GATT and the New Protectionism

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

GATT and the New Protectionism David M. Gould William C. Gruben Senior Economist Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas GATT and the New Protectionism he successful completion of the Uruguay Round What these barriers imply for free trade are T of the General Agreement on Tariffs and sometimes difficult to understand because often Trade (GATT) has generated much optimism they have touched on fairness issues. In many about the future of world trade, and with good countries policymakers—and their supporters in reason. If ratified, the accord will not only eliminate industries that face foreign competition—have tariffs on many goods, but will be the first GATT- devoted much effort to counteract what they round accord to address intellectual property define as unfair trade practices by foreign coun- rights, trade in services, and agricultural subsidies. tries. Unfair trade practices are typically thought to An important question, however, is how much include: 1) subsidies on exports by foreign gov- this new accord can limit future protectionism. ernments and 2) dumping, which is the act of When trade liberalization curtails one form of selling goods for a lower price abroad than in the protectionism, new forms appear almost routinely. home or other markets. To offset foreign subsidies While GATT agreements steadily reduced tariffs to exports the government of the importing coun- on manufactures (from an average of 40 percent in try sometimes erects special tariffs to raise the 1947 to about 5 percent now, as shown in Figure artificially low prices of these goods. These tariff 1), the United States and many other countries barriers are referred to as countervailing duties. were developing other, more arcane administra- Antidumping duties are typically imposed when tive and legal barriers. the government of an importing country suspects that the exporting country is dumping goods on its markets. Figure 1 The particular circumstances under which Tariffs in Industrial Countries countervailing and antidumping actions are used— and the procedures developed to assess the “un- Average tariff rates fairness” of others’ trade practices—have raised (Percent) suspicions about policymakers’ motivations. Per- 50 haps, some have argued, these “fairness” doctrines are vehicles for disguised protectionism. Allegations of disguised protectionism have 40 become more common as efforts to preserve “fair” trade have multiplied. During the 1960s, 30 GATT member countries initiated fewer than 20 10 Ken Emery offered extremely helpful comments as the reviewer for this article. We also benefited from the discus- 0 sion and comments of Steve Brown, Michael Finger, Seth 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 Kaplan, David Mueller, Tracy Murray, and Lori Taylor. All SOURCE: Stoeckel, Pearce, and Banks (1990). remaining errors are solely our responsibility. Economic Review — Third Quarter 1994 29 30 Table 1 Number of Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Cases Initiated, January 1980– June 1989 Jan. ’80 Jul. ’80 Jul. ’81 Jul. ’82 Jul. ’83 Jul. ’84 Jul. ’85 Jul. ’86 Jul. ’87 Jul. ’88 Jan. ’80 Country/Group Jun. ’80 Jun. ’81 Jun. ’82 Jun. ’83 Jun. ’84 Jun. ’85 Jun. ’86 Jun. ’87 Jun. ’88 Jun. ’89 Jun. ’89 Antidumping cases Australia 36 61 54 71 70 63 54 40 20 19 488 Canada 26 48 64 34 26 35 27 24 20 14 318 European Community 17 37 39 26 33 34 23 17 30 29 285 United States 37 24 51 19 46 61 63 41 31 25 398 Other developed countries 13201 025 91235 Developing countries 00000 034131434 All countries 117 173 210 150 176 193 172 131 123 113 1,558 Countervailing duty cases Australia NA NA NA 6 3 5 3 3 0 2 22 Canada 3 3 0 2 3 2 1 4 0 1 19 European Community 10131 000 006 United States 32 17 75 35 22 60 43 11 13 8 316 Chile 0 0 61 33 20 10 11 0 0 0 135 Other countries 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 4 0 7 All countries 36 20 137 80 50 77 58 19 17 11 505 Antidumping plus countervailing duty cases Australia NA NA NA 77 73 68 57 43 20 21 359 Canada 29 51 64 36 29 37 28 28 20 15 337 European Community 18 37 40 29 34 34 23 17 30 29 291 United States 69 41 126 54 68 121 106 52 44 33 714 Other developed countries 13212 026131242 Federal ReserveBankofDallas Developing countries 0 0 61 33 20 10 14 1 3 14 156 All countries 117 132 293 230 226 270 230 147 130 124 1,899 SOURCE: Finger 1993. twelve antidumping actions per year. By the States than at home, or if foreign governments second half of the 1970s, the United States alone subsidize exports to the United States, U.S. laws averaged more than thirty-five per year. As Table and rules accommodate U.S. efforts at retaliation. 