Alfred Weber's Theory of the Location of Industries the University of Chicago Press Chicago, Illinois

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Alfred Weber's Theory of the Location of Industries the University of Chicago Press Chicago, Illinois IHtbrarg MATERIALS FOR THE STUDY OF BUSINESS ALFRED WEBER'S THEORY OF THE LOCATION OF INDUSTRIES THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO PRESS CHICAGO, ILLINOIS THE BAKER & TAYLOR COMPANY NEW YORK THE MACMILLAN COMPANY OF CANADA, LIMITED TORONTO THE CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS LONDON THE MARUZEN-KABUSHIKI-KAISHA TOKYO, OSAK.\, KYOTO, FUKUOKA, SENDAI THE COMMERCIAL PRESS, LIMITED SHANGHAI ENGLISH EDITION, WITH INTRODUCTION AND NOTES BY CARL JOACHIM FRIEDRICH, Ph.D. ASSISTANT PROFESSOR AT HARVARD UNIVERSITY ALFRED WEBER'S THEORY OF THE LOCATION OF INDUSTRIES THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO PRESS CHICAGO • ILLINOIS T COPYRIGHT 1929 BY THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. PUBLISHED JULY 19iJ9 COMPOSED AND PRINTED BY THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO PRESS CHICAGO, ILLINOIS, U.S.A. PREFACE In presenting this book to the public I am spared an embar- rassment that many writers encounter ; I do not need to give an apology for the topic with which it deals. Alfred Weber's treat- ise is a pioneering venture. He attempts to master by theoreti- cal analysis a complete wilderness of facts which has grown up around us during the last two centuries concerning the location of our modern manufacturing industries. To be sure, others have ventured upon the task of describing and classifying the phenomena of geographical distribution; but, as Weber points out, previous writers did not get beyond a mere enumeration of various factors which played a part in determining the location of industries. While I am quite impressed with the importance of Weber's work itself, if clearly understood, it is precisely this task of mak- ing it understood about which I feel very apologetic. In spite of the help and advice which Professors Leon C. Marshall and Frank W. Taussig, as well as Drs. E. H. Chamberlin, William Y. Elliot, Edward Mason, Talcott Parsons, and Andreas Pre- döhl have so generously afforded me, I do not feel confident that I have succeeded in conquering the difficulties which con- front the translator of such a highly abstract treatise. Had not Professor Marshall and Dr. Mason read the entire manuscript through and made numerous suggestions for its improvement, I fear I should not have found the courage to let it see the light of day. It will be conceded by those who have embarked on the hazardous adventure of translating abstract thought from one language into another that nothing is more perplexing. It is in such thought that the Sprachgeist develops its subtlest distinc- tions, successfully defying either translating, transcribing, or vii viii PREFACE paraphrasing. For this reason the paging of the German edition of Weber's book has been inserted as marginal notes through- out. These notes are usually inserted at the end of a sentence, even though that sentence overlaps the page in the original. The interested reader will consult the German text wherever the English translation becomes too obscure. Had space per- mitted, I should have included the German text itself. But, after all, the greatest usefulness of such a translation is the as- sistance it may give to the student who knows the original lan- guage, but does not know it sufficiently well to enable him to make the entire translation himself. Comparison with the German text will show that Weber's preface to the first and second (unaltered) edition, as well as his two notes (Exkurse) have been omitted. We should have been glad to include Weber's contribution to the Grundriss der So- zialökonomik^ could it have been arranged. I can only refer to this treatise all readers who are particularly interested in those aspects of location which Weber touches upon in his introduc- tion and in his last chapter as well as in the paragraphs through- out the book on tendencies of development. It seemed impor- tant to include the mathematical appendix by Georg Pick. I sin- cerely hope that the indulgent reader will not feel as did that stu- dent who wrote on top of Alfred Marshall's mathematical ap- pendix to his Principles: ''A bad case of appendicitis—cut it out." In translating this mathematical appendix I have had the valuable advice of Mr. Paul S. Bauer. This study would probably not have been possible without the constant encouragement of Professor Leon C. Marshall. I wish to thank him and all others who have helped me. C. J. F. ^"Industrielle Standortslehre (Reine und kapitalistische Theorie des Stand- orts)," in Grundriss, Abteilung VI, B, particularly the second part dealing with capitalistic theory. TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE Editor's Introduction: The Theory of Location in Relation to THE Theory of Land Rent xiii 1. In John Stuart Mill xiii " 2. In Alfred Marshall . xv 3. In J. H. von Thiinen xix 4. In Alfred Weber xxii 5. Significance for a Theory of Monopoly, Transportation Rates, and International Trade . xxix Author's Introduction i 1. Importance of an Economic Theory of Location .... i 2. Limitation to a Theory of the Location of Manufacturing Industry; Reasons Therefor 4 3. Method Employed 8 4. Limitations of the Results 12 Chapter I. LocATioNAL Factors and LocATiONAL Dynamics 17 I. The Terms "Locational Factor" and "Locational Unit" . 