The Future of Financial Regulation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Future of Financial Regulation The Future of Financial Regulation Howard Davies The last quarter of 2007 was a very good time not to be a financial regula- tor. And I suspect that the first quarter of 2008 will not be much easier. The turmoil in global financial markets, which as recently as last July was a cloud no bigger than a man’s hand, has spread from the wilder shores of the subprime mortgage business in trailer parks in central Florida, to the heart of the London interbank market. It is not surprising that US mortgage lenders, and the investment banks who securitised their loans and traded them extensively, have run into problems. But so have German and Geordie banks. What began as a house price correction transmuted into a general widening of spreads on risky assets, then a liquidity squeeze and now looks well on the way to becom- ing a full scale credit crunch. Martin Wolf, Chief Economics Commentator of the Financial Times, has talked of a “revulsion” in capital markets, as investors in all types of asset-backed securities have rushed to the exit. In the central banks it has been all hands to the pump to supply liquid- ity which the markets themselves are unwilling to provide. They came to the task with varying degrees of enthusiasm. Yet in spite of this massive assistance the crisis seems far from over, and looks highly likely to have a significant impact on the real economy, certainly in the United States, and probably in Europe as well. As a result, politicians and others have raised serious questions about the adequacy of market regulation. Could the crisis not have been pre- vented? Were the regulators asleep at the wheel?—a common cliché which is proudly trotted out by politicians at these times, as if freshly minted. Sir Howard Davies is Director of the London School of Economics and Political Science. The article is an edited version of the speech he gave at Oxford University on January 15, 2008 at a seminar organised by OXONIA, The Oxford Institute for Economic Policy. WORLD ECONOMICS • Vol. 9 • No. 1 • January–March 2008 11 Howard Davies In the regulatory bodies themselves, the loudest sound is that of stable doors being slammed shut. But there are also countless reviews under way, both domestically and internationally, to try to understand what went wrong and what might be done to strengthen our defences in the future. In this article I shall try to parse some of the so far rather inchoate criti- cisms of the performance of the regulatory system and to give a prelimi- nary assessment of where there is a case for a change. But first let me provide one simple conclusion from my new book with David Green, who was head of international affairs at the UK’s Financial Services Authority (FSA).1 The global regulatory system is rather complex. Figure 1 shows the heavily simplified version. It has grown up like topsy and committees have proliferated extravagantly. New committees rarely die. That is espe- cially true in the European Union, where it is given to few to understand how things are supposed to work (Figure 2). There is a powerful case for simplification. (How this might be done is described in the book.) Figure 1: Global committee structure—a regulator’s view G-7 (Governments) IMF World Bank OECD (Governments) WTO (Governments) FATF (money laundering) IASB IASC Financial Stability Forum IAASB Monitoring Bank for (Audit) PIOB International Group Settlements (Central banks) G-10 Basel IOSCO IAIS IFIAR (Central banks) (Banking) (Securities) (Insurance) (Audit) CGFS CPSS Joint Forum Source: Adapted with permission from Sloan and Fitzpatrick in Chapter 13, The Structure of International Market Regulation, in Financial Markets and Exchanges Law, Oxford University Press, March 2007 1 Global Financial Regulation: The Essential Guide. Howard Davies and David Green. Polity Press, March 2008. 12 WORLD ECONOMICS • Vol. 9 • No. 1 • January–March 2008 W ORLD Figure 2: European committee structure E Council of Ministers (ECOFIN) FSC EFC European Parliament CONOMICS Financial Services Economic and Committee Financial Committee European Commission Council CoRePer Working Groups Ambassadors (legislative) • Vol. 9•No.1January–March 2008 • Vol. (legislative) Government level ESC ARC EIOPC EBC EFCC AURC (Finance Ministries European Accounting European Insurance European European Financial Audit and observers from Securities Regulatory and Occupational Banking Conglomerates Regulatory regulatory level) Committee Committee Pensions Committee Committee Committee Committee The FutureofFinancial Regulation Regulatory level CESR CEIOPS CEBS IWCFC EGAOB (Competent authorities) Committee of Committee of European Committee of Interim Working European Group European Securities Insurance and Occupational European Banking Committee on of Audit Supervisors Pension Supervisors Supervisors Financial Oversight Bodies Conglomerates 3L3 Committee Central Bank level Banking Supervision Outside Commission ECB