Inflation in Recession and Recovery

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Inflation in Recession and Recovery ROBERT J. GORDON* Universityof Chicago and the National Bureau of Economic Research In.fl!ation in Recession and Recovery The cruelchoice between two evils, unemploymentand inflation, has becomethe majoreconomic issue of the day.' THE INTERVAL FROM 1969:3 TO 1970:4 qualifiesas a full-fledgedeco- nomic slowdownin whichthe officialunemployment rate increasedby 59 percent.But in the firstyear of everyprevious U.S. postwarrecession, the rate of inflationwas lowerthan it was in the last expansionyear, while the rateof inflationwas more rapid in 1970than during any part of the previous businessexpansion.2 This paper develops wage andprice equations that at- tempt,first, to explainwhy inflation accelerated in 1970rather than slowing as it did duringpast recessions;second, to isolatethe relativerole of prices and wagesin the 1970episode; and third,to form predictionsof wage and pricebehavior during the next ten years.In particular,the paperattempts to predictthe responseof the rate of inflationto alternativepaths of eco- nomicrecovery--that is, to estimatehow much more rapidlyprices would * I am gratefulto Thomas D. Henrion for helping me preparethe computer runs. The paperwas made possible by the contributionsof the National Bureau of Economic Researchfor researchassistance and of the Departmentof Economicsof the Universityof Chicagofor computertime. I wish to acknowledge,besides the help receivedfrom mem- bers of the Brookingspanel, the comments of Milton Friedman,and other membersof the Money and BankingWorkshop at the Universityof Chicago, on an earlier version of this paper. 1. JamesTobin and LeonardRoss, "Livingwith Inflation,"The New YorkReview of Books, Vol. 16 (May 6, 1971), p. 23. 2. During the five expansionaryquarters between 1968:2 and 1969:3, the nonfarm privatedeflator increased at an annual rate of 4.2 percent,while duringthe five quarters between 1969:3 and 1970:4, the deflator increased by 5.2 percent. For comparable figures during previous recessions, see my "Prices in 1970: The Horizontal Phillips Curve?"Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity (3:1970), p. 449. 105 106 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971 increaseif full employmentwere to be attainedswiftly rather than grad- ually. In addition,the short- and long-runtradeoffs between inflation and unemploymentare calculated. The resultsshow that in the long run a given reductionin the unemploymentrate causesa greaterincrease in the rate of inflationthan most previousresearch has suggested;nevertheless, the data do not supportthe "accelerationist"hypothesis that there is no long-run tradeoff. Inflationary1970: Was It a Surprise? The Phillipscurve pictures a widelyaccepted hypothesis that the rate of inflationis inverselydependent on the rate of unemployment.The simplest versionof the hypothesismakes no distinctionbetween long-run and short- run Phillipscurves; the economyis alwayson "the"curve and experiences an immediatereduction in the rate of inflationwhenever, as in 1970,the un- employmentrate rises. A more sophisticatedapproach treats the Phillips curveas a long-runequilibrium relationship from whichthe economycan divergein the shortrun. In particular,if wagesand pricesadjust slowly to changesin economicconditions, an increasein the unemploymentrate is not accompaniedby an immediatereduction in the rate of inflation.Even- tually, however,the rate of inflationwill decline after sufficienttime has passedfor the laggedeffects of the higherunemployment rate to worktheir way throughthe economy. In an earlierpaper, I presentedone versionof a "dynamicPhillips curve" in whichinflation was determinedby the interactionof separatewage and priceequations.3 How surprisingwas 1970when viewedagainst their pre- dictions?Using actualprice changes to help predictwages, the wage equa- tion trackedthe firsthalf of 1970well, but underpredictedthe rate of wage increasein the last two quartersby an averageof 1.0 percentagepoint at an annualrate. Using actualwage changesin the priceequation, it underpre- dicted the annualrate of price increaseby an averageof 1.1 percentage points duringthe last threequarters of the year.Full predictions,based on predictedrather than actualvalues of both variablesin both equations,re- sult in a wideningunderprediction of the rate of priceincrease, reaching 2 percentagepoints in the fourthquarter. 