The Cultural Background of Ludwig Von Mises

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Cultural Background of Ludwig Von Mises The Cultural Background of Ludwig von Mises Erik Ritter von Kuehnelt-Leddihn riting for Americans born in 1881 in Lwów, the capital background, and by the time he about the cultural of what was known as Galicia. A was twelve years old, he knew the Wbackground of Ludwig kingdom and crownland of Austria, Germanic, the Latin, the Cyrillic, von Mises, an eminent Galicia was called Lesser Poland. the Greek, and the Hebraic script. former compatriot of mine, poses At the time, the majority of the city As to languages, he spoke German, some difficulties: how to present was Polish; more than a quarter was Polish, and 4rench, and understood you with a world radically different Jewish; a small minority was Ukrainian. The year he was born from yours, a world far away, Ukrainian; and a tiny percentage which in many ways no longer was Austro-German officials. How- exists. 4or example, the birthplace ever, the upper classes were dis- of this eminent economist was for tinctly Polish. nearly fifty years within the con- The eastern part of Galicia had fines of the Soviet Union. Who belonged to Poland since the four- was this great man and scholar? In teenth century, but became what ambiance did he live before Austrian at the first Polish parti- he came to the United States, tion in 1772, and it was returned where he continued to publish his to Poland in 1918. It is important crucially important works and to to realize all this in order to inspire new generations of econo- understand Misess cultural as well mists? We have to go back to the as psychological upbringing, and Karl, Ludwig, and Richard von Mises. old Austro-Hungarian Empire, the roots of his life-philosophy. then the second-largest political His Jewish roots, his Polish cul- his grandfatherhead of the Israeli unit in Europe. Only Russia was ture, his Austrian political frame Cult Communitywas ennobled bigger, although Germanys popu- and allegiance are all intertwined. with the title Edler, which means lation was slightly larger. Mises was Variety was the keynote of his The Noble, a distinction not so rare for Jews in the Austro-Hungarian Empire. His father, a very well-to- do railroad enterpriser, made sure Ludwig got the very best classical education. He did the same for his other son, Richard, who became a professor of mathematics at the University of Berlin and then later at Harvard. The Poles enjoyed complete freedom in Lesser Poland, unlike in Russia or Prussia, and had two universities of their own. The Mises family with Ludwig at the left. In the Austrian Parliament in STUDIES IN CLASSICAL LIBERALISM Vienna, they played a very impor- was not always a solidly Catholic country, at the invitation of King tant role as true pillars of the country. In the sixteenth century it Casimir the Great, and they came multinational Habsburg Empire, was one-third Presbyterian and mostly from Germany. In and many Poles saw in that dynasty one-third Unitarian (Socinian), Germany they had the privilege to the future rulers of a liberated and but the Catholic Church regained settle in ghettoes where they had resuscitated Poland. its vast majority thanks largely to complete self-government. (See the Jesuits and their cultural We must keep in mind that Guido Kischs magistral work, The endeavors: their schools accepted long before the catastrophe of the Jews in Medieval Germany, Chicago, pupils from all denominations, and partitions, the Poles, as an aristo- 1942.) Since by their own ritual supported good architecture, cratic nation, strongly upheld per- they were not permitted to take painting, and, above all, theater. more than 2,000 steps on the sonal freedom. Movements for lib- (The Jesuits were the initiators of erty, as a matter of fact, have typi- Sabbath, they could not dwell too our stage technology.) There was far from the synagogue. Of course, cally been carried on by the nobil- no inquisition, neither stake nor ity, which always opposed central- efforts were made to convert rope. Poland was, unlike England, them, and if they accepted bap- izing pressure and control. We the most tolerant European coun- saw this in England with the tism, they automaticallyas rela- try. Polish liberty was such that tives of our Lordbecame mem- Magna Carta, in Hungary with the when, in 1795, at the last partition, Golden Bull, in Aragon by the bers of the nobility. Antisemitism? stubborn Grandes, and in 4rance by As anywhere else, it came from the !ronde. In this respect, Poland very simple people to whom the went further; it became an elective descendants of Abraham seemed monarchy in 1572 and called itself odd in their rituals, their clothing, a republic. One of the slogans of their language, and their behavior, this very independent nobility was: although orthodox Jews, above all, Menace the foreign kings and were people