1 shows, in the 1980s the total of cases initiated But is unfair trade really unfair? by GATT signatory countries exceeded one hun- Economists often deny that below-cost prices dred per year. or foreign export subsidies mean unfair trade. Concerns that “fair” trade laws are vehicles for After all, if foreign firms want to sell cheaply in the protectionism have become even more acute with United States, why should U.S. consumers not be the advent of the Uruguay Round. While rough allowed the obvious benefit? While this argument guidelines for using antidumping and counter- recognizes the benefits to consumers, it dismisses vailing duties have appeared in past GATT agree- the effects of unfair trading on some domestic ments, the Uruguay Round accord has introduced producers and ignores other arguments against much more formalization and detail to accommo- unfair trading practices. Moreover, as Bhagwati date and codify such retaliation. Moreover, these (1988) notes, “a free trade regime that does not rein codifications greatly resemble those of the United in or seek to regulate artificial subventions will States, a principal exponent of antidumping and likely help trigger its own demise.” countervailing measures. Conversely, in the more concrete world of The Uruguay Round’s various approaches government policy, both arguments and govern- to addressing government trade policy—lower- ment policies in support of antidumping and ing tariffs here, sanctioning some types of anti- countervailing duties typically place the interests dumping actions and countervailing duties there— of import-competing industries over the interests raise questions about the accord’s overall implica- of consumers and also over those of producers tions for free trade. The related central question who use imported inputs. (See the box entitled addressed in this article is whether the recent “Do Fair Trade Laws Protect the Economy?”) An changes in GATT will discourage the most pro- analysis of eight antidumping duties imposed by tectionist aspects of these administered trade regu- the United States between 1989 and 1990 showed lations. Because the accord adopts many aspects that for each $1 gained by the protected indus- of U.S. laws and administrative procedures con- tries, the U.S. economy as a whole lost $3.60, on cerning antidumping and countervailing duties, average (Anderson 1993). Moreover, according to we use the U.S. experience of recent years to the same study, the cost per job created in the assess what may be in store for the world trading protected industries was $113,800, which is sub- environment under the new GATT. stantially higher than the $14,300 average salary We begin by examining what has been seen paid for these jobs. The extra cost comes from as unfair trade, and we discuss the economic argu- the higher price consumers must pay for these ments for imposing antidumping and countervail- domestic goods and the less efficient use of ing duties. We then outline how fair trade laws domestic resources. have been applied in the United States and discuss Another argument against unfair trade is that why some analysts have claimed that these laws foreign nations can act predatorily to capture are biased toward protectionism. Finally, we domestic markets. But this argument is also sub- assess the impact of the Uruguay Round of GATT ject to criticism. The argument is based on the on the application of fair trade laws. We conclude assumption that once foreign producers capture with an outlook for the future of the world trading domestic markets, competitors will not re-enter environment. domestic markets when prices begin to rise. But if foreign producers cannot block domestic pro- When is trade unfair? ducers from re-entering a market after it is cap- tured, they will have to keep their prices at a The express intention of fair trade laws is to competitive level to maintain their market share. prevent foreign sellers from pricing and selling Some analysts claim that certain high-tech anticompetitively or predatorily in your country. industries can develop natural barriers to entry If foreign exporters sell for less in the United that allow them to capture a particular market and Economic Review — Third Quarter 1994 31 Do Fair Trade Laws Protect the Economy? While antidumping and countervailing laws may pro- tition that lies behind the classical arguments for free trade. tect particular industries from foreign competition, broader In a real world environment, some have argued, other arguments based on the benefits of these measures to countries might subsidize their industries and capture U.S. the whole economy are typically ill founded. There are markets at the expense of future U.S. income. basically three arguments for antidumping and counter- Although economists have long recognized the impor- vailing duties. The first is simply that subsidized or tance of economies of scale, innovation, and international dumped imports of textiles, consumer electronics, and oligopolies, countries have rarely, if ever, been able to automobiles cost domestic textile workers, electronics capture excess profits from other markets for long.
