given the greater interjurisdictional mobility of University of Toronto the base of the income tax relative to that of the con- sumption tax, and of the latter relative to that of the The analysis of the problems that give rise to, property tax (and the efficiency problems arising and arise from, the existence of more than from tax exportation, when not precisely offset by one level of government within the same benefit spillovers), most analysts suggest that the lo- geographical area. cal public sector should be financed basically by user charges and “local” taxes, especially the prop- erty tax, and states by consumption taxes, with the As originally developed by Musgrave (1959) and income tax being left largely to the central (federal) Oates (1972), the “theory of fiscal federalism” con- government (Musgrave 1983). But this division of cerns the division of public-sector functions and fi- revenues means that state and local governments are nances in a logical way among multiple layers of likely to end up with greater expenditure responsi- government (King 1984). Much of the literature of bilities than can be financed from their own reve- fiscal federalism consists of relatively unrelated nues. An important element of fiscal federalism treatments of such issues as the “decentralization from the beginning has thus been recognition of the theorem” (Oates 1991), models for the assignment probable need for intergovernmental grants to close of powers (McLure 1993), discussions of inter- the revenue gap. Considerable attention has been governmental spillovers and intergovernmental devoted to the appropriate design of such grants grants (Break 1980), fiscal mobility and migration (Wilde 1971; Ahmed 1997), as well as to empirical (Wildasin 1991), and vertical fiscal imbalance and analysis of their effects on local spending patterns dependence (Hunter 1977). The theoretical discus- (Gramlich 1977; Rubinfeld 1987). sion of local public goods that has taken place in the The theory of fiscal federalism applies as well, context of the Tiebout model (Wildasin 1986) is not or as badly, to local service units in a metropolitan part of “fiscal federalism” as defined here because it area as to states in a federation. In principle, how- is concerned only with governmental relations at the ever, there are important analytical and policy dif- same jurisdictional level. A more general, and rele- ferences, not only between local-metropolitan vant, theoretical framework to approach some of problems and federal-state problems but even be- these problems might be the theory of overlapping tween “tight” federations such as Germany and clubs (Cornes and Sandler 1996), but as yet this has “loose” federations such as Canada—with the been little developed (Casella and Frey 1992). United States somewhere in between (Bird 1986). Initially, stabilization and distribution were con- These differences arise in part from the differing sidered to be essentially “central” functions, with nature and rigidity of the constraints imposed by the only role for “subcentral” (state and local) gov- political institutions. The question has attracted con- ernments arising in the allocative sphere. From siderable attention in recent years, in part because of this perspective, the main analytical task of fis- the emergence of nascent “federal” institutions in cal federalism is to define the appropriate functions the European Union. However, fiscal federalism has and finances of local governments as efficiently as little to say as yet about the dynamics of institutional possible—that is, in such a way as to maximize change in emerging (or disintegrating) federations. community welfare (often represented, for analytical Moreover, it offers little guidance in dealing with convenience, by the Median Voter Theorem). In a such important real-world intergovernmental fi- territorial variant of the Benefit Principle, it was nance problems as the appropriate size and scope of suggested at an early stage that each jurisdiction operation of local and intermediate-level govern- could be most efficiently mapped in terms of the ments in the newly emerging countries of the former spatial dimension of the services it provided. Thus, Soviet bloc (Bird, Ebel, and Wallich 1995), where, there would be “local public goods,” “state public for example, the potential impact on stabilization goods,” and “national public goods,” with the pre- (Gramlich 1987) is a major concern. sumed beneficiaries of each financing their provi- In contrast, much good work has been done sion in an appropriate way (Olson 1969). In prac- within this analytical framework on some of the tice, the overlapping and multidimensional nature of problems arising from the common metropolitan most public-sector activities makes it difficult to ap- area situation of divided political jurisdictions ply this approach very rigorously, particularly be- within an economically integrated region. A struc- cause few lower-level governments have sufficient ture that puts people’s places of work and residence 152 Fiscal federalism in separate political jurisidictions, while making the Local governments rely heavily on property latter primarily responsible for the most important taxes for revenue, while state governments rely on a local expenditure, education, has obvious implica- mixture of sales and income taxes, and the federal tions for both efficiency and distribution (Wildasin government mainly on income (and payroll) taxes. 