Committee framework Committee of the ECB 13 Source: Adapted with permission from a chart originally devised by John Sloan Howard Davies A health warning Before I begin parsing, I should enter a health warning. It is always dan- gerous to devise regulatory policy in the midst of a crisis. As I have argued elsewhere, financial regulation in the UK, and indeed elsewhere, can best be explained as a series of Dangerous Dog Acts. Legislation is often con- ceived in haste in response to a particular example of excess. In the United States, the Sarbanes–Oxley Act is clearly in this category.2 It may well have some merits, but almost all observers would acknowledge its inflexibility and unintended consequences. It was certainly legislated in haste and American markets have now been repenting for a while. So it is quite important not to be seduced into new regulations and controls by market panic, controls which might in the long run be very costly and deliver insufficient benefits. But even with that health warning in mind, we must acknowledge that the last six months have raised some interesting and difficult questions for central banks and regulators, whether unified or separated. I identify seven, as follows: Question 1 is about the causes of the crisis. Did the Federal Reserve itself inflate the bubble by pushing interest rates down too far in the after- math of the collapse of the dot com boom and 9/11? Were other central banks accessories after the fact? Question 2 is, in some ways, more fundamental. Does this crisis show that liberalisation in financial markets has gone too far, and that there are fundamental flaws in what people, especially the French, call the Anglo- Saxon model? Question 3 relates to the origin of the crisis last summer in the US sub- prime mortgage market. Is there a fatal flaw in that market, which was pos- itively encouraged by the Ancien Régime in the Fed on the essentially political grounds that home ownership was thereby expanded? Question 4 relates to the Credit Ratings Agencies. Did they fall down on the job, and was their failure attributable to fundamental conflicts of interest in their business model which need to be corrected? 2 The Sarbanes–Oxley Act was passed in July 2002 and was a direct reaction by the US Congress to address the accounting scandals of 2001 and early 2002 including the Enron debacle. The Act’s stated purpose is “to protect investors by improving the accuracy and reliability of corporate disclosures made pursuant to the securities laws, and for other purposes”. 14 WORLD ECONOMICS • Vol. 9 • No. 1 • January–March 2008 The Future of Financial Regulation Question 5 relates to liquidity. Can we be happy that central banks have had to inject liquidity on such a massive scale? Do bank regulators need an entirely different approach to liquidity? Question 6 relates specifically to the UK: Does the Northern Rock problem demonstrate a fundamental flaw in the UK arrangements, whether in the Tripartite system itself or in the separation of banking supervision from the Bank of England? Question 7 relates to global financial regulation, the subject matter of my book with David Green. Does the response to the crisis show that there are gaps in the global regulatory system which need to be filled? Is there a leadership problem within the complex network I illustrated in Figure 1? I shall attempt to answer these seven questions in the remainder of this article. Q1. Did the Fed cause the problem? This is the one of my seven questions on which I am proposing to enter an open verdict. My excuse is that it is essentially a macroeconomic ques- tion, rather than an issue of financial regulation. It was almost universally acknowledged that the markets were awash with liquidity and that real interest rates were very low, indeed often neg- ative. So credit expanded extravagantly. Were central banks focused on the wrong indicators, fiddling while New York burned? In focusing exclu- sively on the use of interest rates to target inflation (and stabilize output) are we shifting volatility to other markets? The case for the prosecution has been trenchantly argued by Steve Roach of Morgan Stanley. In a piece in Fortune magazine unambiguously entitled “The Great Failure of Central Banking” he argues that “central banks have failed to provide a stable underpinning to world financial mar- kets and to an increasingly asset dependent economy”.3 Roach maintains that “the current financial crisis is a wake up call for modern day central banking” and that “the art and science of central banking is in desperate need of a major overhaul”. His principal concrete recommendation is that monetary authorities need to take the state of asset markets into explicit 3 ‘The Great Failure of Central Banking,’ Stephen Roach. Fortune, August 2007. WORLD ECONOMICS • Vol. 9 • No. 1 • January–March 2008 15 Howard Davies consideration when framing policy options and that “failure to recognise the interplay between the state of asset markets and the real economy is an egregious error”.