of great piety and resist your own! Political power honesty. rested with the nobility, which Poles and freedom! Not only in (before the partitions) had no their own country did they practice titles, and its claimants comprised it; Polish freedom fighters were a fifth of the population. (4or a active in many parts of the world. comparison, take Alpine Austria Two noblemen survive in the with a third of one percent or memory of ‘ the United States Prussia with much less!) It was a Tadeusz Kosciuszko and Kazimierz nobility without legal distinctions Pulaski, the only U.S. general who and a proverb said: The noble- Mises in his military uniform, died in the War of Independence man in his farmhouse is equal to August 1901 in Vienna. on American soil. (Nor should‘ one the magnate in his castle. And when the 4ree Royal Polish City of forget Henryk Dembinski and since all noblemen were equals, Danzig was incorporated by Józef Bem, who played a similar they could not be ruled by majori- Prussia, the citizens, mostly role in the Hungarian Rising of ties. In the parliament, the Sejm, German Lutherans, fought valiant- 184849.) In the battle of the opposition of a single man ly for their freedom. Many of the Liebnitz, the Poles and the German the Liberum Vetoannulled any leading families emigrated, so the Knights diverted the Mongols from legal proposition. Schopenhauers went to Hanseatic the plains of Northern Europe; the Hamburg. Poles defeated the Turks in 1683 A SENSE O REEDOM How did the Jews fare? They at the gates of Vienna; and in 1920 This sense of freedom also per- came to Poland in the fourteenth they defeated the Bolsheviks in vaded the religious scene. Poland century, then a wholly agrarian front of Warsaw. Three times they 2 The Ludwig von Mises Institute THE CULTURAL BACKGROUND OF LUDWIG VON MISES saved Western civilization. Does Nietzsche, of Albert Einstein, and practical areas which followed the the world realize it? Of course not! also of 4riedrich August von long introduction, the study of His Polish, more than his Hayek! Young Mises, of course, economics is prominent. Jewish background, was decisive got a classical education: the mod- Mises found the law lectures at for Misess earliest years, but that ern languages he learned privately. the University of Vienna to be very did not conflict with his attach- one-sided and the teaching of eco- ment to Austria and the monarchy. STUDYING THE LAW nomics, with a few exceptions, Indeed, I met Mises for the first After getting his baccalaureate, below par. Already as a young man time in New York, in the company Mises studied law. Here we have he had a most critical sense. He of our former crown prince, to explain the character of Contin- was very much aware of the fact Archduke Otto von Habsburg, ental universities which have no that our universities, all perfectly whom he greatly admired. undergraduates: they are graduate autonomous bodies, state-financed Young Ludwig did not study in schools pure and simple. They tra- but not state-controlled, were one of the two linguistically Polish ditionally have four schools: of inevitably dominated by cliques universities of Lwów or Cracow, but theology, law, medicine, and phi- and factions; in the appointments, in Vienna. In order, however, to losophy, the last covering a multi- even family ties played a consider- understand his intellectual growth, tude of disciplines, almost all able role. belonging to the humanities. The it is important to realize how the The rector was addressed as Continental system of education Your Magnificence, and the uni- works. It differs radically from the versities were so sacrosanct that Anglo-American pattern. After the police were not permitted to four years of elementary training, enter them. Criminals hiding one entersif the parents are there had to be arrested by the ambitiousa school which re- Academic Legion, composed of motely resembles a combination of high school and college lasting students, and then were dragged eight (in Germany, nine) years. outside where they were handed over to the arm of the law. The There are three models of that freedom to teach was limitless. school: a classic one with eight (Academic freedom is a term years of Latin and six of Greek, a translated from German.) Even a semi-classic with Latin and one or professor, who, instead of lectur- two modern languages, and a more ing, read newspapers, could not be scientific one with only modern professors were chosen by the fac- languages. In all three types (the ulties, which constituted a self- dismissed. Every professor had classic one being naturally more perpetuating body. tenure up to the age of sixty-five or prestigious than the others), the On the Continent, the study of sixty-seven, when he had to retire local language, mathematics, lawthen as nowwas radically at eighty-two percent of his final geometry, history, geography, and different from legal studies in salary.