1986), as has been much explored in the literature The division of revenues differs in other countries: on education finance. There is still much to be done, Although almost everywhere local governments get however, to satisfactorily explain local redistribu- property taxes and central governments most in- tive policies (Tresch 1981)—through, for example, come taxes, in some countries local income taxes— education—and their impact on migration and other like national sales taxes—are much more important important economic variables (Wildasin 1991). than in the United States (Owens and Panella 1991). Much has been written about the virtues of de- Such taxes are invariably “piggybacked” on national centralized government, from both a political and an taxes—that is, they take the form of surcharges. economic perspective (Tullock 1994), but most of Only Switzerland comes close to matching the di- these supposed virtues can, in the conventional fis- versity of the state and local income and sales taxes cal federalism framework, be achieved as well by found in the United States. Most other countries, regionally based central officials as by locally whether formally federal or not, have much more elected politicians. Perhaps some of the answers lie territorially uniform fiscal systems. Although there in the new “supply-side” theories of government is clearly vertical competition between levels of (Breton 1996) that are beginning to be developed in government for revenue, most attention has been the broad “public choice” framework (Mueller paid in the literature to horizontal tax competition, 1992), because there is considerable similarity be- perhaps because as a rule local governments have tween the assumptions underlying public choice access only to those revenue sources that higher- theory and federalist theory (Ostrom 1971). As yet, level governments do not want for themselves. however, little progress has been made with respect Local governments almost invariably depend in to articulating these arguments in either normative part, and sometimes very heavily, upon transfers or positive terms in the conventional fiscal federal- from upper-level governments to finance the ser- ism analysis, other than as simple assertions. vices for which they are responsible. The appropri- Nonetheless, some important lessons have ate level and design of such transfers has been an emerged from the fiscal federalism literature (Inman important concern in the fiscal federalism literature. and Rubinfeld 1997). In particular, considerable Some argue, for example, that a system of uncondi- progress has been made with respect to the appro- tional fiscal equalization grants is an essential com- priate assignment of tasks and finances in multilevel ponent of an efficient (and equitable) fiscal federal governments, especially with respect to the design system (Boadway and Flatters 1982). Others assert and effects of intergovernmental grants (Wildasin that there is no place for such transfers (Oakland 1997). While there is considerable variation in detail 1994). The theoretical literature suggests that the from state to state—let alone across countries—on only clear efficiency case for intergovernmental the whole the observed assignment of functions to payments is to compensate local governments for local and state governments accords broadly with benefit spillovers to ensure that they provide the op- the dictates of theory, with local governments being timal amount of the public service in question. In broadly responsible for “place-specific” services practice, however, virtually no examples of the such as streets, water and sewerage works, refuse open-ended conditional matching grants called for disposal, and fire and police services. In addition, in by this theory are to be found in any country (Ah- the United States, local governments are also gener- med 1997). On the contrary, most countries (other ally responsible
Recommended publications
  • A Political Companion to Henry David Thoreau
    University of Kentucky UKnowledge Literature in English, North America English Language and Literature 6-11-2009 A Political Companion to Henry David Thoreau Jack Turner University of Washington Click here to let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Thanks to the University of Kentucky Libraries and the University Press of Kentucky, this book is freely available to current faculty, students, and staff at the University of Kentucky. Find other University of Kentucky Books at uknowledge.uky.edu/upk. For more information, please contact UKnowledge at [email protected]. Recommended Citation Turner, Jack, "A Political Companion to Henry David Thoreau" (2009). Literature in English, North America. 70. https://uknowledge.uky.edu/upk_english_language_and_literature_north_america/70 A Political Companion to Henr y David Thoreau POLITIcaL COMpaNIONS TO GREat AMERIcaN AUthORS Series Editor: Patrick J. Deneen, Georgetown University The Political Companions to Great American Authors series illuminates the complex political thought of the nation’s most celebrated writers from the founding era to the present. The goals of the series are to demonstrate how American political thought is understood and represented by great Ameri- can writers and to describe how our polity’s understanding of fundamental principles such as democracy, equality, freedom, toleration, and fraternity has been influenced by these canonical authors. The series features a broad spectrum of political theorists, philoso- phers, and literary critics and scholars whose work examines classic authors and seeks to explain their continuing influence on American political, social, intellectual, and cultural life. This series reappraises esteemed American authors and evaluates their writings as lasting works of art that continue to inform and guide the American democratic experiment.
