Keynesian and Classical Unemployment in Four Countries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Keynesian and Classical Unemployment in Four Countries ROBERT M. COEN Northwestern University BERT G. HICKMAN Stanford University Keynesian and Classical Unemploymentin Four Countries THE WORLD ECONOMY entered a period of stagflationduring the 1970s. Markedly slower growth combined with rates of unemployment and inflationthat were unprecedentedlyhigh for the postwar era, and the slowdown persists to this day. In this paper we draw on a larger study of the deceleration of potential growth to emphasize the contributory role of demandshortfalls in prolongingand deepeningthe adjustmentto lower growth rates of productivityand real wages. A key issue is the relative importanceof high real wages and deficient aggregatedemand as proximatecauses of the rise of unemployment. We use the theoreticalapproach developed by Hickmanto estimate the classical and Keynesian componentsof excess unemploymentin the United States, Germany, Austria, and the United Kingdom.1The ap- proach is closely related to the "wage gap" analysis of Michael Bruno This paperis partof a researchproject on unemployment,real wages, and economic growthin selectedOECD countries. The supportof the AustrianNational Bank is gratefully acknowledged.We are indebtedto the BrookingsPanel and to Erich Streissler, Stefan Schleicher,Stephen King, GeorgeEvans, Jean Waelbroeck,and seminarparticipants at the Universityof Vienna,Project LINK, and StanfordUniversity for theircomments and suggestions.Thanks are also due to ChristianStadlinger for his valuableassistance. 1. BertG. Hickman,"Real Wages, Aggregate Demand, and Unemployment"(Center for EconomicPolicy Research, Stanford University, July 1986).Forthcoming in European Economic Review. 123 124 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1987 andJeffrey Sachs, butit differsin buildingon the assumptionof imperfect competitionand cost minimizationrather than perfect competitionand profitmaximization as the basis for labor demand.2Similarly, it differs fromthe generaldisequilibrium or non-market-clearingmodels of Robert Barroand Herschel Grossmanand EdmondMalinvaud in that it allows for coexistence of classical and Keynesian unemploymentinstead of explainingthem as separateregimes in marketswith price-takingfirms and rationedbuyers and sellers.3 Our empirical measures of the wage and demand components of employment are computed from a conditional demand function for aggregateman-hours, with the real wage and outputtreated as predeter- mined to the employment decisions of firms. Since the real wage and aggregatedemand are in realityendogenous variables, the decomposition deals only with their relative importance as proximate sources of unemployment.A deeper approachwould employ a complete macro- economic model endogenizing aggregate output and real wages and capable of explainingthe evolution of both as a function of exogenous shocks to aggregate supply and demand, as recommendedby Robert Solow.4 That would be feasible in our U.S. model, which is just such a complete system, but not in the truncatedsupply-side models we have estimatedfor the Europeancountries in the study. Concepts of Keynesian and Classical Unemployment The standardfixed-price or non-market-clearingmodel distinguishes Keynesianand classical unemploymentstates as separateregimes under fixed wage and price levels by incorporatingquantity constraints into the optimizationproblems of firmsand households.5 2. Michael Bruno and Jeffrey D. Sachs, Economics of Worldwide Stagflation (Harvard UniversityPress, 1985). 3. RobertJ. Barroand Herschel I. Grossman,"A GeneralDisequilibrium Model of Incomeand Unemployment,"American Economic Review, vol. 61 (March1971), pp. 82- 93; Edmond Malinvaud, The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered (Oxford: Basil Blackwood, 1977). 4. Robert M. Solow, "Unemployment:Getting the Questions Right," Economica, vol. 53 (Supplement,1986), pp. S23-S34. 