17 IL Classification of Locational Factors 20 a) General and Special 20 b) Regional and Agglomerative 20 c) Natural and Technical, Social and Cultural .... 21 III. Ascertaining the General Factors of Location .... 23 a) Ascertaining the Individual Regional Factors ... 23 b) Costs of Transportation and Labor Costs Are the Only Regional Factors 29 IV. Theory of the Locational Factors 34 Chapter II. Simplifying Assumptions 37 I. The Assumption of a Separate Basis of Material Supply, Con- sumption, and Labor . 37 II. The Consideration of the "Forces of Nature" 39 Chapter I^I. Transport Orientation (Transportorientierung) Section I. Analysis of Transportation Costs 41 I. Weight and Distance the Only Elements of Cost in Our Theoretical Analysis 41 ix X TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE 2. The Type of the Transportation Sj^stem and the Extent of Its Use 43 3. The Nature of the Locality and Its Kinds of Roads . 45 4. The Nature of the Goods 45 5. Relation to Reality 46 Section IL The Laws of Transport Orientation 48 1. The Locational Figures and the Kinds of Industrial Materials 48 2. Mathematical Solution 53 3. Material Index, Locational Weight, and Theoretical Conclusion 59 4. Cases 61 5. The Orientation of an Entire Industry 67 a) The Creation of the Individual Figures .... 67 b) Co-operation of the Individual Figures .... 70 6. The Factors of Transport Orientation 72 7. Tendencies of Development 73 Section III. Approximations to Reality 76 1. The Existing System of Transportation Rates ... 76 A. Deviations from the Pure Calculation of Rates According to Mileage 77 A. Deviation from the Pure Calculation of Rates Accord- ing to Weight 78 2. The Real Nature of the Transportation System ... 81 A. A Divided System of Transportation 81 B. Different Kinds of Transportation Systems Working Together 82 a) The Effect of the Waterways 84 b) The Effect of the Net of Highways 86 3. Further Applications of the Theory to Reality ... 88 A. The Price Differences of Materials and Their Effect . 88 B. The Use of Water Power . 89 a) The Use of Waterfalls 89 b) Transmissible Water Power 91 Chapter IV. Labor Orientation 95 Section L The Analysis of Labor Costs 95 1. The Geographical Differences in Labor Costs 95 2. Their "Forms of Occurrence"; Differences Accordini7 to Area 97 3. Simplifying Assumptions 100 TABLE OF CONTENTS xi PAGE Section II. The Law of Labor Orientation 102 1. Theoretical Solution; Isodapanes 102 2. The Conditions of Labor Orientation 105 3. The Character of the Industries and Labor Orientation 107 A. Orientation of an Individual Plant: Index of Labor Costs and Coefficient of Labor 107 B. Orientation of an Entire Industry: Elimination of Labor Locations and Replacement of Deposits . 112 4. The Environmental Conditions of the Labor Orientation 117 5. Tendencies of Development 120 Chapter V. Agglomeration 124 Section I. Analysis of Agglomerative and Deglomerative Factors 1. Object of the Analysis 124 2. Definitions: Function of Economy and Function of Agglomeration 126 3. Agglomerative and Deglomerative Factors . 127 A. Agglomerative Factors 127 a) Development of the Technical Equipment . 128 b) Development of the Labor Organization 129 c) Marketing Factors 130 d) General Overhead Costs 130 B. Deglomerative Factors 131 Section IL The Laws of Agglomeration 134 A. Agglomeration within Transport Orientation 135 1. Agglomeration with Fixed Index 135 a) When Does Agglomeration Take Place, and How Much? 135 b) Where Will Agglomeration Take Place? .... 138 c) The Size of the Unit of Agglomeration 139 d) Modifications 141 2. Agglomeration in the Case of an Increasing Index . 143 3. The Conditions of Agglomeration 147 4. The Formula of Agglomeration 153 B. Agglomeration and Labor Orientation 156 Section HI. Reintroducing the Realities 162 1. Coefficient of (Value Added through) Manufacture (Formkoeffizient) 162 2. The Forms of Agglomeration in Reality 166 3. Tendencies of Development 168 xii TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE Chapter VI. The Total Orientation 173 Section I. The Organization of the Stages of a Given Productive Process 174 A. The Stages of Production and Transport Orientation 174 1. When Does a Split Occur in the Production? . 174 2. Where Will the Locations of the Productive Stages Be When Production Is Split? 178 3. A More Precise Answer to the Question: When Does a Split in the Production Occur? 182 4. Complications (Replacement of Material Deposits) . 183 B. The Stages of Production and Labor Orientation . 184 C. The Stages of Production and Agglomeration .... 186 D. Reintroducing the Realities 187 1. General Observations 187 2. Tendencies of Actual Development 190 Section II. The Interaction of the Independent Productive Processes 196 1.