Recommended publications
  • University of Surrey Discussion Papers in Economics By
    råáp=== = = ======råáîÉêëáíó=çÑ=pìêêÉó Discussion Papers in Economics THE DISSENT VOTING BEHAVIOUR OF BANK OF ENGLAND MPC MEMBERS By Christopher Spencer (University of Surrey) DP 03/06 Department of Economics University of Surrey Guildford Surrey GU2 7XH, UK Telephone +44 (0)1483 689380 Facsimile +44 (0)1483 689548 Web www.econ.surrey.ac.uk ISSN: 1749-5075 The Dissent Voting Behaviour of Bank of England MPC Members∗ Christopher Spencer† Department of Economics, University of Surrey Abstract I examine the propensity of Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee (BoEMPC) members to cast dissenting votes. In particular, I compare the type and frequency of dissenting votes cast by so- called insiders (members of the committee chosen from within the ranks of bank staff)andoutsiders (committee members chosen from outside the ranks of bank staff). Significant differences in the dissent voting behaviour associated with these groups is evidenced. Outsiders are significantly more likely to dissent than insiders; however, whereas outsiders tend to dissent on the side of monetary ease, insiders do so on the side of monetary tightness. I also seek to rationalise why such differences might arise, and in particular, why BoEMPC members might be incentivised to dissent. Amongst other factors, the impact of career backgrounds on dissent voting is examined. Estimates from logit analysis suggest that the effect of career backgrounds is negligible. Keywords: Monetary Policy Committee, insiders, outsiders, dissent voting, career backgrounds, ap- pointment procedures. Contents 1 Introduction 2 2 Relationship to the Literature 2 3 Rationalising Dissent Amongst Insiders and Outsiders - Some Priors 3 3.1CareerIncentives........................................... 4 3.2CareerBackgrounds........................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Case of Neglected Liquidity Risks in Market-Based Banking
    Regulation & Governance (2021) 15, 909–932 doi:10.1111/rego.12330 Divisions of regulatory labor, institutional closure, and structural secrecy in new regulatory states: The case of neglected liquidity risks in market-based banking Leon Wansleben Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Cologne, Germany Abstract Monetary policy and financial regulation have been regarded one of the paradigmatic domains where states can reap the bene- fits of delegating clearly delineated and unequivocal policy tasks to specialized technocrats. This article discusses the negative side-effects and unintended consequences of particular ways to partition such tasks. The separation between monetary policy formulation, central banks’ money market management, and financial supervision has weakened policy makers’ capacities to address risks associated with banks’ active liability management and to mitigate pro-cyclical dynamics in money markets. These adverse effects derive from the neglect of liquidity as a regulatory problem in formal task descriptions; from the obsta- cles to positive coordination between specialized technocrats in the self-contained domains of monetary policy formulation, implementation, and prudential regulation; and from a dissociation between formal responsibilities, which lie with regulators, and the resources residing in money market divisions – market expertise and influence over counterparties – that are critical to influence bank behavior. I explore these mechanisms with an in-depth case study of British monetary and financial gover- nance between 1970 and 2007. I posit that we can generalize the respective mechanisms to explore unintended effects of ‘agencification’ and to contribute to a broader re-assessment of those organizing principles that have guided the construction of ‘new regulatory states’.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Economics and the Political Economy of Central Banking