5. Basic references include Don Patinkin, Money, Interest and Prices: An Integration of Monetaryand Value Theory,2d ed. (Harperand Row, 1965);Robert Clower, "The Robert M. Coen and Bert G. Hickman 125 The representativefirm is a price taker in its marketsfor inputs and output. It maximizes profits subject to a well-behaved production function, Y = F(K,L), and a product demand constraint, Y c Y. For fixed K in the short run, the optimalsolution for L is the min-equation (1) Ld = min[F- 1 (Y,K), FL 1 (WIP,K)], where WIPis the real productwage. The unconstrainedor notional short-runfunctions for labor demand and productsupply are (2) Ld = FL1 (WIP,K), given by the first-ordermarginal productivity condition, and (3) ys = F(Ld,K). The classical labor supplyfunction is (4) Ls = Ls(W/P), where the real wage equates the marginaldisutility of effort and the marginalutility of consumption. With flexible wages and prices, a Walrasiansolution of equations 2 and 4 would yield full employment at the equilibriumreal wage. With fixed wages and prices, however, if notional supply exceeds effective demandat the given price, the sales of firmsare rationedin the product market. Labor demand is then output-constrainedand is smaller than laborsupply at the existing real wage, resultingin Keynesianunemploy- ment: (5) Ld = F-1 (Y,K) < Ls (WIP). Thus Keynesian unemploymentis the spillover effect of disequilibrium in the productmarket. Classical unemploymentmay occur if the fixed price is below the Walrasianequilibrium level. Effective demand then exceeds notional KeynesianCounterrevolution: A TheoreticalAppraisal," in F. H. Hahn and F. P. R. Brechling, eds., The Theory of Interest Rates (London: Macmillan, 1965), pp. 103-25; Barroand Grossman, "A General DisequilibriumModel"; Malinvaud,The Theoryof UnemploymentReconsidered; Jean-PascalBenassy, "Neo-Keynesian Disequilibrium Theory in a Monetary Economy," Review of Economic Studies, vol. 42 (October 1975), pp. 503-23; Jean-Pascal Benassy, The Economics of Market Disequilibrium (Academic Press, 1982). 126 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1987 supply. Firms have no incentive to increase supply at the existing real wage, so the short side of the market prevails and households are rationed.Firms are unconstrainedand operatingon their notionallabor demandand output supply schedules, but since the real wage exceeds the Walrasianlevel, labor demandfalls short of full-employmentlabor supply. In both unemploymentstates householdsare constrainedin the labor market, and hence effective demandfalls short of the notional demand that would result from unconstrainedutility maximization.Indeed, as Robert Clower showed, it is because of the spillover from the labor market constraint that income is an argument in the consumption function.6 However, the approach of this paper modifies the standardfixed- price model, in which prices are fixed over the periodbeing analyzed, in two principal respects. First, we assume imperfect competition with firms setting prices in the face of uncertain demand. We assume that prices are not continually adjusted. Second, firms choose capital and labor inputs so as to minimize the cost of producingthe quantitythey expect to sell at the price they have set. The assumptionof imperfectcompetition is adoptedfor both theoret- ical and empiricalreasons. Perfect competitionamong atomistic price- takingfirms is incompatiblewith the fixed-priceassumption except for very shortadjustment periods afterunexpected shocks. As an empirical matter, moreover, auction markets are largely limited to agricultural productsand primarymetals. There is also solid econometricevidence of the ubiquitousexistence of cost-basedprice setting,with only a limited scope for markupvariations in response to shifts in productdemand.7 One important consequence of cost-based price setting is that it reduces the sensitivity of real wages to changes in effective demand. Increases or decreases in nominalwages induced by shifts in aggregate demandinduce price movements in the samedirection, greatly mitigating the response of real wages to demand pressures in labor markets. In contrast, supply shocks that directlyraise productioncosts, such as the 6. Clower, "The KeynesianCounterrevolution." 7. Otto Eckstein, ed., TheEconometricsofPriceDetermination, conference sponsored by Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Social Science Research Council(Board of Governors, 1972);Phillip Cagan, "The Hydra-HeadedMonster: The Problemof Inflationin the UnitedStates," DomesticAffairs Study 26 (Washington,D.C.: AmericanEnterprise Institute, 1974); William D. Nordhaus,"The Falling Share of Profits," BPEA, 1:1974, pp. 169-208. Robert M. Coen and Bert G. Hickman 127 energy shocks of the 1970s, have greater potential to alter real wage rates unless they are offset by promptand substantialwage indexation. As a corollaryto real wage inflexibilityunder markup pricing, macro- economic models, includingour own, that incorporatethe hypothesis generallydepend for theirequilibrating