Recommended publications
  • Von Mises' Frequentist Approach to Probability
    Section on Statistical Education – JSM 2008 Von Mises’ Frequentist Approach to Probability Milo Schield1 and Thomas V. V. Burnham2 1 Augsburg College, Minneapolis, MN 2 Cognitive Systems, San Antonio, TX Abstract Richard Von Mises (1883-1953), the originator of the birthday problem, viewed statistics and probability theory as a science that deals with and is based on real objects rather than as a branch of mathematics that simply postulates relationships from which conclusions are derived. In this context, he formulated a strict Frequentist approach to probability. This approach is limited to observations where there are sufficient reasons to project future stability – to believe that the relative frequency of the observed attributes would tend to a fixed limit if the observations were continued indefinitely by sampling from a collective. This approach is reviewed. Some suggestions are made for statistical education. 1. Richard von Mises Richard von Mises (1883-1953) may not be well-known by statistical educators even though in 1939 he first proposed a problem that is today widely-known as the birthday problem.1 There are several reasons for this lack of recognition. First, he was educated in engineering and worked in that area for his first 30 years. Second, he published primarily in German. Third, his works in statistics focused more on theoretical foundations. Finally, his inductive approach to deriving the basic operations of probability is very different from the postulate-and-derive approach normally taught in introductory statistics. See Frank (1954) and Studies in Mathematics and Mechanics (1954) for a review of von Mises’ works. This paper is based on his two English-language books on probability: Probability, Statistics and Truth (1936) and Mathematical Theory of Probability and Statistics (1964).
    [Show full text]
  • The Interpretation of Probability: Still an Open Issue? 1
    philosophies Article The Interpretation of Probability: Still an Open Issue? 1 Maria Carla Galavotti Department of Philosophy and Communication, University of Bologna, Via Zamboni 38, 40126 Bologna, Italy; [email protected] Received: 19 July 2017; Accepted: 19 August 2017; Published: 29 August 2017 Abstract: Probability as understood today, namely as a quantitative notion expressible by means of a function ranging in the interval between 0–1, took shape in the mid-17th century, and presents both a mathematical and a philosophical aspect. Of these two sides, the second is by far the most controversial, and fuels a heated debate, still ongoing. After a short historical sketch of the birth and developments of probability, its major interpretations are outlined, by referring to the work of their most prominent representatives. The final section addresses the question of whether any of such interpretations can presently be considered predominant, which is answered in the negative. Keywords: probability; classical theory; frequentism; logicism; subjectivism; propensity 1. A Long Story Made Short Probability, taken as a quantitative notion whose value ranges in the interval between 0 and 1, emerged around the middle of the 17th century thanks to the work of two leading French mathematicians: Blaise Pascal and Pierre Fermat. According to a well-known anecdote: “a problem about games of chance proposed to an austere Jansenist by a man of the world was the origin of the calculus of probabilities”2. The ‘man of the world’ was the French gentleman Chevalier de Méré, a conspicuous figure at the court of Louis XIV, who asked Pascal—the ‘austere Jansenist’—the solution to some questions regarding gambling, such as how many dice tosses are needed to have a fair chance to obtain a double-six, or how the players should divide the stakes if a game is interrupted.
    [Show full text]
  • Qualitative Freedom
    Claus Dierksmeier Qualitative Freedom - Autonomy in Cosmopolitan Responsibility Translated by Richard Fincham Qualitative Freedom - Autonomy in Cosmopolitan Responsibility Claus Dierksmeier Qualitative Freedom - Autonomy in Cosmopolitan Responsibility Claus Dierksmeier Institute of Political Science University of Tübingen Tübingen, Baden-Württemberg, Germany Translated by Richard Fincham American University in Cairo New Cairo, Egypt Published in German by Published by Transcript Qualitative Freiheit – Selbstbestimmung in weltbürgerlicher Verantwortung, 2016. ISBN 978-3-030-04722-1 ISBN 978-3-030-04723-8 (eBook) https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04723-8 Library of Congress Control Number: 2018964905 © The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s) 2019. This book is an open access publication. Open Access This book is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this book are included in the book’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the book’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
    [Show full text]
  • Mathematicians Fleeing from Nazi Germany
    Mathematicians Fleeing from Nazi Germany Mathematicians Fleeing from Nazi Germany Individual Fates and Global Impact Reinhard Siegmund-Schultze princeton university press princeton and oxford Copyright 2009 © by Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, 6 Oxford Street, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1TW All Rights Reserved Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Siegmund-Schultze, R. (Reinhard) Mathematicians fleeing from Nazi Germany: individual fates and global impact / Reinhard Siegmund-Schultze. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-691-12593-0 (cloth) — ISBN 978-0-691-14041-4 (pbk.) 1. Mathematicians—Germany—History—20th century. 2. Mathematicians— United States—History—20th century. 3. Mathematicians—Germany—Biography. 4. Mathematicians—United States—Biography. 5. World War, 1939–1945— Refuges—Germany. 6. Germany—Emigration and immigration—History—1933–1945. 7. Germans—United States—History—20th century. 8. Immigrants—United States—History—20th century. 9. Mathematics—Germany—History—20th century. 10. Mathematics—United States—History—20th century. I. Title. QA27.G4S53 2008 510.09'04—dc22 2008048855 British Library Cataloging-in-Publication Data is available This book has been composed in Sabon Printed on acid-free paper. ∞ press.princeton.edu Printed in the United States of America 10 987654321 Contents List of Figures and Tables xiii Preface xvii Chapter 1 The Terms “German-Speaking Mathematician,” “Forced,” and“Voluntary Emigration” 1 Chapter 2 The Notion of “Mathematician” Plus Quantitative Figures on Persecution 13 Chapter 3 Early Emigration 30 3.1. The Push-Factor 32 3.2. The Pull-Factor 36 3.D.