    Monetary Economics and the Political Economy of Central Banking: * ** Inflation Targeting and Central Bank Independence Revisited 27-01-2008 Willem H. Buiter Professor of European Political Economy, European Institute. London School of Economics and Political Science * © Willem H. Buiter, 2006, 2007 ** Paper presented at the Session: ‘Changing Doctrinal Perspectives in Central Banking’ at the Central Bank of Argentina 2007 Money and Banking Conference “Monetary Policy Under Uncertainty”, June 4-5 2007, Buenos Aires, Argentina. An earlier version of this paper provided the background to a lecture given at the XI Meeting of the Research Network of Central Banks of the Americas, Buenos Aires, 22 - 24 November 2006. I would like to thank Charlie Bean, Tim Besley, Mario Blejer, Guillermo Calvo, Howard Davies, Katherine Hennings, Christopher Kent, Manuel Ramos Francia, Katerina Smidkova, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel for comments on earlier versions of this paper. 1 Introduction There is a widespread consensus among practicing and practical central bankers as well as among theoretical and applied monetary economists, that the canonical global best practice central bank is operationally independent 1 and targets inflation 2. Historically, whenever a near-universal consensus takes hold of the economics profession, it tends to be at least half wrong. A concern that this may be happening in the areas of inflation targeting and central bank independence prompted the choice of subject for this lecture. I. Inflation targeting Inflation targeting – the pursuit of a low and stable rate of inflation over the medium-to-long term for some broadly based index of consumer prices or cost-of-living index - is best rationalised as the operational expression of the pursuit of the more fundamental objective of price stability.
    [Show full text]
  • Center on Capitalism and Society At
    CENTER ON CAPITALISM AND SOCIETY AT CCS Conference on the Financial Crisis Friday, February 20, 2009 Italian Academy, Columbia University 1161 Amsterdam Avenue (between 116th and 118th Streets) Program 9:00 am: Introductory Remarks Prof. Edmund S. Phelps, Director, Center on Capitalism and Society, and McVickar Professor of Political Economy, Columbia University. Winner of 2006 Nobel Prize in Economics. 9:10am – 10:40am: Panel 1: Reforming the Financial Sector Chair: To be announced Prof. Edmund S. Phelps, Director, Center on Capitalism and Society, and McVickar Professor of Political Economy, Columbia University. Winner of 2006 Nobel Prize in Economics. [confirmed] Prof. Amar Bhidé, Glaubinger Professor of Business, Graduate School of Business, Columbia University. Co-editor, Capitalism and Society. [confirmed] Dr. Richard Robb, CEO of Christofferson, Robb and Company. Associate Professor of Professional Practice in International Finance, School of International and Public Affairs at Columbia University. [confirmed] Mr. Leo Tilman, President of L.M. Tilman & Co. Author of Financial Darwinism: Create Value or Self-Destruct in a World of Risk. [confirmed] Mr. John Kay, Member, Council of Economic Advisers, Scottish Government. Author of The Truth about Markets and contributor, Financial Times. [confirmed] Prof. Jose A. Scheinkman, Theodore A. Wells Professor of Economics, Princeton University 10:40 – 10:55am: Coffee 10:55am – 12:25pm: Panel 2: Regulating the new Financial Sector Chair: To be announced Mrs. Christine Lagarde, Minister of Economics, Industry and Employment, France. [confirmed] Dr. Malcolm Knight, Vice-Chairman, Deutsche Bank. Former General Manager, BIS. [confirmed] Prof. Joseph Stiglitz, University Professor, Columbia University. Chair, Committee on Global Thought, Columbia University. Executive Director, Initiative for Policy Dialogue, Columbia University.