Recommended publications
  • Non-Tariff Measures Overview Glossary of Related Terms
    Non-Tariff Measures Overview Glossary of Related Terms Note: With thanks to the following for definitions provided here: Deardorff's Glossary of International Economics, the 1 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), the United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) and the World Trade Organization (WTO). Terms Definition Absolute Advantage (AA) The ability to produce a good at lower cost, in terms of real resources, than another country. In a Ricardian model, cost is in terms of labor only. Absolute advantage is neither necessary nor sufficient for a country to export a good. Ad Valorem Equivalent The ad valorem tariff that would be equivalent, in terms of its effects on trade, Terms price, or some other measure, to a nontariff barrier. Ad Valorem Tariff (A Tariff defined as a percentage of the value of an imported good. Percentage of Price) Adjustment Assistance Government program to assist workers and/or firms whose industry has declined, either due to import competition (trade adjustment assistance) or from other causes. Such programs usually have two (conflicting) goals: to lessen hardship for those affected, and to help them change their behavior -- what, how, or where they produce. AGOA U.S. legislation enacted May 2000 providing tariff preferences to African countries that qualify, including trade facilitation and technical assistance to producers. As of January 2016, 40 countries were listed as eligible. Several countries have had their eligibility removed and some later reinstated over the years. Anti-Dumping Measures A complaint by a domestic producer that imports are being dumped, leading to an anti-dumping duty if both dumping and injury are found in the resulting investigation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Risks of Protectionism
    Box 1 THE RISKS OF PROTECTIONISM Since the intensifi cation of the global fi nancial crisis in September 2008, the sharp contraction in global trade has been a key factor propagating the economic downturn across borders, making it a truly global phenomenon.1 At the same time, protectionist pressures have been rising worldwide, as signalled by policy statements and opinion polls, as well as by recent developments in multilateral, regional and bilateral trade negotiations.2 Meanwhile anecdotal evidence of discrimination against foreign suppliers of goods and services has also been emerging. Against this background, this box discusses recent features of protectionism and the adverse implications for competitiveness, economic activity and welfare. Gauging the full extent of recent protectionist initiatives is far from easy. Relevant data become available with considerable delay and many forms of non-tariff barriers or complex forms of protection are very diffi cult to identify and quantify. Often statistics on the use of contingent protection, including safeguard measures, anti-dumping and countervailing duties, are used as an early indicator of trade protectionism. However, according to the World Trade Organization, signifi cant gaps exist in the empirical evidence on contingent protection, making it diffi cult to gather general trends from these data.3 Hence, the assessment of protectionist trends necessarily needs to rely on indirect evidence. Econometric analysis by the World Trade Organization suggests that the frequency of anti- dumping actions, countervailing duties and safeguards seems to be linked to the business cycle, with some statistical evidence of an increase in global anti-dumping activity during macroeconomic downturns.
    [Show full text]
  • Dumping, Protectionism and Free Trade
    DUMPING, PROTECTIONISM AND FREE TRADE Ron Sheppard Catherine Atkins Views expressed in Agribusiness and Economics Research Unit Discussion Papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Director, other members of staff, or members of the Management Committee Discussion Paper No.140 September 1994 Agribusiness & Economics Research Unit PO Box 84 Lincoln University CANTERBURY Telephone No: (64) (3) 325 2811 Fax No: (64) (3) 325 3847 ISSN 1170-7607 ISBN 0-909042-01-2 AGRIBUSINESS & ECONOMICS RESEARCH UNIT The Agribusiness and Economics Research Unit (AERU) operates The major research areas supported by the AERU include trade from Lincoln University providing research expertise for a wide policy, marketing (both institutional and consumer), accounting, range of organisations concerned with production, processing, finance, management, agricultural economics and rural sociol­ distribution, finance and marketing. ogy. In addition to the research activities, the AERU supports conferences and seminars on topical issues and AERU staff are The AERU operates as a semi-commercial research agency involved in a wide range of professional and University related Research contracts are carried out for clients on a commercial extension activities. basis and University research is supported by the AERU through sponsorship of postgraduate research programmes. Research Founded as the Agricultural Economics Research Unit in 1962 clients include Government Departments, both within New from an annual grant provided by the Department of Scientific and Zealand and from other countries, international agencies, New Industrial Research (DSIR), the AERU has grown to become an Zealand companies and organisations, individuals and farmers. Independent, major source of business and economic research Research results are presented through private client reports, expertise.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 6 Subsidies and Countervailing Measures
    CHAPTER 6 SUBSIDIES AND COUNTERVAILING MEASURES 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES (1) Subsidies and Countervailing Measures Subsidies have been provided widely throughout the world as a tool for realizing government policies, in such forms as grants (normal subsidies), tax exemptions, low-interest financing, investments and export credits. There are six primary categories of subsidies, divided by purpose: 1) export subsidies, 2) subsidies contingent upon the use of domestic over imported goods, 3) industrial promotion subsidies, 4) structural adjustment subsidies, 5) regional development subsidies, and 6) research and development subsidies. By beneficiary, there are two primary categories: 1) subsidies that are not limited to specific businesses or industries (non-specific subsidies), and 2) subsidies that are limited to specific businesses and industries (specific subsidies). Although governments articulate ostensibly legitimate goals for their subsidy programmes, it is widely perceived that government subsidies may give excessive protection to domestic industries. In such cases, subsidies act as a barrier to trade, by distorting the competitive relationships that develop naturally in a free trading system. Exports of subsidized products may injure the domestic industry producing the same product in the importing country. Similarly, subsidized products may gain artificial advantages in third- country markets and impede other countries’ exports to those markets. Because of this potential the WTO Agreements prohibit with respect to industrial goods any export subsidies and subsidies contingent upon the use of domestic over imported goods, as having a particularly high trade-distorting effect. Furthermore, even for subsidies that are not prohibited, it allows Member countries importing subsidized goods to enact countermeasures, such as countervailing duties if such goods injure the domestic industry and certain procedural requirements are met .