Recommended publications
  • The Future of the Cluster Concept
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Koschatzky, Knut Working Paper Cluster quo vadis? The future of the cluster concept Arbeitspapiere Unternehmen und Region, No. R1/2012 Provided in Cooperation with: Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research ISI Suggested Citation: Koschatzky, Knut (2012) : Cluster quo vadis? The future of the cluster concept, Arbeitspapiere Unternehmen und Region, No. R1/2012, Fraunhofer-Institut für System- und Innovationsforschung ISI, Karlsruhe This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/55860 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence
    [Show full text]
  • A New Look at Max Weber and His Anglo-German Family Connections1
    P1: JLS International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society [ijps] PH231-474840-07 October 28, 2003 17:46 Style file version Nov. 19th, 1999 International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society, Vol. 17, No. 2, Winter 2003 (C 2003) II. Review Essay How Well Do We Know Max Weber After All? A New Look at Max Weber and His Anglo-German Family Connections1 Lutz Kaelber2 Guenther Roth’s study places Max Weber in an intricate network of ties among members of his lineage. This paper presents core findings of Roth’s analysis of Weber’s family relations, discusses the validity of Roth’s core theses and some of the implications of his analysis for Weber as a person and scholar, and addresses how Roth’s book may influence future approaches to Weber’s sociology. KEY WORDS: Max Weber; history of sociology; classical sociology; German history; Guenther Roth. “How well do we know Max Weber?”—When the late Friedrich H. Tenbruck (1975) raised this question almost thirty years ago, he had Weber’s scholarship in mind. The analysis of Weber’s oeuvre and the debate over it, fueled by a steady trickle of contributions of the Max Weber Gesamtaus- gabe, has not abated since. Thanks to the Gesamtausgabe’s superbly edited volumes, we now know more about Weber the scholar than ever before, even though the edition’s combination of exorbitant pricing and limitation to German-language editions has slowed its international reception. Tenbruck’s question might be applied to Weber’s biography as well. Here, too, the Gesamtausgabe, particularly with the edition of his personal letters, has been a valuable tool for research.1 Yet the fact remains that what we know about Weber the person derives to a significant extent from 1Review essay of Guenther Roth, Max Webers deutsch-englische Familiengeschichte, 1800–1950.
    [Show full text]
  • Max Weber and Franz Kafka
    Law, Culture and the Humanities http://lch.sagepub.com/ Max Weber and Franz Kafka: A Shared Vision of Modern Law Douglas Litowitz Law, Culture and the Humanities 2011 7: 48 originally published online 7 July 2010 DOI: 10.1177/1743872109355552 The online version of this article can be found at: http://lch.sagepub.com/content/7/1/48 Published by: http://www.sagepublications.com On behalf of: Association for the Study of Law, Culture and the Humanities Additional services and information for Law, Culture and the Humanities can be found at: Email Alerts: http://lch.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Subscriptions: http://lch.sagepub.com/subscriptions Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Downloaded from lch.sagepub.com at Chelyabinsk State University on January 11, 2011 LAW, CULTURE AND THE HUMANITIES Article Law, Culture and the Humanities 7(1) 48–65 Max Weber and Franz Kafka: © The Author(s) 2011 Reprints and permission: sagepub. A Shared Vision of Modern Law co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1743872109355552 http://lch.sagepub.com Douglas Litowitz Magnetar Capital LLC Abstract Recent scholarship suggests a line of influence from the sociologist Max Weber to the writer Franz Kafka, mediated through the lesser-known figure of Alfred Weber, who was Max’s younger brother and a law professor who served as one of Kafka’s law school examiners. This paper finds textual support for this claim of influence. Indeed, there is an uncanny similarity between Weber’s and Kafka’s writings on law, particularly in their diagnosis of a legitimation crisis at the heart of modern law, and in their suspicion that modern law cannot deliver on its promises.