3. Robert J. Gordon, "The Recent Accelerationof Inflationand Its Lessons for the Future," BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity (1:1970), pp. 8-41. RobertJ. Gordon 107 In short, the continuedacceleration of inflationin 1970 was indeed a "surprise"when comparedwith these predictions.This paperseeks to de- velop refinementsto these earlierwage and price equationsthat will im- proveboth the fit to historicaldata and the explanationof developmentsin 1970. Like most other recent research,the model developedhere postulates that the primaryforce "driving" the rateof inflationis the determinationof wages in the labor market.The price equationis based on the hypothesis that in the long run the relativeshares of wage and nonwageincome are constantand that the pricelevel is thus "tied"to laborcost; the purposeof the priceequation is then to describetemporary deviations of the distribu- tion of incomefrom this long-runconstant relationship. The dominantrole this model assignsto wagesin the inflationprocess justifies the dispropor- tionate emphasisthat it receivesin the followingdiscussion. The Determinationof Wages The theoryof wage determinationused here is similarin its generalfea- tures to the approachtaken by most previouseconometric research. The primarycurrent force that pulls the wage level upward(relative to "stan- dard"productivity) is an excess demandfor labor. When workersare in short supply,firms raise wage rates both to bid workersaway from other firmsand to inducenew entrantsinto the laborforce. Workers do not eval- uate wage offersby employersin a vacuum,however, but measurethem againstthe wage they expectto receiveif they remainin theirpresent jobs and the expectedprice level of the goods they will be ableto buy with them. Thusthe secondmajor force pushing upward on wagerates is the expected rate of increasein pricesand wages.Even without currentexcess demand for labor, the averagewage rate would be pushedup fasterthan the trend increasein productivityif the pricelevel were expectedto rise rapidly.4In 4. For a theoreticallabor marketmodel in which the primary"pushing" force is the expectedincrease in wages, see EdmundS. Phelps, "Money-WageDynamics and Labor- Market Equilibrium,"Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76 (July/August 1968), pp. 678-711. For a model in which the expectedincrease in pricesplays a dominantrole, see Milton Friedman,"The Role of MonetaryPolicy," AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 58 (March 1968), pp. 1-14. A hybrid model combining elements of both approachesand several other innovationsis containedin a monographthat I am currentlypreparing for the National Bureauof Economic Research. 108 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 1:1971 short, the basic variablesin most wage equationsfall into two classes,in- tended to measureeither (1) the "pull" of the labor market, or (2) the "push"of price expectations.Much of the controversyin the field centers on the way to measureexcess labor demandand price expectations;the selectionamong the competingmethods that maketheoretical and intuitive sense dependson the verdictof the empiricaldata. ALTERNATIVE MEASURES OF EXCESS LABOR DEMAND The aggregateunemployment rate, the most widelypublicized measure of labor markettightness, is subjectto severalimportant criticisms that have led GeorgePerry, myself, and othersto suggestalternative measures. The unemploymentinverse (1/U). Frictional and structuralunemploy- mentset a floorto the unemploymentrate, but thereis no upperlimit to the degreeof excessdemand that can accompanythis minimumunemployment rate. Thus the relationshipof excess demandand hence wage increasesto the unemploymentrate is usuallyassumed to be convexto the origin.In an attemptto approximatethis convexity,the inverseof the unemployment ratehas beenthe measureof labormarket pressure most frequentlyused in previousresearch. The vacancyrate (V). Since the major currentdeterminant of wage in- creasesis assumedto be net excess labor demand,the rate of unemploy- ment, which measuresexcess labor supply,should in principlebe supple- mentedby a measureof excesslabor demand.Unfortunately, the absence of a comprehensivevacancy measure for the postwarUnited Stateshas in- hibitedthis approach,but I proposeto use, as a roughapproximation to a vacancyrate, the numberof "nonagriculturaljob openings unfilled"(a seriescollected by the U.S. ManpowerAdministration) divided by the ci- vilianlabor force. The