    [Show full text]
  • Transforming Uncertainty Into Opportunity
    Citi Private Bank cordially invites you to: Transforming Uncertainty into Opportunity Print Next > Close Foreword It is my pleasure to cordially invite you to Citi Private Bank’s Global Outlook 2013: Transforming Uncertainty into Opportunity. At this annual Outlook roadshow that runs across the Europe, Middle East and Africa region, you will hear from Citi’s top analysts and strategists on various topical issues — views on investment opportunities and challenges awaiting investors; perspectives on global and regional geopolitical and economic developments; markets insight by asset class and geography; and informed opinions about managing one’s wealth in 2013. We look forward to your participation at the event, and for the opportunity of more thoughtful and productive discussions with our bankers and investment specialists on your wealth management plans. Luigi Pigorini Chief Executive Officer Citi Private Bank, Europe, Middle East and Africa Print < Back Next > Close Date & Time Thursday 17 January 2013 15.30 — 18.15 Location Ballroom The Berkeley Wilton Place The Berkeley Knightsbridge London SW1X 7RL Dress code Business-casual RSVP (by 8/1/13) Please email [email protected] or contact your Private Banker. Please let us know if you have any special dietary requirements Print < Back Next > Close Agenda 15.30 Welcome Refreshments 16.00 Welcome Address 16.05 2012 Retrospective and 2013 Outlook Willem Buiter, Chief Economist, Citi 16.30 2012 Political Review and 2013 Political Outlook Tina Fordham, Senior Political Analyst, Citi 17.00
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation Report
    Inflation Report November 1998 The Inflation Report is produced quarterly by Bank staff under the guidance of the members of the Monetary Policy Committee. It serves a dual purpose. First, its preparation provides a comprehensive and forward-looking framework for discussion among MPC members as an aid to our decision making. Second, its publication allows us to share our thinking and explain the reasons for our decisions to those whom they affect. Although not every member will agree with every assumption on which our projections are based, the fan charts represent the MPC’s best collective judgment about the most likely path for inflation and output, and the uncertainties surrounding those central projections. This Report has been prepared and published by the Bank of England in accordance with section 18 of the Bank of England Act 1998. The Monetary Policy Committee: Eddie George, Governor Mervyn King, Deputy Governor responsible for monetary policy David Clementi, Deputy Governor responsible for financial stability Alan Budd Willem Buiter Charles Goodhart DeAnne Julius Ian Plenderleith John Vickers The Overview of this Inflation Report is available on the Bank’s web site: www.bankofengland.co.uk/infrep.htm. The entire Report is available in PDF format on www.bankofengland.co.uk/ir.htm. Printed by Park Communications Ltd © Bank of England 1998 ISBN 1 85730 181 1 ISSN 1353–6737 Overview The Monetary Policy Committee sets interest rates to maintain a path for inflation looking ahead that is consistent with the 2.5% target for inflation on the RPIX measure. This requires the Committee to act in response to prospective deviations—downwards or upwards—from the inflation target in a symmetrical fashion.
    [Show full text]
  • [Presentation Title/Subject]
    May 26, 2017 Global Economic Outlook Willem BuiterAC Global Chief Economist [email protected] +1 212-816-2363 See Appendix A-1 for Analyst Certification, Important Disclosures and non-US research analyst disclosures Citi Research is a division of Citigroup Global Markets Inc. (the "Firm"), which does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research reports. As a result, investors should be aware that the Firm may have a conflict of interest that could affect the objectivity of this report.. Investors should consider this report as only a single factor in making their investment decision. Certain products (not inconsistent with the author's published research) are available only on Citi's portals. This presentation was approved for distribution on 21 May 2017; the disclosures in Appendix A1 are current as of the same date. Global growth looks relatively stable with some signs of a pick up We see a cyclical pickup in GDP growth across AEs and EMs with industrial production and trade growth leading the way Global— Real GDP Growth (%YY) Global—Composite, Mfg and Services PMI % YoY Diffusion index (50+= Expansion) 6 56 Global Forecasts Global 5 AE 55 Manufacturing EM Services 54 4 53 3 52 2 51 50 1 49 0 48 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 Note: Aggregates at market exchange rates. Global and EM aggregates exclude Sources: Markit and Citi Research. Venezuela. Source: National Statistical Offices, IMF and Citi Research US and China – Industrial Production AE and EM – Goods Exports and Imports %3M/3M saar 20 3m3m saar 30 18 US AE Exports AE Imports 16 25 14 China 20 EM Exports EM Imports 12 15 10 8 10 6 5 4 0 2 0 -5 -2 -10 -4 -15 -6 Mar-17 Feb-17 -8 -20 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2014 2015 2016 2017 Sources: FRB, NBS and Citi Research.