    [Show full text]
  • Redefining Federalism NEWS&ANALYSIS
    Copyright © 2005 Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, DC. reprinted with permission from ELR®, http://www.eli.org, 1-800-433-5120. 7-2005 35 ELR 10445 ELRNEWS&ANALYSIS Redefining Federalism by Douglas T. Kendall Editors’ Summary: Federalism has become a highly politicized term in envi- ronmental law, with some parties having adopted the term to signify an ideol- ogy of devolving federal authority over environmental protection back to the states. In this Article, the author argues that from the states’ perspective, the U.S. Supreme Court is using federalism both too much and too little. Too much, in striking down federal law where even the states recognize that a federal role is necessary to address a national problem. Too little, in inappropriately limit- ing state experimentation. By listening more carefully to the states, the author argues that the Court could transform its federalism jurisprudence from a source of criticism and polarization to a doctrine that should win broad support from across the political spectrum. n its current iteration, the U.S. Supreme Court’s federal- important state environmental initiatives despite consider- Iism jurisprudence presents a serious threat to environ- able ambiguity about the intent of Congress. mental protection. The Court’s efforts to reestablish This pattern of rulings suggests the Court is adopting a formalistic limits on the U.S. Congress’ power under the form of “libertarian federalism” in striking down environ- Commerce Clause in United States v. Lopez1 and Morrison mental protections at the federal, state, and local level. As- v. United States2 has led to a flurry of claims that Congress cending in concert with the Court’s jurisprudence has been has exceeded its regulatory authority in protecting sin- an effort by the libertarian right—comprised of grass-roots gle-state species under the Endangered Species Act (ESA)3 organizers such as Grover Norquist, legal activists such as and isolated waters and wetlands under the Clean Water Act Michael Greve, and legal scholars such as Prof.
    [Show full text]
  • Executive Order 13132 of August 4, 1999
    43255 Federal Register Presidential Documents Vol. 64, No. 153 Tuesday, August 10, 1999 Title 3Ð Executive Order 13132 of August 4, 1999 The President Federalism By the authority vested in me as President by the Constitution and the laws of the United States of America, and in order to guarantee the division of governmental responsibilities between the national government and the States that was intended by the Framers of the Constitution, to ensure that the principles of federalism established by the Framers guide the execu- tive departments and agencies in the formulation and implementation of policies, and to further the policies of the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act, it is hereby ordered as follows: Section 1. Definitions. For purposes of this order: (a) ``Policies that have federalism implications'' refers to regulations, legis- lative comments or proposed legislation, and other policy statements or actions that have substantial direct effects on the States, on the relationship between the national government and the States, or on the distribution of power and responsibilities among the various levels of government. (b) ``State'' or ``States'' refer to the States of the United States of America, individually or collectively, and, where relevant, to State governments, in- cluding units of local government and other political subdivisions established by the States. (c) ``Agency'' means any authority of the United States that is an ``agency'' under 44 U.S.C. 3502(1), other than those considered to be independent regulatory agencies, as defined in 44 U.S.C. 3502(5). (d) ``State and local officials'' means elected officials of State and local governments or their representative national organizations.
    [Show full text]
  • The State of Our Federalism Michael S
    The State of Our Federalism Michael S. Greve The Oldest Question of American Constitutional Law Federalism has been called “the oldest question of American constitutional law.” And so it is. Federalism was the central question of our constitutional founding. It has been a constant theme of our politics ever since, and it has been a central, highly contentious question in every critical era in our history—the Civil War and Reconstruction; the Progressive Era; the New Deal; and the Civil Rights Era. We are now living through another critical period. The country is broke, and our political institutions seem incapable of finding solutions. And as always, federalism is playing a prominent role in a heated political debate. You’ve heard the story line: an overbearing, out-of-touch, out-of-control government in Washington, D.C. has aggrandized itself and trampled state and local governments underfoot. To restore fiscal sanity and democratic government, we should restore federalism’s balance. We should respect the Tenth Amendment, return power to the states, and so bring government closer to the people. All of the Republican contenders for the presidency advocate this program, with varying degrees of enthusiasm. I agree with their analysis and prescription—up to a point. Washington has indeed assumed far too much power over local affairs. In many policy areas, decentralization would improve our policies and our politics. I also agree that our problems have a potent constitutional dimension. And yet: I will try to persuade you that our federalism problem is a great deal more complicated. “Federalism” in the sense of decentralization and state authority is not just a solution.