    [Show full text]
  • G/Adp/N/1/Rus/1
    WORLD TRADE G/ADP/N/1/RUS/1 G/SCM/N/1/RUS/1 ORGANIZATION G/SG/N/1/RUS/1 3 October 2012 (12-5357) Committee on Anti-Dumping Practices Original: English Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures Committee on Safeguards NOTIFICATION OF LAWS AND REGULATIONS UNDER ARTICLES 18.5, 32.6 AND 12.6 OF THE AGREEMENTS RUSSIAN FEDERATION The following communication, dated 13 September 2012, is being circulated at the request of the Delegation of the Russian Federation. _______________ I. RELEVANT LAWS AND REGULATIONS Pursuant to Article 18.5 of the Agreement on Implementation of Article VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994, Article 32.6 of the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures and Article 12.6 Agreement on Safeguards please find attached texts of laws and regulations as of 22 August 2012. The English text of the attached laws and regulations is not an officially translated text. II. TRANSPARENCY 1. The Department for Internal Market Defense of the Eurasian Economic Commission is the responsible authority for conducting safeguard, antidumping and countervailing investigations. Address: Smolensky bulvar, 3/5, Moscow, Russian Federation, 119121 Tel: 7 495 604 40 38 (*1272) Fax: 7 495 604 40 38 (*1109) Website: www.tsouz.ru 2. Notifications of the responsible authority concerning safeguard, antidumping and countervailing actions are published on the website of the Eurasian Economic Community at http://www.tsouz.ru. The list of laws and regulations: 1. Agreement on the application of safeguards, antidumping and countervailing measures against third countries of 25 January 2008; 2. Agreement on the application of safeguard, antidumping and countervailing measures in transitional period of 19 November 2010; G/ADP/N/1/RUS/1 G/SCM/N/1/RUS/1 G/SG/N/1/RUS/1 Page 2 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Priority Trade Issue: AD/CVD
    Overview Collecting Revenue Leveraging Domestic Partnerships Due to critical effects on the U.S. industry, CBP The United States uses a retrospective system CBP is committed to ensuring that AD/CVD has identified Antidumping and to assess AD/CVD, which means that the duties laws are vigorously enforced. To this end, CBP Countervailing Duties (AD/CVD) as a that CBP collects from importers at the time of has established key partnerships with the U.S. Priority Trade Issue (PTI). AD/CVD are entry are only estimated, and the final duties are Department of Commerce, U.S. additional duties determined by the U.S. often not determined until two to three years Immigrations and Customs Enforcement (ICE), Department of Commerce which offset unfair later, when the U.S. Department of Commerce U.S. Department of Treasury, Office of the U.S. low prices and foreign government subsidies on instructs CBP to collect final duties owed. CBP Trade Representative, and domestic industries. certain imported goods. AD/CVD rates are in uses all of its legal authority to collect any CBP and ICE specifically partner to identify, some cases significantly higher than other duties. penalize, and disrupt distribution channels of importation duties. AD/CVD cash deposit rates imported goods that seek to evade AD/CVD. range from 0% through 1731.75% These high duty rates may result in efforts to evade the What is a Priority Trade Issue (PTI)? CBP’s Roles and Responsibilities duties and illegally import the goods. PTIs represent high-risk areas that can cause • Administer AD/CVD Entries significant revenue loss, harm the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Trade Law and Policy Series #7: the Countervailing Duty Law's Applicability to Nonmarket Economies
    ALAN F. HOLMER* t JUDITH HIPPLER BELLO CURRENT DEVELOPMENTS U.S. Trade Law and Policy Series #7: The Countervailing Duty Law's Applicability to Nonmarket Economies I. Introduction The U.S. Court of International Trade recently overruled the Depart- ment of Commerce's 1984 decision that the countervailing duty law cannot be applied to nonmarket economy countries. On September 17, 1985, the government filed its notice of appeal to the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit. Affirmation by the appeals court of the lower court's ruling would delight domestic producers faced with nonmarket economy import competi- tion; they would likely besiege the Commerce Department with complaints about allegedly subsidized imports from nonmarket economy countries. Reversal of the lower court's ruling would be welcome news to the nonmar- ket economy countries, their producers and exporters, and U.S. importers and consumers who purchase nonmarket economy goods. It could