    [Show full text]
  • Max Weber's Protestant Ethic in the 21St Century
    P1: Vendor/FZN International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society [ijps] ph137-ijps-376822 July 8, 2002 15:39 Style file version Nov. 19th, 1999 International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society, Vol. 16, No. 1, Fall 2002 (C 2002) II. The Protestant Ethic: On New Translations Max Weber’s Protestant Ethic in the 21st Century Lutz Kaelber† The history of sociology’s most famous study began with the publication of a two-part essay. Its author, educated as a lawyer but formerly employed as a national economist, had no formal training in its subject. He had just overcome a mood disorder that had debilitated him and all but finished his promising academic career, allowing his wife to become better known in some academic and social circles than he was. The essay’s arguments were quickly challenged by historians, whose critiques the author rebuffed in an acerbic and cantankerous fashion. Within weeks and months after publishing the study, its author moved on to conduct other monumental studies and did not return to the original study’s subject matter until close to the end of his life, when the essays were thoroughly revised and made part of a much larger project comparing the interface of religion and economics in the major religions. Since the author’s death, there have been studies addressing the genesis of the original essays, the significance of the changes made in their revision, the original and revised essays’ status in the larger context of the author’s work, their extension both stepping back and moving forward in time, and, last but not least, their shortcomings and aberrations, real and imagined.1 The work itself has been translated into numerous languages.
    [Show full text]
  • Alfred Weber, Theory of the Location of Industries, 1909
    UC Santa Barbara CSISS Classics Title Alfred Weber, Theory of the Location of Industries, 1909. CSISS Classics Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/1k3927t6 Author Fearon, David Publication Date 2002 eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California CSISS Classics - Alfred Weber: Theory of the Location of Industries, 1909 Alfred Weber: Theory of the Location of Industries, 1909 By David Fearon Background Alfred Weber (1868–1958), like his older brother Max Weber, started his academic career in Germany as an economist, then became a sociologist. While schooled at a time when European economics was emphasizing historical analysis, Weber was among those reintroducing theory and causal models to the field. He is best remembered, particularly in economics, regional science and operations research, for early models of industrial location (discussed below). When his work turned to sociology, however, Weber maintained a commitment to the "philosophy of history" traditions, developing theories for analyzing social change in Western civilization as a confluence of civilization (intellectual and technological), social processes (organizations) and culture (art, religion, and philosophy). He also published empirical and historical analyses of the growth and geographical distribution of cities and capitalism. Weber remained in Nazi Germany during the war, but was a leader in intellectual resistance. After the war his writings and teaching was influential both in and out of academic circles in promoting a philosophical and political recovery for the German people. Innovation With the publication of Über den Standort der Industrie (Theory of the Location of Industries) in 1909, Alfred Weber put forth the first developed general theory of industrial location [references here are to the 1929 translation of the 1909 book by Carl Friedrich].
    [Show full text]
  • The Secular Prophet of Religious Socialism the Erich Fromm’S Early Writings (1922-1930)
    The secular prophet of religious socialism The Erich Fromm’s early writings (1922-1930) Michael Löwy* https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5679-0927 Dialectics of the secular and the sacred There exists a German-Jewish cultural discourse from the early 20th century that stands in dynamic tension between spiritual and material, sacred and secular, beyond the usual static dichotomies. Several key Jewish thinkers have sought to recover spiritual meaning, in direct interaction with the profane. Under different ways they developed a process of simultaneous secularization and sacralization, in a sort of “dialectic” combination of both. Among some examples: Franz Kafka, Walter Benjamin, Ernst Bloch, Erich Fromm, Gustav Landauer, Martin Buber, Gershom Scholem, Leo Löwenthal, Hans Kohn, Manes Sperber and others. This applies particularly to their early writings (until 1933) although in some cases it holds true during their entire life. The first common characteristic of these authors is their deep attachment to the German romantic culture, with its ambivalence towards modernity, and its desperate attempt at re-enchanting the world through a return to past spiritual forms. For the Jewish thinkers, this meant a rediscovery of the spiritual treasures of the less rational and less codified forms of Jewish religiosity, the “romantic” religious traditions of the past: the Prophets, Messianism, Mysticism, Kabballah, Sabbataism, Hassidism. * Centre National de Recherche Scientifique, Paris, França. The secular prophet of religious socialism, pp. 21-31 However, being modern subjects, they cannot return to the faith of their ancestors: their spirituality is intimately intertwined with secular aspirations. These aspirations lead them – and this is another common aspect of their writings – to support radical social/political utopias, such as socialism, communism or anarchism, which are in a relation of elective affinity with the Jewish Messianic heritage.