    [Show full text]
  • Federalism in Eastern Europe During and After Communism
    James Hughes Federalism in Eastern Europe during and after Communism Book section Original citation: Originally published in Fagan, Adam and Kopecký, Petr, (eds.) The Routledge Handbook of East European Politics. Routledge, London, UK. ISBN 9781138919754 © 2018 Routledge This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/69642/ Available in LSE Research Online: March 2017 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s submitted version of the book section. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Federalism in Eastern Europe during and after Communism James Hughes Chapter 10 Forthcoming in Adam Fagan and Petr Kopecky eds. The Routledge Handbook of East European Politics. Routledge 2017 One of the earliest political visionaries of federalism in Eastern Europe,interwar Polish leader Józef Piłsudski, famously remarked to former socialist comrades that “we both took
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Decentralization and Centralization in a Federal System : the Case Of
    Rev. Sociol. Polit. vol.1 no.se Curitiba 2006 Decentralization and centralization in a federal system: the case of * democratic Brazil Maria Hermínia Tavares de Almeida University of São Paulo Abstract: This paper discusses the contradictory impulses towards decentralization and centralization in Brazil during the 1990s and early 2000s. After discussing the analytical issues related to the specific nature of decentralization in federal systems, the paper examines two sets of policy issues: those regulating the fiscal relations between national and sub-national governments and those redefining responsibilities for social services provision (basic education, health care, social assistance). Against conventional academic wisdom, it sustains that although there has been some re-centralization of fiscal decisions and of targeted income transfer programs, a clear re-centralization tendency cannot be siad to exist. Decentralization and centralization trends coexist propelled by different forces, with different motives and different outcomes. Keywords: centralization; de-centralization; democratization; fiscal relations; social welfares. After a decade of steadfast decentralization is Brazilian federation undergoing a process of re-centralization? Academic conventional wisdom, both within and outside Brazil, seems to say that indeed it is. Decentralization was a major issue of the Brazilian democratization agenda, during the 80s. The bureaucratic-authoritarian regime (1964-1984) concentrated decisions, financial resources and administrative capacities at federal level. The country became an extreme case of centralized federalism1, almost undistinguishable from a unitary polity. Therefore, it was only too natural that democratic opposition to military rule took decentralization as one of its most cherished aims, together with social justice, rule of law and citizens participation. Decentralization to the local level was argued for in the name of democracy as much as in the name of governmental efficiency and efficacy.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Federalism As a Constraint on States
    FISCAL FEDERALISM AS A CONSTRAINT ON STATES CLAYTON P. GILLETTE* Federalism—by which I mean more than federal‐state rela‐ tionships, and in particular mean all relationships between rela‐ tively centralized governments and their relatively decentral‐ ized subdivisions—allows different jurisdictions to compete for residents, both firms and individuals. Those who embrace fed‐ eralism point to the benefits it confers by allowing jurisdictions to vary the bundle of goods and services they offer when the contents of that bundle generate only intrajurisdictional effects. The underlying assumption is that federalism induces subna‐ tional jurisdictions to attract residents by offering a preferred public good at a particular tax price.1 The resulting competition, in theory, has many benefits. It maximizes preference satisfac‐ tion, as individuals migrate to jurisdictions that offer the public goods that they desire. It allows efficient delivery of local public goods as competitive markets for residents both drive down monopoly tax prices that public entities might otherwise be able to demand and provide public officials signals of desired ser‐ vices. It reduces the size of government because the resulting homogeneity (1) reduces the costs of monitoring officials who are charged with providing public goods consistent with resi‐ dents’ preferences and (2) represses logrolling among groups with diverse interests that might otherwise divert public re‐ sources to private use. And it diminishes corruption within government because that same homogeneity causes expendi‐ tures for illicit activity—which almost by definition deviates from majoritarian preferences—to be more salient. * Max E. Greenberg Professor of Contract Law, NYU School of Law. My thanks to the University of Virginia School of Law Chapter of the Federalist Society for inviting me to participate as a panelist in the Thirtieth Annual Federalist Society National Student Symposium.