    [Show full text]
  • 41 Friedrich August Von Hayek (1899-1992) Ludwig Van Den Hauwe
    41 Friedrich August von Hayek (1899-1992) Ludwig Van den Hauwe Biographical note Friedrich August von Hayek, a central figure in twentieth-century economics and a representative of the Austrian tradition, 1974 Nobel laureate in eco- nomics, was born on 8 May 1899, in Vienna, then the capital of the Austro- Hungarian empire. Following military service as an artillery officer in the First World War, Hayek entered the University of Vienna, where he attended the lectures of Friedrich von Wieser and obtained doctorates in jurisprudence (1921) and political science (1923). After spending a year in New York (1923-24), Hayek returned to Vienna where he joined the famous Privatseminar conducted by Ludwig von Mises. In 1927 Hayek became the first director of the Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research. On an invitation from Lionel Robbins, he delivered four lectures entitled 'Prices and production' at the London School of Economics in 1931 and subsequently accepted the Tooke Chair. He was a vigorous participant in the heated debates that raged in England during the 1930s concerning monetary, capital and business cycle theories. Hayek was to become the only intellectual opponent of John Maynard Keynes (see Caldwell, 1995). As an outgrowth of his participation in the debate over the possibility of economic calculation under socialism (Hayek, 1948 [1980], 119-208), the focus of Hayek's research shifted during the late 1930s and early 1940s to the role of knowledge and discovery in market processes, and to the methodological underpinnings of the Austrian tradition, particularly subjectivism and methodological individu- alism. In 1950, Hayek moved to the United States, joining the Committee on Social Thought at the University of Chicago.
    [Show full text]
  • Karel Engliš's Methodology of Social Sciences In
    The 14th International Days of Statistics and Economics, Prague, September 10-12, 2020 KAREL ENGLIŠ’S METHODOLOGY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES IN COMPARISON WITH WORK OF FRIEDRICH A. HAYEK Ilona Bažantová – Jan Horych Abstract The aim of this article is to analyse Karel Engliš’s methodology of social sciences in comparison with work of Friedrich A. Hayek (1899–1992). Karel Engliš (1880–1961) is the most influential economist of the interwar era of Czech and Czechoslovak economics, that being true both in the sphere of theory and practical policy. Engliš was a member of the so called Brno School of Economics, along with other authors, notably Václav Chytil (1907– 1980) and Jan Loevenstein (1886–1932), which developed and used its own particular methodology of social sciences and economics in particular based on teleological conception of economic phenomena. This conception of economics is in some aspects similar to that of the better known Austrian School of Economics, that consequently developed by the end of 20th Century into one of the most influential heterodox school of economics and which uses a teleological methodology of its own. This article points out some similarities and differences between both variations of the teleologically based Schools of Economics, using the work of Karel Engliš and Friedrich A. Hayek as the referential points. Key words: teleology, methodology of social sciences, Karel Engliš, F. A. Hayek JEL Code: B 31, B 53, Introduction Economics is one of the most dynamic social sciences of the recent era. Few other fields of social sciences have drawn so much attention and talent, as the branch that concerns itself with human behaviour between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.