    [Show full text]
  • Provision of Emergency Liquidity Assistance in 2008/9
    REVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND’S PROVISION OF EMERGENCY LIQUIDITY ASSISTANCE IN 2008–09 Report by Ian Plenderleith Presented to the Court of the Bank of England October 2012 Introduction Introduction 1. This Review examines the actions of the Bank of England at the height of the financial crisis, around the collapse of Lehman Brothers, to provide emergency liquidity assistance (ELA) to HBOS and Royal Bank of Scotland in 2008–09. It is one of three reviews commissioned by the Court of Governors of the Bank on 21 May 2012. 2. The terms of reference for the Review (set out in full in Appendix 1) specify that its purpose is to learn lessons to inform the way the Bank conducts ELA operations for individual financial institutions. Specifically, the Review is charged with examining: The basis of the decisions to provide ELA to each firm concerned; The governance arrangements within the Bank for making those decisions; The structure and terms of each ELA operation; The effects of those operations on the institutions concerned and on overall financial stability; The capability of the Bank to plan, implement and manage those operations. 3. Overall, the Review is charged with examining how the Bank discharged its responsibilities as lender of last resort in a crisis and making recommendations for the conduct of any such operations in the future. 4. The Review addresses this remit by examining each aspect of the Bank’s ELA operations in 2008–09 in turn. At each stage, an assessment is made of the effectiveness of the Bank’s actions in the circumstances of the time; and, looking forward, recommendations are made at various points on issues the Bank may need to consider for the conduct of any future ELA operations.
    [Show full text]
  • Tilburg University Gorby Games Güth, W.; Van Damme, E.E.C
    Tilburg University Gorby games Güth, W.; van Damme, E.E.C. Publication date: 1991 Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal Citation for published version (APA): Güth, W., & van Damme, E. E. C. (1991). Gorby games: A game theoretic analysis of disarmament campaigns and the defense efficiency-hypothesis. (Reprint series / CentER for Economic Research; Vol. 62). Unknown Publisher. General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain • You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim. Download date: 29. sep. 2021 ~~~~ cBM R for ~mic Research 8823 IIIIIIIIIIIullllIIIIIIIIINIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII 1991 62 Gorby Games - A Game Theoretic Analysis of Disarmament Campaigns and the Defense Efficiency - Hypothesis - by Werner Guth and Eric van Damme Reprinted from R. Avenhaus, H. Karkar and M. Rudnianski (eds.), Defense Decision Making - Analytical Support
    [Show full text]
  • Unbundling 'Too Big to Fail'
    AP PHOTO/MARK LENNIHAN PHOTO/MARK AP Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Why Big Is Bad and What to Do About It By Ganesh Sitaraman July 2014 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG Unbundling ‘Too Big to Fail’ Why Big Is Bad and What to Do About It By Ganesh Sitaraman July 2014 Contents 1 Introduction and summary 2 Unbundling too big to fail 9 Reforming too big to fail 18 Conclusion 20 Endnotes Introduction and summary Since the 2008 financial crisis, the problem of financial institutions being “too big to fail,” or TBTF, has been front and center in the public debate over the reform and regulation of the financial industry. Commentators across the political spectrum decried bailouts of the biggest Wall Street financial institutions, arguing that bail- outs would establish too big to fail as public policy. When it was time for reform, legislators tried to address this problem, and even incorporated into the full title of the Dodd-Frank Act that one of the bill’s purposes was “to end ‘too big to fail.’”1 Yet more than five years after the financial crash, the biggest banks are 37 percent larger than they were before,2 and the debate over what to do about the size of finan- cial institutions continues. Policy proposals range from improving resolution mecha- nisms, to more stringent prudential standards such as leverage limits, to charging fees to eliminate the implicit government subsidy the biggest banks receive, to capping the size of the banks, to instituting a new Glass-Steagall Act. Each approach is hotly contested, with commentators frequently arguing that the proposed solution will not actually fix the problem of financial institutions that are too big to fail.3 The problem at the heart of the debate over too big to fail is that the popular moniker has come to mean more than the concern that big firms get a government bailout in the event of failure.