properties on absolutevariations in the wage-pricelevel, operatingthrough the Phillipscurve and markup mechanisms. In the standard textbook IS-LM model, for example, restoration of long-term equilibriumafter a shock depends on price- inducedchanges in the real money supplyand interestrates.8 In some of the largereconometric models, real wealth argumentsin the aggregate demandfunctions are also involved.9 Market imperfectionsprovide a theoretical rationale for the fixed- price assumption.One theoreticalrationale is the perceived asymmetry of competitors'responses to a firm'spotential price increaseor decrease in oligopolistic industries as the source of price rigidity, as in Paul Sweezy's theory
Recommended publications
  • Introductory Discussions of Supply and Demand and of the Working of the Price Mechanism Normally Treat Quantities Demanded and S
    STRATHCLYDE DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS ‘ECONOMIC GEOMETRY’: MARSHALL’S AND OTHER EARLY REPRESENTATIONS OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY. BY ROY GRIEVE NO. 08-06 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF STRATHCLYDE GLASGOW ‘ECONOMIC GEOMETRY’: MARSHALL’S AND OTHER EARLY REPRESENTATIONS OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY ROY GRIEVE1 ABSTRACT Does an apparent (minor) anomaly, said to occur not infrequently in elementary expositions of supply and demand theory, really imply – as seems to be suggested – that there is something a bit odd about Marshall’s diagrammatic handling of demand and supply? On investigation, we find some interesting differences of focus and exposition amongst the theorists who first developed the ‘geometric’ treatment of demand and supply, but find no reason, despite his differences from other marginalist pioneers such as Cournot, Dupuit and Walras, to consider Marshall’s treatment either as unconventional or forced, or as to regard him as the ‘odd man out’. Introduction In the standard textbooks, introductory discussions of demand and supply normally treat quantities demanded and supplied as functions of price (rather than vice versa), and complement that discussion with diagrams in the standard format, showing price on the vertical axis and quantities demanded and supplied on the horizontal axis. No references need be cited. Usually this presentation is accepted without comment, but it can happen that a more numerate student observes that something of an anomaly appears to exist – in that the diagrams show price, which, 1 Roy’s thanks go to Darryl Holden who raised the question about Marshall's diagrams, and for his subsequent advice, and to Eric Rahim, as always, for valuable comment.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 24 Financial Accelerator
    Chapter 24 Financial Accelerator Starting in 2007, and becoming much more pronounced in 2008, macro-financial events took center stage in the macroeconomic landscape. The “financial collapse,” as many have termed it, had its proximate cause in the U.S., as several financial-sector institutions experienced severe or catastrophic downturns in the values of their financial assets. Various and large-scale policy efforts were implemented very quickly in the U.S. to try to contain possible consequences. The motivation behind these policy efforts was not to save the financial sector for its own sake. Instead, the rationale for policy responses was that severe financial downturns often lead to contraction in real macroeconomic markets (for example, think in terms of goods markets). Despite a raft of policy measures to try to prevent such effects, the severe financial disruption did cause a sharp contraction of economic activity in real markets: GDP declined by nearly four percent in the third quarter of 2008, the time period during which financial disruptions were at their most severe. This quarterly decline was the largest in the U.S. since the early 1980s, and GDP continued declining for the next three quarters. But the reason this pullback in GDP was especially worrisome was something history shows is common. When it is triggered by financial turbulence, a contraction in real economic activity can further exacerbate the financial downturn. This downstream effect was the real fear of policy makers. If this downstream effect occurred, the now- steeper financial downturn then could even further worsen the macro downturn, which in turn could even further worsen the financial downturn, which in turn could even further worsen the macro downturn, and ….