    [Show full text]
  • The Emergence of French Statistics. How Mathematics Entered the World of Statistics in France During the 1920S
    The emergence of French statistics. How mathematics entered the world of statistics in France during the 1920s. Rémi Catellier, Laurent Mazliak To cite this version: Rémi Catellier, Laurent Mazliak. The emergence of French statistics. How mathematics entered the world of statistics in France during the 1920s.. 2009. hal-00397750v1 HAL Id: hal-00397750 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00397750v1 Preprint submitted on 23 Jun 2009 (v1), last revised 21 Feb 2011 (v2) HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. The emergence of French statistics How mathematics entered the world of statistics in France during the 1920s Remi´ CATELLIER1 and Laurent MAZLIAK2 Abstract This paper concerns the emergence of modern mathematical statistics in France after First World War. Emile Borel’s achievements are presented, and especially his creation of two institutions where mathematical statistics were developed, the Statistical Institute of Paris University, (ISUP) in 1922 and above all the Henri Poincar´eInstitute (IHP) in 1928. At the IHP, a new journal Annales de l’Institut Henri Poincar was created in 1931. We present the first papers dealing with mathematical statistics. INTRODUCTION The important transformations in the field of the mathematics of randomness between around 1910 and 1930 are now rather well listed.
    [Show full text]
  • Prof. Richard Von Mises
    Professor Richard von Mises (1883 – 1953) From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Richard_von_Mises ) Richard Edler von Mises ( 19 April 1883, Lwów – 14 July 1953, Boston, Massachusetts) was a scientist and mathematician who worked on solid mechanics, fluid mechanics, aerodynamics, aeronautics, statistics and probability theory. He held the position of Gordon-McKay Professor of Aerodynamics and Applied Mathematics at Harvard University. He described his work in his own words shortly before his death as being on “... practical analysis, integral and differential equations, mechanics, hydrodynamics and aerodynamics, constructive geometry, probability calculus, statistics and philosophy.” Although best known for his mathematical work, he also contributed to the philosophy of science as a neo- positivist, following the line of Ernst Mach. Historians of the Vienna Circle of logical empiricism recognize a "first phase" from 1907 through 1914 with Philipp Frank, Hans Hahn, and Otto Neurath. His older brother, Ludwig von Mises, held an opposite point of view with respect to positivism and epistemology. During his time in Istanbul, von Mises maintained close contact with Philipp Frank, a logical positivist and Professor of Physics in Prague until 1938. His literary interests included the Austrian novelist Robert Musil and the poet Rainer Maria Rilke, on whom he became a recognized expert. Von Mises’ Life: Eighteen months after his brother, the Austrian School economist Ludwig von Mises, Richard von Mises was born in Lemberg, then part of Austria-Hungary, into a Jewish family. His parents were Arthur Edler von Mises, a doctor of technical sciences who worked as an expert for the Austrian State Railways, and Adele Landau.
    [Show full text]
  • The Atavism of Social Justice
    Social Justice, Socialism & Democracy CIS Occasional Papers 2 Social Justice, Socialism & Democracy Three Australian Lectures by F.A. HAYEK. THE CENTRE FOR INDEPENDENT STUDIES 1979 This publication has been made possible with the support of World Economic Reporters Ltd., Hong Kong. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The Centre for Independent Studies gratefully acknowledges the consent of The University of Sydney, the Canberra Branch of The Economic Society of Australia and New Zealand and the Institute of Public Affairs (NSW) in publishing these lectures. / National Library of Australia Cataloguing in Publication Data Hayek, Friedrich August von, 1899- Social Justice, Socialism & Democracy (Centre for Independent Studies. CIS Occasional Papers; 2) Bibliography ISBN 0 9596485 3 4 1. Social justice. 2. Socialism. 3. Democracy. I. Title. (Series) , 323.4 Cover design by Suzie Chapman First published 1979 by the Centre for Independent Studies. O The Centre for Independent Studies. Contents Preface ............................................1 1. THE ATAVISM OF SOCIAL JUSTICE ............. 3 2. SOCIALISM AND SCIENCE .....................17 3. WHITHER DEMOCRACY? ......................33 Hayek -- Scholar. Teacher. Liberal ....................47 - a biographical essay Roger Randerson Australian 1976 lecture tour Roger Randerson ..........57 Preface In his ch'arming introduction to Austr.uliu (1930), Sir Keith Hancock tells how the newly-founded Federal Parliament was expected to make ''those experiments which were to demonstrate to the world the possibility of social justice" His book also records that "Australians have always disliked scientific economics and (still more) scientific economists" This seems to show that Australian economists have done their duty and performed the greatest service economists can render to the public. This is to question public beliefs which to them seem to be delusions, warning against measures and procedures which they have reason to think will fall short of what they are meant to achieve, and may often produce opposite results.