also increase domestic support for an alternative remedy for nonmarket econ- omy imports in lieu of the antidumping and countervailing duty laws. This article reviews the Commerce Department's original decision, the Court of International Trade's reversal, and the likely significance of these develop- ments. *General Counsel, Office of the U.S. Trade Representative. Formerly Deputy Assistant Secretary of Commerce for Import Administration, Deputy Assistant to the President for Intergovernmental Affairs, Administrative Assistant to Senator Bob Packwood. tDeputy General Counsel, Office of the U.S. Trade Representative. Formerly Deputy (for Policy) to the Deputy Assistant Secretary of Commerce for Import Administration; Attorney- adviser, Department of State. 320 THE INTERNATIONAL LAWYER A.
    [Show full text]
  • The Applicability of the United States Countervailing Duty Law to Imports from Nonmarket Economy Countries
    Fordham International Law Journal Volume 9, Issue 3 1985 Article 4 The Applicability of the United States Countervailing Duty Law to Imports from Nonmarket Economy Countries Karen A. O’Brien∗ ∗ Copyright c 1985 by the authors. Fordham International Law Journal is produced by The Berke- ley Electronic Press (bepress). http://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/ilj The Applicability of the United States Countervailing Duty Law to Imports from Nonmarket Economy Countries Karen A. O’Brien Abstract This Note will examine the applicability of the countervailing duty law to nonmarket economies. Part I will review the legislative history of the countervailing duty statute and its judicial and ad- ministrative interpretations. Part II will discuss the Commerce Department rulings, the Court of International Trade’s reversal of these rulings in Continental Steel Corp. v. United States and the Federal Circuit’s reversal of the CIT. Finally, Part III will analyze both approaches to the issue. This Note will conclude that the counterveiling duty law should apply to goods from nonmarket economies. THE APPLICABILITY OF THE UNITED STATES COUNTERVAILING DUTY LAW TO IMPORTS FROM NONMARKET ECONOMY COUNTRIES INTRODUCTION The countervailing duty law' is one of the principal nontariff barriers2 used by the United States to combat unfair 1. United States countervailing duty law is embodied in the Tariff Act of 1930, ch. 497, tit. III, § 303, 46 Stat. 687 (codified as amended at 19 U.S.C. § 1303 (1982)). The Tariff Act provides as follows: (a) Levy of countervailing duties
    [Show full text]
  • G/Adp/N/1/Slv/3
    WORLD TRADE G/ADP/N/1/SLV/3 G/SCM/N/1/SLV/3 ORGANIZATION 8 April 2008 (08-1565) Committee on Anti-Dumping Practices Original: Spanish Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures NOTIFICATION OF LAWS AND REGULATIONS UNDER ARTICLES 18.5 AND 32.6 OF THE AGREEMENTS EL SALVADOR The following communication, dated 2 April 2008, is being circulated at the request of the delegation of El Salvador. _______________ Pursuant to Article 18.5 of the Agreement on Implementation of Article VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 and Article 32.6 of the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, we submit herewith a copy of the Central American Regulations on Unfair Business Practices, published in Official Journal No. 89, Vol. 375, of 18 May 2007, which gives effect to Resolution No. 193-2007 (COMIECO-XLIV) of the Council of Ministers for Economic Integration. The Regulations in question supersede the Central American Regulations on Unfair Business Practices notified previously (G/ADP/N/1/SLV/2, G/SCM/N/1/SLV/2), which were adopted through Resolution No. 12-95 (COMRIEDRE-II) of 12 December 1995 by the Council of Ministers Responsible for Economic Integration and Regional Development. G/ADP/N/1/SLV/3 G/SCM/N/1/SLV/3 Page 2 RESOLUTION No. 193-2007 (COMIECO-XLIV) THE COUNCIL OF MINISTERS FOR ECONOMIC INTEGRATION WHEREAS: 1. By Resolution No. 12-95 (COMRIEDRE-II) of 12 December 1995, the Council of Ministers Responsible for Economic Integration and Regional Development approved the Central American Regulations on Unfair Business Practices; 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Antidumping and Countervailing Duties in Regional Trade Agreements: Canada-U.S