    [Show full text]
  • Keynesianism: Mainstream Economics Or Heterodox Economics?
    STUDIA EKONOMICZNE 1 ECONOMIC STUDIES NR 1 (LXXXIV) 2015 Izabela Bludnik* KEYNESIANISM: MAINSTREAM ECONOMICS OR HETERODOX ECONOMICS? INTRODUCTION The broad area of ​​research commonly referred to as “Keynesianism” was estab- lished by the book entitled The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money published in 1936 by John Maynard Keynes (Keynes, 1936; Polish ed. 2003). It was hailed as revolutionary as it undermined the vision of the functioning of the world and the conduct of economic policy, which at the time had been estab- lished for over 100 years, and thus permanently changed the face of modern economics. But Keynesianism never created a homogeneous set of views. Con- ventionally, the term is synonymous with supporting state interventions as ensur- ing a higher degree of resource utilization. However, this statement is too general for it to be meaningful. Moreover, it ignores the existence of a serious divide within the Keynesianism resulting from the adoption of two completely different perspectives concerning the world functioning. The purpose of this paper is to compare those two Keynesian perspectives in the context of the separate areas of mainstream and heterodox economics. Given the role traditionally assigned to each of these alternative approaches, one group of ideas known as Keynesian is widely regarded as a major field for the discussion of economic problems, whilst the second one – even referred to using the same term – is consistently ignored in the academic literature. In accordance with the assumed objectives, the first part of the article briefly characterizes the concept of neoclassical economics and mainstream economics. Part two is devoted to the “old” neoclassical synthesis of the 1950s and 1960s, New Keynesianism and the * Uniwersytet Ekonomiczny w Poznaniu, Katedra Makroekonomii i Badań nad Rozwojem ([email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • Calculating the Output Gap
    ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS Appendix 2 Calculating the output gap The output gap is an important concept in the preparation of inflation forecasts and assessments of the economic outlook. However, the output gap is difficult to measure and subject to great uncertainty in practice. The techniques used by the Central Bank of Iceland and elsewhere to calculate the output gap, which have previously been described in Monetary Bulletin (2000/4 pp. 14-15), will be recapitulated here taking particular account of investments in the aluminium and power sectors, since these have a substantial impact on both the level of production and output potential in the economy, not only during the construction phase but also when the investments 1 have been completed. 2005•1 MONETARY BULLETIN Definition of the output gap The output gap is defined as the difference between actual and potential GDP as a per cent of potential GDP, i.e.: (1) P where GAPt is the output gap, Yt is GDP in real terms and Y t is the potential output of the economy, all during the year t. Potential output is defined as the level of GDP that is consistent with full utilisation of all factors of production under conditions of stable inflation. Thus potential output is determined on the supply side of the economy, i.e. by capital stock, labour use and available technology. Potential output in the long term is determined by how effici- ently the available factors of production can be utilised for a given level of productivity. In the short run, however, aggregate demand can drive the level of production beyond long-term potential output.