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek's Divorce and Move to Chicago · Econ Journal Watch
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: https://journaltalk.net/articles/5973 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 15(3) September 2018: 301–321 Hayek’s Divorce and Move to Chicago Lanny Ebenstein1 LINK TO ABSTRACT The personal life of a great intellectual is not always highly pertinent. Al- though Friedrich Hayek may have been, in his son’s words, “the great philosopher with feet of clay” (L. Hayek 1994–1997), his clay feet would not necessarily detract from his scholarly contributions. But since Hayek was a moral philosopher—his title at the University of Chicago was Professor of Social and Moral Science—his personal life may be more relevant than would be the case for intellectuals in other fields. The history of Hayek’s personal life has not always, to this point, been accurately told. The story of his divorce and move to Chicago has often been presented as one in which he discovered after World War II on a visit to Vienna to see his mother and other family members that a distant cousin of his, Helene Bitterlich, with whom he had a relationship as a young man, felt free to marry him. After Helene’s husband died, she and Hayek decided to marry, requiring Hayek to divorce his first wife, the former Hella Fritsch. At the same time, it has been suggested, he began to feel out of place in England in the immediate postwar era as a result of the policies of the first Labour Party government. He relocated to America, having first sought a post in the Economics Department at the University of Chicago and then, after being turned down by it as a result of The Road to Serfdom (1944), having been offered a position in the Committee on Social Thought.
    [Show full text]
  • Modernism, Fiction and Mathematics
    MODERNISM, FICTION AND MATHEMATICS JOHANN A. MAKOWSKY July 15, 2019 Review of: Nina Engelhardt, Modernism, Fiction and Mathematics, Edinburgh Critical Studies in Modernist Culture, Edinburgh University Press, Published June 2018 (Hardback), November 2019 (Paperback) ISBN Paperback: 9781474454841, Hardback: 9781474416238 1. The Book Under Review Nina Engelhardt's book is a study of four novels by three authors, Hermann Broch's trilogy The Sleepwalkers [2, 3], Robert Musil's The Man without Qualities [21, 23, 24], and Thomas Pynchon's Gravity's Rainbow and Against the Day [27, 28]. Her choice of authors and their novels is motivated by the impact the mathe- matics of the interwar period had on their writing fiction. It is customary in the humanities to describe the cultural ambiance of the interwar period between World War I and World War II as modernism. Hence the title of Engelhardt's book: Mod- ernism, Mathematics and Fiction. Broch and Musil are indeed modernist authors par excellence. Pynchon is a contemporary American author, usually classified by the literary experts as postmodern. arXiv:1907.05787v1 [math.HO] 12 Jul 2019 Hermann Broch in 1909 Robert Musil in 1900 1 2 JOHANN A. MAKOWSKY Thomas Pynchon ca. 1957 Works produced by employees of the United States federal government in the scope of their employment are public domain by statute. Engelhard's book is interesting for the literary minded mathematician for two reasons: First of all it draws attention to three authors who spent a lot of time and thoughts in studying the mathematics of the interwar period and used this experience in the shaping of their respective novels.
    [Show full text]
  • A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives in the Works of Friedrich A. Hayek
    RESEARCH ASSOCIATION for RAIS INTERDISCIPLINARY DOI: 10.5281/zenodo.1215124 MARCH 2018 STUDIES A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives in the Works of Friedrich A. Hayek Anusha Mahendran Curtin University [email protected] ABSTRACT: Given that the academic work of Friedrich Hayek has received eminent accolades (including the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics Sciences) and has been well recognised and widely referenced, this paper reviews the denial of the concept of social justice in many of the academic economic theory papers written by the renowned British-Austrian economist. The paper therefore effectively provides a critical analysis of some of Hayek’s socio-political and economic theories relating to this issue. It attempts to do this by adopting the perspective of an objective and analytical economist with reference to and by examining the content of three of Hayek’s well known economic texts, namely The Road to Serfdom (1944); Law, Legislation and Liberty (1973-79) and the Fatal Conceit Conceit: The Errors of Socialism (1988). KEYWORDS: social justice, economics, Friedrich Hayek 1. Introduction Friedrich August von Hayek (who was also commonly referred to as F.A. Hayek) was an Austrian-British economist and was well known for his staunch defence of classical liberalism (Birner and van Rip 1994). Hayek was born in Vienna, Austria in 1899 and the majority of his perspectives were derived from theories and philosophies from the Austrian School of Economics (Birner and van Rip 1994). 82 MAHENDRAN: A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives The primary basis of the Austrian School of Economic Thought is centred around the concept of methodological individualism which entails the ideology that the motivations and actions of individuals drive social phenomenon (Boettke and Leeson 2003).
    [Show full text]