obstacleto using this seriesis its partialcoverage, but a workableassumption is thatthe ratioof "unmeasured"to "measured" vacanciesis constant.If so, the vacancyrate (V) can be multipliedby a con- stant selectedto make the net excess demandmeasure (V - U) equal to zero in a periodwhen labor marketsappear to be "in balance."5 5. I assumed that labor markets were "in balance" in 1965:2, requiringthat the vacancyrate be multipliedby 11.0. This arbitrarychoice servesonly to scale the vacancy rate to the same order of magnitudeas the unemploymentrate, but has no effect on the finalresults, since V, and U, are enteredseparately into the regressionsbelow in orderto allow the com'puterto determine the "true" contribution of each variable to labor markettightness. RobertJ. Gordon 109 The total unemploymentrate
Recommended publications
  • Inflation and the Business Cycle
    Inflation and the business cycle Michael McMahon Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 1 / 68 To Cover • Discuss the costs of inflation; • Investigate the relationship between money and inflation; • Introduce the Romer framework; • Discuss hyperinflations. • Shocks and the business cycle; • Monetary policy responses to business cycles. • Explain what the monetary transmission mechanism is; • Examine the link between inflation and GDP. Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 2 / 68 The Next Few Lectures Term structure, asset prices Exchange and capital rate market conditions Import prices Bank rate Net external demand CPI inflation Bank lending Monetary rates and credit Policy Asset purchase/ Corporate DGI conditions Framework sales demand loans Macro prudential Household policy demand deposits Inflation expectations Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 3 / 68 Inflation Definition Inflation is a sustained general rise in the price level in the economy. In reality we measure it using concepts such as: • Consumer Price Indices (CPI); • Producer Price Indices (PPI); • Deflators (GDP deflator, Consumption Expenditure Deflator) Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 4 / 68 Inflation: The Costs If all prices are rising at same rate, including wages and asset prices, what is the problem? • Information: Makes it harder to detect relative price changes and so hinders efficient operation of market; • Uncertainty: High inflation countries have very volatile inflation; • High inflation undermines role of money and encourages barter; • Growth - if inflation increases by 10%, reduce long term growth by 0.2% but only for countries with inflation higher than 15% (Barro); • Shoe leather costs/menu costs; • Interaction with tax system; • Because of fixed nominal contracts arbitrarily redistributes wealth; • Nominal contracts break down and long-term contracts avoided.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • This Is the Heritage Society After All – to 1893, and the Shape of This
    1 IRVING HERITAGE SOCIETY PRESENTATION By Maura Gast, Irving CVB October 2010 For tonight’s program, and because this is the Irving Heritage Society, after all, I thought I’d take a departure from my usual routine (which probably everyone in this room has heard too many times) and talk a little bit about the role the CVB plays in an historical context instead. I’m hopeful that as champions of heritage and history in general, that you’ll indulge me on this path tonight, and that you’ll see it all come back home to Irving by the time I’m done. Because there were really three key factors that led to the convention industry as we know it today and to our profession. And they are factors that, coupled with some amazing similarities to what’s going on in our world today, are worth paying attention to. How We as CVBs Came to Be • The Industrial Revolution – And the creation of manufacturing organizations • The Railroad Revolution • The Panic of 1893 One was the industrial revolution and its associated growth of large manufacturing organizations caused by the many technological innovations of that age. The second was the growth of the railroad, and ultimately the Highway system here in the US. And the third was the Panic of 1893. The Concept of “Associations” 2 The idea of “associations” has historically been an American concept – this idea of like‐minded people wanting to gather together in what came to be known as conventions. And when you think about it, there have been meetings and conventions of some kind taking place since recorded time.