    [Show full text]
  • Central Banks: Powerful, Political and Unaccountable?
    Journal of the British Academy, 2, 269–303. DOI 10.5871/jba/002.269 Posted 19 December 2014. © The British Academy 2014 Central banks: Powerful, political and unaccountable? Keynes Lecture in Economics1 read 18 September 2014 WILLEM H. BUITER Fellow of the Academy Abstract: The economic and political importance of central banks has grown markedly in advanced economies since the start of the Great Financial Crisis in 2007. In this article I argue that the preservation of the central bank’s legitimacy and independence requires that a clear line be drawn between the central bank’s provision of liquidity and the Treasury’s solvency support for systemically important financial institutions. Central banks should not be materially involved in regulation and supervision of the financial sector. All activities of the central bank that expose it to material credit risk should be guaranteed by the Treasury. In addition, central banks must increase their accountability by increasing the transparency of their lender-of- last-resort and market-maker-of-last resort activities. Central banks ought not to engage in quasi-fiscal activities. Finally, central banks should stick to their knitting and central bankers should not become participants in public debates and deeply political arguments about matters beyond their mandate and competence, including fiscal policy and structural reform. Keywords: Quasi-fiscal, independence, legitimacy, accountability, regulation, supervision. JEL Classification: E02, E42, E52, E58, E61, E62, E63, G18, G28, H63 1. INTRODUCTION The economic and political importance of central banks has grown markedly in advanced economies since the start of the Great Financial Crisis (GFC) in 2007.
    [Show full text]
  • CEP Discussion Paper No 786 April 2007 Seigniorage Willem Buiter
    CEP Discussion Paper No 786 April 2007 Seigniorage Willem Buiter Abstract Governments through the ages have appropriated real resources through the monopoly of the ‘coinage’. In modern fiat money economies, the monopoly of the issue of legal tender is generally assigned to an agency of the state, the Central Bank, which may have varying degrees of operational and target independence from the government of the day. In this paper I analyse four different but related concepts, each of which highlights some aspect of the way in which the state acquires command over real resources through its ability to issue fiat money. They are (1) seigniorage (the change in the monetary base), (2) Central Bank revenue (the interest bill saved by the authorities on the outstanding stock of base money liabilities), (3) the inflation tax (the reduction in the real value of the stock of base money due to inflation and (4) the operating profits of the central bank, or the taxes paid by the Central Bank to the Treasury. To understand the relationship between these four concepts, an explicitly intertemporal approach is required, which focuses on the present discounted value of the current and future resource transfers between the private sector and the state. Furthermore, when the Central Bank is operationally independent, it is essential to decompose the familiar consolidated ‘government budget constraint’ and consolidated ‘government intertemporal budget constraint’ into the separate accounts and budget constraints of the Central Bank and the Treasury. Only by doing this can we appreciate the financial constraints on the Central Bank’s ability to pursue and achieve an inflation target, and the importance of cooperation and coordination between the Treasury and the Central Bank when faced with financial sector crises involving the need for long-term recapitalisation or when confronted with the need to mimic Milton Friedman’s helicopter drop of money in an economy faced with a liquidity trap.
    [Show full text]