    [Show full text]
  • Landscapes of Unrest: Herbert Giersch and the Origins of Neoliberal Economic Geography
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter; Slobodian, Quinn Article — Published Version Landscapes of unrest: Herbert Giersch and the origins of neoliberal economic geography Modern Intellectual History Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter; Slobodian, Quinn (2019) : Landscapes of unrest: Herbert Giersch and the origins of neoliberal economic geography, Modern Intellectual History, ISSN 1479-2451, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Vol. 16, Iss. 1, pp. 185-215, http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1479244317000324 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/181676 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available
    [Show full text]
  • Max Weber's View of Religion in China
    chapter 6 Max Weber’s View of Religion in China Max Weber is known for his studies on Daoism and Confucianism. But his famous journal article on the Protestant Ethic (Weber 1950), originally pub- lished in 1904, has had more impact on the development of the sociology of religion. It served as the point of departure and the background for his later research on the religions of Asia. As Weber clarifies in comments he wrote on his own work, his ideal-typical1 construction of the Protestant Ethic is designed to explain how a specific type of rational modern capitalism came about as a novel type of economic activity. Once rational capitalism exists as a way of doing business and of making mon- ey, it can be carried on rationally through history without remaining attached to its religious origins, or – for that matter – to any religion or other specific value orientation. In other words, the Protestant Ethic was needed – according to Weber – to start a particular type of capitalism, not to continue its existence. In addition, it was needed to replace universalism and instead establish ethical exclusivity on a religious basis. When we followed Fei Xiaotong in his interpretation of the reckless behav- iour of throwing garbage into the canals of Suzhou, the quick disposal hap- pened in the – presumed – interest of the family and against the general public. Such behaviour needed the ethical principle of exclusivity as justification. Pre-reformation Christian churches in the West as well as Mozi in ancient China (see here the Introduction!), emphasized the brotherhood of human- kind (universalism).
    [Show full text]
  • Being Max Weber
    review Joachim Radkau, Max Weber: die Leidenschaft des Denkens Carl Hanser Verlag: Munich 2005, €45, hardback 1007 pp, 3 446 20675 2 Peter Thomas BEING MAX WEBER Hearing of Weber’s death in 1920, many in the German academic com- munity might have thought the news referred to Alfred Weber, Professor of Economics at the University of Heidelberg. While his elder brother Max had recently made a forceful return to public affairs, he was still known princi- pally as the fin de siècle advocate of a muscular national imperialism and the author of some significant, albeit occasional, articles in specialist journals. Although he had tentatively resumed teaching and a more overt political role—having resigned his own post at Heidelberg in 1903, due to a deep depressive illness—Max Weber’s scholarly reputation remained limited at the time of his death to a relatively narrow intellectual circle in Mitteleuropa. Thereafter, the elder brother reclaimed his birthright; only a few years later, Alfred could complain that his own students were more interested in ‘Marx and Max’ than in himself. In the first instance, this was largely due to the efforts of wife Marianne, who not only tirelessly promoted Weber’s work, but also in a very real sense ‘authored’ the Max Weber we know today. At the time of his death, Weber’s only book publications were the two texts neces- sary for an academic career, while the main body of his work—the vast mass of Economy and Society; The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism— either languished in manuscript or had appeared in specialist journals.