    [Show full text]
  • Federalism and Decentralization – a Critical Survey of Frequently Used Indicators
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Joint Discussion Paper MAGKS Göttingen Series in Economics Kassel Aachen by the Universities of Siegen Marburg Aachen · Gießen · Göttingen Kassel · Marburg · Siegen Gießen ISSN 1867-3678 No. 21-2008 Lorenz Blume and Stefan Voigt Federalism and Decentralization – A Critical Survey of Frequently Used Indicators This paper can be downloaded from http://www.uni-marburg.de/fb02/makro/forschung/magkspapers/index_html%28magks%29 Coordination: Bernd Hayo • Philipps-University Marburg Faculty of Business Administration and Economics • Universitätsstraße 24, D-35032 Marburg Tel: +49-6421-2823091, Fax: +49-6421-2823088, e-mail: [email protected] Federalism and Decentralization – A Critical Survey of Frequently Used Indicators1 Lorenz Blume * and Stefan Voigt # Abstract: The economic effects of federalism are unclear: some papers find that federalism has strong positive effects on a number of economically relevant variables, others find negative effects. The results often crucially hinge upon the proxies for federalism used. In this paper, we critically survey the existing indicators for both federalism and fiscal decentralization. We argue that federalism is a constitutional institution whereas decentralization is (the outcome of) a policy choice and that the two ought to be systematically distinguished because decentralization can also occur in non-federally structured states. We further argue that institutional details are very important with regard to federalism and that dummy variables usually capture only very specific aspects of the institutional details. We use factor analysis to test whether the latent variables behind the observed indicators support these assumptions.
    [Show full text]
  • Federalism and Families
    University of Pennsylvania Law Review FOUNDED 1852 Formerly American Law Register VOL. 143 JUNE 1995 No. 6 ARTICLES FEDERALISM AND FAMILIES ANNE C. DAILEYt TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................. 1788 I. THE LOCALIST STRAND IN CONSTITUTIONAL FEDERALISM 1794 A. Localism Under Dual Federalism ................. 1796 B. The Paradigm of Procedural Federalism: Process and InstitutionalModels .......................... 1805 C. The Reemergence of Substantive Federalism: United States v. Lopez ............................ 1816 D. Localism and Family Law ...................... 1821 II. FAMILIES AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF CIVIC CHARACTER . 1825 A. Families in Liberal Theory .................... 1826 t Associate Professor, University of Connecticut School of Law. B.A. 1983, Yale College;J.D. 1987, Harvard Law School. I would like to thank Matthew Adler, Steven Ecker, Richard Kay, Stephen Morse,Jeremy Paul,Judith Resnik, Tanina Rostain, Vicki Schultz, Nomi Stolzenberg, Kathleen A. Sullivan, and participants at the University of Pennsylvania Legal Studies Workshop for their helpful comments and criticisms. Heather Stuart and Marc Ubaldi provided valuable research assistance. (1787) 1788 UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 143: 1787 B. Liberal Citizenship and Civic Character ............ 1835 C. Civic Characterand ParentalAuthority ............ 1850 1. The Relational View of the Situated Self ....... 1851 2. The Communal View of the Situated Self ..... 1856 III. A LOCALIST THEORY OF FAMILY LAW .............. 1860 A. The
    [Show full text]
  • Between Secession and Federalism: the Independence of South Sudan and the Need for a Reconsidered Nigeria Obehi S
    Global Business & Development Law Journal Volume 26 | Issue 2 Article 2 1-1-2013 Between Secession and Federalism: The Independence of South Sudan and the Need for a Reconsidered Nigeria Obehi S. Okojie Adeleke Adeyemo & Co., Lagos, Nigeria Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.pacific.edu/globe Part of the Comparative and Foreign Law Commons, Constitutional Law Commons, and the International Law Commons Recommended Citation Obehi S. Okojie, Between Secession and Federalism: The Independence of South Sudan and the Need for a Reconsidered Nigeria, 26 Pac. McGeorge Global Bus. & Dev. L.J. 415 (2013). Available at: https://scholarlycommons.pacific.edu/globe/vol26/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals and Law Reviews at Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Global Business & Development Law Journal by an authorized editor of Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. [2] OBEHI.DOCX (DO NOT DELETE) 5/10/2013 11:16 AM Between Secession and Federalism: The Independence of South Sudan and the Need for a Reconsidered Nigeria Obehi S. Okojie* TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................... 416 II. BACKGROUND ............................................................................................................ 420 A. Nigeria and Sudan at a Glance ............................................................. 420 B. Similar Features