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to Post-Keynesian Models of Distribution and Growth
    An Introduction to Post-Keynesian Theories of Distribution and Growth: Alternative Models and Empirical Findings Robert A. Blecker Professor of Economics, American University Washington, DC, USA, [email protected] Introductory Lecture, 22nd FMM/IMK Conference “10 Years After the Crash: What Have We Learned?” Berlin, Germany, 25 October, 2018 Shameless advertisement and important acknowledgement • Portions of this presentation are based on the book manuscript: Robert A. Blecker and Mark Setterfield, Heterodox Macroeconomics: Models of Demand, Distribution and Growth, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, Ltd., 2019, forthcoming. • I also present results from the dissertation of one of my doctoral students (used with permission): Michael Cauvel, Three Essays on the Empirical Estimation of Wage-led and Profit-led Demand Regimes, unpublished PhD dissertation, American University, Washington, DC, USA, July 2018. Distribution and growth: the big questions • Does a society have to endure worse inequality for its economy to grow and create jobs? • Or can growth and employment creation be consistent with greater distributive equity? • Historically, economists believed that distributional equity had to be sacrificed to achieve faster growth • Ricardo, Marx, Lewis-Ranis-Fei, Kaldor, etc.: faster growth generally requires a higher profit share or greater inequality • At least in the early stages of development (Kuznets curve) • Kuznets curve now largely debunked by Piketty • Recent empirical studies are finding that lower inequality is often
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Methods of Measuring the Economy, Efficiency and Effectiveness Of
    Methods Of Measuring The Economy, Efficiency And Effectiveness Of Public Expenditure ANNEX 7: August 2015 1 | P a g e TABLE OF CONTENTS 1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................................... 3 2 PER Context ........................................................................................................................................... 3 3 Necessity of the measures .................................................................................................................... 4 4 Measurement and coding ..................................................................................................................... 5 5 Assumptions .......................................................................................................................................... 5 6 Definitions and basic qualitative measures .......................................................................................... 6 6.1 Measuring Efficiency with DEA ..................................................................................................... 9 6.1.1 DEA ...................................................................................................................................... 10 6.1.2 Assumption of DEA ............................................................................................................. 10 6.2 Scale Efficiency Issues in DEA .....................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 753 Syllabus
    Economics 753: Applied Econometrics – Fall 2017 Monday/Wednesday 9:05–10:30 am & Lab Monday 10:30-11:30 Gordon Hall 303-304 Michael Ash, [email protected] 306 Crotty, Office hours: Tue 10-11:30; Wed 10:30-12 Robert Pollin, [email protected] 313 Gordon, 577-0819, Office Hours: Tue 2-4 or by appt. http://courses.umass.edu/econ753 http://courses.umass.edu/econ753/econ753.pdf COURSE SYLLABUS “There is no royal road to science, and only those who do not dread the fatiguing climb of its steep paths have a chance of gaining its luminous summits.”—Karl Marx The purpose of this course is to help you become comfortable and creative as empirical economic researchers. We will therefore introduce a series of econometric techniques and models by observing life in the trenches, i.e., working through how practitioners have approached econometric problems and built models as a vehicle for addressing substantive questions. We also put stress on communicating econometric results and descriptive statistics in ways that are illuminating, persuasive, and rigorous. But we will also ask the question: what does it mean to be rigorous with econometrics and with statistics in general? Indeed, early in the course, we will even address so basic a methodological question as that raised by John Maynard Keynes himself in the infancy of econometrics—whether the entire enterprise was worth pursuing. Finally, in the course of your studying and then doing real-world econometrics, we aim to get you to become comfortable, and perhaps even proficient, in least one major statistical software package and with manipulating data sets.
    [Show full text]
  • A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Gertler, Mark, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, and Andrea Prestipino
    K.7 A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Gertler, Mark, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, and Andrea Prestipino Please cite paper as: Gertler, Mark, Nobuhior Kiyotaki, and Andrea Prestipino (2017). A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics. International Finance Discussion Papers 1219. https://doi.org/10.17016/IFDP.2017.1219 International Finance Discussion Papers Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Number 1219 December 2017 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers Number 1219 December 2017 A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Andrea Prestipino NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at www.ssrn.com. A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton and Federal Reserve Board December, 2017 Abstract This paper incorporates banks and banking panics within a conven- tional macroeconomic framework to analyze the dynamics of a financial crisis of the kind recently experienced. We are particularly interested in characterizing the sudden and discrete nature of the banking panics as well as the circumstances that makes an economy vulnerable to such panics in some instances but not in others. Having a conventional macroeconomic model allows us to study the channels by which the crisis a¤ects real activity and the e¤ects of policies in containing crises.