    [Show full text]
  • The Near-Death of Liberal Capitalism: Perceptions from the Weber to the Polanyi Brothers
    10.1177/0032329203252271POLITICSGUENTHERARTICLE & ROTHSOCIETY The Near-Death of Liberal Capitalism: Perceptions from the Weber to the Polanyi Brothers GUENTHER ROTH Karl Polanyi and Max Weber held radically different views of liberal capitalism, but they also came to differ in significant respects with their brothers Michael Polanyi and Alfred Weber. The first section provides an overview of some critical moments in the history of liberal capitalism as perceived by some historical witnesses. The second treats the views of the Weber brothers on the world economy before 1914. The third deals with Max Weber’s overlooked treatment of G. F.Knapp’s once famous state the- ory of money. The fourth (re)turns to the circle of cosmopolitan Austro-Hungarian intellectuals who passionately debated the future of liberal capitalism and almost all of whom became political refugees. Keywords: Karl Polanyi; Max Weber; liberal capitalism; Austro-Hungarian intellectuals; state theory of money I would like to treat some historical moments of the near-death and “miracu- lous” resurrection of liberal capitalism as a particularly fateful lesson in historical contingency. By liberal capitalism (or economic liberalism) I mean first of all multilateral world trade by private enterprise and the currency and credit arrange- ments required by it. Today we often speak of globalization instead of liberal capi- talism and project that term backward. Thus, Harold James’s recent book The End of Globalization turns out to provide, as the subtitle reveals to the unwary reader, Lessons from the Great Depression.1 The first globalization saw the rise, in the nineteenth century, of a liberal world economy, which was characterized by the relatively free movement of persons, capital, goods, and information in an arena POLITICS & SOCIETY, Vol.
    [Show full text]
  • EUI Working Papers MWP 2008/35
    1 EUI Working Papers MWP 2008/35 Max Weber in the 21st Century: Transdisciplinarity within the Social Sciences Frank Adloff and Manuel Borutta (Editors) EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE MAX WEBER PROGRAMME Max Weber in the 21st Century: Transdisciplinarity within the Social Sciences FRANK ADLOFF and MANUEL BORUTTA (Editors) EUI Working Paper MWP No. 2008/35 This text may be downloaded for personal research purposes only. Any additional reproduction for other purposes, whether in hard copy or electronically, requires the consent of the author(s), editor(s). If cited or quoted, reference should be made to the full name of the author(s), editor(s), the title, the working paper or other series, the year, and the publisher. The author(s)/editor(s) should inform the Max Weber Programme of the EUI if the paper is to be published elsewhere, and should also assume responsibility for any consequent obligation(s). ISSN 1830-7728 © 2008 Frank Adloff and Manuel Borutta (selection and editorial matter); individual sections contributors Printed in Italy European University Institute Badia Fiesolana I – 50014 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) Italy http://www.eui.eu/ http://cadmus.eui.eu/ Table of Contents Foreword Ramon Marimon I. Max Weber in the 21st Century or: how is Transdisciplinarity within the Social Sciences Possible Today?.......................................................................................................01 by Frank Adloff and Manuel Borutta II. Max Weber between ‘Eruptive Creativity’ and ‘Disciplined Transdisciplinarity’…………………………………………………13 by Joachim Radkau III. Weber’s Foundations of the Social Sciences and Rational Choice Theory………………………………………………….......…..31 by Sandro Segre IV. Weber, Marx and Contemporary Economic Theory: a Secular Theory of the Spirit of Capitalism………………………………......43 by Fabrizio Zilibotti V.
    [Show full text]
  • Inventing the Axial Age: the Origins and Uses of a Historical Concept
    Theor Soc DOI 10.1007/s11186-013-9193-0 Inventing the axial age: the origins and uses of a historical concept John D. Boy & John Torpey # Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2013 Abstract The concept of the axial age, initially proposed by the philosopher Karl Jaspers to refer to a period in the first millennium BCE that saw the rise of major religious and philosophical figures and ideas throughout Eurasia, has gained an established position in a number of fields, including historical sociology, cultural sociology, and the sociology of religion. We explore whether the notion of an “axial age” has historical and intellectual cogency, or whether the authors who use the label of a more free-floating “axiality” to connote varied “breakthroughs” in human experience may have a more compelling case. Throughout, we draw attention to ways in which uses of the axial age concept in contemporary social science vary in these and other respects. In the conclusion, we reflect on the value of the concept and its current uses and their utility in making sense of human experience. Keywords History of social thought . Civilizations . Axial Age . Axiality. Religion . Historical sociology . Cultural sociology Until recently, it was widely said that we live in a time that has exhausted all “grand narratives.” Yet recently some of the biggest names in contemporary scholarship have taken up studies of the very longue durée, and of world history as a whole, in efforts to grasp central aspects of human experience. For example, the sociologist Robert Bellah, the anthropologist David Graeber, the ancient historian Ian Morris, and the psychologist Stephen Pinker have published massive studies going back millennia in time to make sense of our proclivity for religion, the origin of basic categories of economic life, relations of world domination and subordination, and our (putatively declining) propensity toward violence, respectively.
    [Show full text]