    [Show full text]
  • Research & Policy Brief No.47
    Research & Policy Briefs From the World Bank Malaysia Hub No. 47 May 24, 2021 Demand and Supply Dynamics in East Asia during the COVID-19 Recession Ergys Islamaj, Franz Ulrich Ruch, and Eka Vashakmadze The COVID-19 pandemic has devastated lives and damaged economies, requiring strong and decisive policy responses from governments. Developing Public Disclosure Authorized the optimal short-term and long-term policy response to the pandemic requires understanding the demand and supply factors that drive economic growth. The appropriate policy response will depend on the size and duration of demand and supply shocks. This Research & Policy Brief provides a decomposition of demand and supply dynamics at the macroeconomic level for the large developing economies of East Asia. The findings suggest that both demand and supply shocks were important drivers of output fluctuations during the first year of the pandemic. The demand shocks created an environment of deficient demand—reflected in large negative output gaps even after the unprecedented policy response—which is expected to last through 2021. The extant deficient demand is suggestive of continued need to support the economic recovery. Its size should guide policy makers in calibrating responses to ensure that recovery is entrenched, and that short-term supply disruptions do not lead to long-term declines in potential growth. The Pandemic-Induced Shock Low external demand will continue to affect economies reliant on tourism, while sluggish domestic demand will disproportionally affect The pandemic, national lockdowns, and reverberations from the rest economies with large services sectors. Understanding the demand of the world inflicted a massive shock to the East Asia and Pacific and supply factors that drive economic growth is critical for region in 2020 (World Bank 2020a).
    [Show full text]
  • Rebuilding the Public Sector for Economic Recovery and Resilience
    REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE Sara Hinkley, Ph.D. March 2021 Executive Summary As the country crests the most devastating wave yet of the COVID-19 pandemic, there is growing optimism that the new administration will act quickly to stem the economic crisis: both by deploying the federal government’s leadership to control the pandemic itself and by using the federal government’s fiscal capacity to mitigate the economic damage caused by the public health crisis. The Biden administration will need to turn around both of these failures quickly in order to prevent further catastrophe for millions of Americans and a sustained recession. But the disaster unfolding now is not just a result of policy failures over the past eleven months; it is the result of decades of disinvestment and austerity, accelerated during the Great Recession, which made us more vulnerable to this crisis. Local, state, and national austerity set the country up for a harsh, prolonged, and profoundly unequal recession. We face a pivotal moment now: we can repeat those mistakes, leaving us more vulnerable to future crises, or we can build back our public sector to make us more economically resilient. groundworkcollaborative.org REBUILDING THE PUBLIC SECTOR FOR ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND RESILIENCE | 1 It is certainly bad luck that the long-predicted1 economic downturn was sparked by a pandemic, but our failure to meet this crisis with an effective public response is the outcome of years of deliberate policy choices. The austerity implemented after the Great Recession decimated both our ability to weather an economic downturn and our ability to handle any crisis requiring a strong public response.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. Working Paper The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. (2007) : The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/4105 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IZA DP No. 2900 The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties Marika Karanassou Hector Sala Dennis J.
    [Show full text]
  • Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New Keynesian Models∗†
    Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New Keynesian Models∗† Martin S. Eichenbaum‡ Sergio Rebelo§ Mathias Trabandt¶ June 19, 2020 Abstract We analyze the e§ects of an epidemic in three standard macroeconomic models. We find that the neoclassical model does not rationalize the positive comovement of consumption and investment observed in recessions associated with an epidemic. Intro- ducing monopolistic competition into the neoclassical model remedies this shortcoming even when prices are completely flexible. Finally, sticky prices lead to a larger recession but do not fundamentally alter the predictions of the monopolistic competition model. JEL Classification: E1, I1, H0 Keywords: Epidemic, comovement, investment, recession. ∗We thank R. Anton Braun, Joao Guerreiro, Martín Harding, Laura Murphy, and Hannah Seidl for helpful comments. †Matlab/Dynare replication codes will be made available by the end of June 2020 at the following URL: https://sites.google.com/site/mathiastrabandt/home/research ‡Northwestern University and NBER. Address: Northwestern University, Department of Economics, 2211 Campus Dr, Evanston, IL 60208. USA. E-mail: [email protected]. §Northwestern University, NBER, and CEPR. Address: Northwestern University, Kellogg School of Man- agement, 2211 Campus Dr, Evanston, IL 60208. USA. E-mail: [email protected]. ¶Freie Universität Berlin, School of Business and Economics, Chair of Macroeconomics. Address: Boltz- mannstrasse 20, 14195 Berlin, Germany, German Institute for Economic Research (DIW) and Halle Institute for Economic Research (IWH), E-mail: [email protected]. 1Introduction Acentralfeatureofrecessionsisthepositivecomovementbetweenoutput,hoursworked, consumption, and investment. In this respect, the COVID-19 recession is not unique. At least since Barro and King (1984), it has been recognized that, absent aggregate productivity shocks, it is di¢cult for many models to generate comovement in macroeconomic aggregates.