    University of Minnesota Law School Scholarship Repository Minnesota Journal of International Law 1994 Antidumping and Countervailing Duties in Regional Trade Agreements: Canada-U.S. FTA, NAFTA and beyond Gilbert R. Winham Heather A. Grant Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mjil Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Winham, Gilbert R. and Grant, Heather A., "Antidumping and Countervailing Duties in Regional Trade Agreements: Canada-U.S. FTA, NAFTA and beyond" (1994). Minnesota Journal of International Law. 12. https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mjil/12 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the University of Minnesota Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Minnesota Journal of International Law collection by an authorized administrator of the Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Antidumping and Countervailing Duties in Regional Trade Agreements: Canada- U.S. FTA, NAFTA and Beyond* Gilbert R. Winham** Heather A. Grant*** The use of antidumping (AD) and countervailing duties (CVDs) to prevent or remedy unfair trade practices has been an important issue during recent multilateral and regional trade negotiations. It is a particularly difficult issue because parties differ on the role unfair trade remedies should play in trade pol- icy. One approach is to view these measures as an attempt to remedy or offset unfair trade practices by foreign governments or exporters. Alternatively, exporters may view these measures as politically motivated
    [Show full text]
  • Antidumping, Countervailing Duties and Trade Remedies: "Let's Make a Deal"??- Views from a Domestic Practitioner
    Antidumping, Countervailing Duties and Trade Remedies: "Let's Make A Deal"??- Views from a Domestic Practitioner TERENCE P. STEWART, AMY S. DWYER, AND MARTA M. PRADO* I. Background During the Uruguay Round, various agreements were negotiated in the Rules area. One, the Agreement on Safeguards, was a first agreement expanding on the rights and obligations Members had under article XIX of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATYD of 1994. Two others were refinements of prior Codes dealing with rights and obligations under articles VI and XVI of GATT 1994. The Agreement on Implementation of article VI of GATT 1994 (Antidumping Agreement) represented the third attempt by the multi- lateral trading system to work through the rights and obligations of nations under article VI of GAT 1994 (and its predecessor GATT 1947) which, inter alia, condemns injurious dumping. Similarly, the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM Agreement) was the second cut at defining what, if any, limitations exist on nations' rights to provide subsidies under article XVI of GATT 1994 (and its predecessor GATT 1947) or how countervailing duty investigations should proceed under article VI of GATT 1994. The Antidumping and SCM Agreements are quite detailed on a host of issues, both sub- stantive (e.g., definition of dumping and actionable subsidies) and procedural (e.g., time for questionnaire responses, content of notices), and should go a long way to ensuring greater uniformity in administration by Member nations. While the Agreements required a number of changes to preexisting U.S. law, the Agreements incorporated much of U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Growing Problem of Antidumping Protection
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: International Trade in East Asia, NBER-East Asia Seminar on Economics, Volume 14 Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Andrew K. Rose, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-37896-9 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/ito_05-1 Conference Date: September 5-7, 2003 Publication Date: August 2005 Title: The Growing Problem of Antidumping Protection Author: Thomas J. Prusa URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c0198 10 The Growing Problem of Antidumping Protection Thomas J. Prusa 10.1 Introduction While the public’s and press’s imagination has tended to focus on hot- button issues such as agriculture, labor standards, and the environment, it is the dozens, if not hundreds, of other less publicly visible policies that will largely determine the success of the Doha Round of the World Trade Or- ganization (WTO). Chief among these less celebrated policies is anti- dumping (AD). Antidumping is a fairly inconspicuous trade policy—I have never seen a picture of a WTO protestor carrying a placard lamenting the spread of AD or, for that matter, praising the virtues of AD. Despite its somewhat low public profile, many studies have shown that AD imposes heavy costs on both implementing and affected countries. For instance, Gallaway, Bloni- gen, and Flynn (1999) estimate that only the Multifiber Arrangement im- poses larger welfare costs on the U.S. economy than do antidumping and countervailing duty actions.1 Messerlin (2001) estimates that AD protec- tion and farm policies were about equally as costly for European Union Thomas J.
    [Show full text]