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Federalism in Comparative Perspective
    CONTEMPORARY AUSTRIAN STUDIES | VOLUME 24 Bischof, Karlhofer (Eds.), Williamson (Guest Ed.) • 1914: Aus tria-Hungary, the Origins, and the First Year of World War I War of World the Origins, and First Year tria-Hungary, Austrian Federalism in Comparative Perspective Günter Bischof AustrianFerdinand Federalism Karlhofer (Eds.) in Comparative Perspective Günter Bischof, Ferdinand Karlhofer (Eds.) UNO UNO PRESS innsbruck university press UNO PRESS innsbruck university press Austrian Federalism in ŽŵƉĂƌĂƟǀĞWĞƌƐƉĞĐƟǀĞ Günter Bischof, Ferdinand Karlhofer (Eds.) CONTEMPORARY AUSTRIAN STUDIES | VOLUME 24 UNO PRESS innsbruck university press Copyright © 2015 by University of New Orleans Press All rights reserved under International and Pan-American Copyright Conventions. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form, or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy, recording, or any information storage nd retrieval system, without prior permission in writing from the publisher. All inquiries should be addressed to UNO Press, University of New Orleans, LA 138, 2000 Lakeshore Drive. New Orleans, LA, 70148, USA. www.unopress.org. Printed in the United States of America Book design by Allison Reu and Alex Dimeff Cover photo © Parlamentsdirektion Published in the United States by Published and distributed in Europe University of New Orleans Press by Innsbruck University Press ISBN: 9781608011124 ISBN: 9783902936691 UNO PRESS Publication of this volume has been made possible through generous grants from the the Federal Ministry for Europe, Integration, and Foreign Affairs in Vienna through the Austrian Cultural Forum in New York, as well as the Federal Ministry of Economics, Science, and Research through the Austrian Academic Exchange Service (ÖAAD). The Austrian Marshall Plan Anniversary Foundation in Vienna has been very generous in supporting Center Austria: The Austrian Marshall Plan Center for European Studies at the University of New Orleans and its publications series.
    [Show full text]
  • The Federative Principle: an Alternative Political- Spatial Project of the Modern State’S Logic1
    THE FEDERATIVE PRINCIPLE: AN ALTERNATIVE POLITICAL- SPATIAL PROJECT OF THE MODERN STATE’S LOGIC1 O PRINCÍPIO FEDERATIVO: UM PROJETO POLÍTICO-ESPACIAL ALTERNATIVO À LÓGICA DO ESTADO MODERNO EL PRINCIPIO FEDERATIVO: UM PROYECTO POLÍTICO-ESPACIAL ALTERNATIVO A LA LÓGICA DEL ESTADO MODERNO Rafael Zilio Fernandes – Universidade Federal do Oeste do Pará – Santarém – Pará – Brasil [email protected] Abstract The Federative Principle is inscribed in the tradition of libertarian thought over the last two centuries as an alternative political-spatial project to the centralist logic of the modern State. Such project was the object of reflection by several authors and geographers. This paper features this tradition under a geographical approach, highlighting the Federalism’s spatiality and identifying what the selected authors understood by nation, region, borders, and important ideas to think about the organization of human space. First I do a background for the systematization of this Principle; after I present the Federalism for Proudhon and Bakunin; then the geographers Reclus and Kropotkin are analyzed; for the twentieth century I approach ideas from Landauer, Rocker, and Bookchin. I end the paper offering some ideas to think of Federalism nowadays. Keywords: Federalism, Libertarian Thought, Modern State. Resumo O Princípio Federativo se inscreve na tradição do pensamento libertário ao longo dos últimos dois séculos como projeto político-espacial alternativo à lógica centralista do Estado moderno. Tal projeto foi objeto de reflexão por parte de diversos autores, inclusive geógrafos. O que este artigo traz é um resgate desta tradição sob um olhar geográfico, colocando à luz a espacialidade do Federalismo e identificando o que os autores selecionados entenderam por nação, região e fronteira, ideias importantes para se pensar a organização do espaço humano de modo geral.
    [Show full text]