    [Show full text]
  • The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond
    Working Paper No. 822 The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond by Riccardo Bellofiore* University of Bergamo December 2014 * [email protected] This paper was prepared for the project “Financing Innovation: An Application of a Keynes-Schumpeter- Minsky Synthesis,” funded in part by the Institute for New Economic Thinking, INET grant no. IN012-00036, administered through the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Co-principal investigators: Mariana Mazzucato (Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex) and L. Randall Wray (Levy Institute). The author thanks INET and the Levy Institute for support of this research. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract An understanding of, and an intervention into, the present capitalist reality requires that we put together the insights of Karl Marx on labor, as well as those of Hyman Minsky on finance. The best way to do this is within a longer-term perspective, looking at the different stages through which capitalism evolves.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Predicting Recessions: Financial Cycle Versus Term Spread
    BIS Working Papers No 818 Predicting recessions: financial cycle versus term spread by Claudio Borio, Mathias Drehmann and Dora Xia Monetary and Economic Department October 2019 JEL classification: C33, E37, E44 Keywords: financial cycle, term spread, recession risk, panel probit model BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2019. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Predicting recessions: financial cycle versus term spread1 Claudio Borio, Mathias Drehmann and Dora Xia2 Abstract Financial cycles can be important drivers of real activity, but there is scant evidence about how well they signal recession risks. We run a horse race between the term spread – the most widely used indicator in the literature – and a range of financial cycle measures. Unlike most papers, ours assesses forecasting performance not just for the United States but also for a panel of advanced and emerging market economies. We find that financial cycle measures have significant forecasting power both in and out of sample, even for a three-year horizon. Moreover, they outperform the term spread in nearly all specifications.
    [Show full text]
  • How Would Modern Macroeconomic Schools of Thought Respond to the Recent Economic Crisis?
    ® Economic Information Newsletter Liber8 Brought to You by the Research Library of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis November 2009 How Would Modern Macroeconomic Schools of Thought Respond to the Recent Economic Crisis? “Would financial markets and the economy have been better off if the Fed pursued a policy of quantitative easing sooner?” —Daniel L. Thornton, Vice President and Economic Adviser, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Synopses The government and the Federal Reserve’s response to the current recession continues to be hotly de bated. Several questions arise: Was a $780 billion economic stimulus bill appropriate? Was the Troubled Asset Re lief Program (TARP) beneficial? Should the Fed have increased the money supply sooner? Should Lehman Brothers have been allowed to fail? Some answers to these questions lie in economic theory, and whether prudent decisions were made depends on whom you ask. This article examines three modern schools of economic thought and how each school would advise was the best way to respond to the most recent crisis. The New Keynesian Approach New Keynesian economics, the “new” version of the school based on the works of the early twentieth- century economist John Maynard Keynes, is founded on two major assumptions. First, people are forward looking; that is, they use available information today (interest rates, stock prices, gas prices, and so on) to form expectations about the future. Second, prices and wages are “sticky,” meaning they adjust gradually. One example of “stickiness” is a union-negotiated contract, which is fixed for a definite period of time. Menus are also an example of price stickiness: The cost associated with reprinting menus causes a restaurant owner to be reluctant about replacing them.
    [Show full text]