    [Show full text]
  • Carbonomics Innovation, Deflation and Affordable De-Carbonization
    EQUITY RESEARCH | October 13, 2020 | 9:24PM BST Carbonomics Innovation, Deflation and Affordable De-carbonization Net zero is becoming more affordable as technological and financial innovation, supported by policy, are flattening the de-carbonization cost curve. We update our 2019 Carbonomics cost curve to reflect innovation across c.100 different technologies to de- carbonize power, mobility, buildings, agriculture and industry, and draw three key conclusions: 1) low-cost de-carbonization technologies (mostly renewable power) continue to improve consistently through scale, reducing the lower half of the cost curve by 20% on average vs. our 2019 cost curve; 2) clean hydrogen emerges as the breakthrough technology in the upper half of the cost curve, lowering the cost of de-carbonizing emissions in more difficult sectors (industry, heating, heavy transport) by 30% and increasing the proportion of abatable emissions from 75% to 85% of total emissions; and 3) financial innovation and a lower cost of capital for low-carbon activities have driven around one-third of renewables cost deflation since 2010, highlighting the importance of shareholder engagement in climate change, monetary stimulus and stable regulatory frameworks. The result of these developments is very encouraging, shaving US$1 tn pa from the cost of the path towards net zero and creating a broader connected ecosystem for de- carbonization that includes renewables, clean hydrogen (both blue and green), batteries and carbon capture. Michele Della Vigna, CFA Zoe Stavrinou Alberto Gandolfi +44 20 7552-9383 +44 20 7051-2816 +44 20 7552-2539 [email protected] [email protected] alberto.gandolfi@gs.com Goldman Sachs International Goldman Sachs International Goldman Sachs International Goldman Sachs does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research reports.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 9 Gross Fixed Capital Formation
    Gross fixed capital formation Chapter 9 Gross fixed capital formation Introduction 9.1 In the Income and Expenditure Accounts (IEA), gross fixed capital formation is divided into three principal types of investment expenditure: • residential structures; • non-residential structures; and • machinery and equipment. 9.2 Estimates of each type of investment are produced for the business1 and government sectors in the IEA. The discussion in this chapter is structured around these three major categories of gross fixed capital formation. 9.3 Fixed investment expenditure is a significant part of aggregate demand. This activity is tied to economic growth through its impact on the productive stock of capital, to social welfare in relation to government infrastructure, and to business cycles in terms of the volatility of its components. Concepts and definitions 9.4 Defining capital and capital expenditure is increasingly challenging, given the changing nature of production. Recently, the investment boundary has shifted, resulting in the re-classification of certain types of current expenditure to capital expenditure (e.g., software). In the simplest terms, any expenditure that gives rise to an asset could be considered investment; or, spending on an item whose expected life equals or exceeds one year could be considered investment. However, investment spending must be linked to future use in production.2 9.5 Fixed capital covers tangible or intangible assets which are produced as outputs from production processes and which are themselves used repeatedly or continuously in other production processes for more than one year. Fixed assets exclude, by definition, certain non-produced intangible assets, such as non-cultivated biological resources (e.g., virgin forests).3 9.6 Generally speaking, capital formation refers to additions to the stock of the nation’s non-financial assets resulting from investment activities.
    [Show full text]
  • The Macroeconomic Model
    Briefing paper No. 5 The macroeconomic model October 2013 © Crown copyright 2013 You may re-use this information (excluding logos) free of charge in any format or medium, under the terms of the Open Government Licence. To view this licence, visit http://www.nationalarchives.gov.uk/doc/open- government-licence/ or write to the Information Policy Team, The National Archives, Kew, London TW9 4DU, or e-mail: [email protected]. Any queries regarding this publication should be sent to us at: [email protected] ISBN 978-1-909790-28-5 PU1558 Contents Chapter 1 Introduction.................................................................................. 1 Chapter 2 Expenditure components of GDP ................................................... 9 Chapter 3 The labour market ...................................................................... 63 Chapter 4 Prices, costs and earnings ........................................................... 71 Chapter 5 Balance sheets and income accounts ........................................... 95 Chapter 6 Public sector ............................................................................. 145 Chapter 7 Domestic financial sector........................................................... 183 Chapter 8 North Sea................................................................................. 187 Annex A Glossary of Winsolve notations.................................................. 193 Annex B Winsolve model code...............................................................
    [Show full text]