Translated Attributes As Choice Architecture: Aligning Objectives and Choices Through Decision Signposts

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Translated Attributes As Choice Architecture: Aligning Objectives and Choices Through Decision Signposts MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Articles in Advance, pp. 1–15 http://pubsonline.informs.org/journal/mnsc/ ISSN 0025-1909 (print), ISSN 1526-5501 (online) Translated Attributes as Choice Architecture: Aligning Objectives and Choices Through Decision Signposts Christoph Ungemach,a Adrian R. Camilleri,b Eric J. Johnson,c Richard P. Larrick,d Elke U. Webere a TUM School of Management, Technische Universität München, 80333 München, Germany; b RMIT University, Melbourne, Victoria 3000, Australia; c Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York, New York 10027; d Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina 27708; e Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey 08544 Contact: [email protected] (CU); [email protected] (ARC); [email protected] (EJJ); [email protected] (RPL); [email protected] (EUW) Received: February 2, 2015 Abstract. Every attribute can be expressed in multiple ways. For example, car fuel econ- Accepted: August 23, 2016 omy can be expressed as fuel efficiency (“miles per gallon”), fuel cost in dollars, or tons of Published Online in Articles in Advance: greenhouse gases emitted. Each expression, or “translation,” highlights a different aspect March 23, 2017 of the same attribute. We describe a new mechanism whereby translated attributes can https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2703 serve as decision “signposts” because they (1) activate otherwise dormant objectives, such as proenvironmental values and goals, and (2) direct the person toward the option that Copyright: © 2017 INFORMS best achieves the activated objective. Across three experiments, we provide evidence for the occurrence of such signpost effects as well as the underlying psychological mech- anism. We demonstrate that expressing an attribute such as fuel economy in terms of multiple translations can increase preference for the option that is better aligned with objectives congruent with this attribute (e.g., the more fuel-efficient car for those with pro- environmental attitudes), even when the new information is derivable from other known attributes. We discuss how using translated attributes appropriately can help align a per- son’s choices with their personal objectives. History: Accepted by Yuval Rottenstreich, judgment and decision making. Funding: Financial support from the National Science Foundation [Grant SES 0951516] is gratefully acknowledged. The second author was supported by an Alcoa Foundation Fellowship (2787_2012) received from the American Australian Association. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2703. Keywords: behavioral decision making • behavioral economics • consumer behavior • choice architecture • theory • government • regulations • applications • marketing • segmentation • translated attributes • proenvironmental behavior 1. Introduction overwhelm a person. On the other, less information Choice options typically vary on multiple attributes. could deprive a person of important facts. For example, a car’s attributes include price, fuel econ- Little may be gained by presenting one translated omy, safety rating, and type of navigation system. attribute instead of another because the two trans- In turn, each attribute can have multiple translations, lated attributes are often perfectly correlated. From that is, different ways the attribute can be expressed. a strictly rational point of view, translated attributes For instance, a car’s fuel economy can be expressed are completely redundant if the translation equiva- in different ways. Figure1 shows the U.S. Environ- lence is known. However, the theoretical perspective of bounded rationality (Simon 1982) and supporting mental Protection Agency (EPA) fuel economy and empirical evidence suggest that people tend to con- environment label, which expresses fuel economy in struct their preferences (Lichtenstein and Slovic 2006; terms of miles travelled per gallon of fuel, the esti- Payne et al. 1988, 1993; Ungemach et al. 2011) using mated annual fuel cost (AFC), and a 1-to-10 green- information about choice options at face value (e.g., house gas rating (GGR), among others. These differ- Downloaded from informs.org by [128.112.72.171] on 19 May 2017, at 12:21 . For personal use only, all rights reserved. the concreteness principle, Slovic 1972; or What You ent expressions, which we term “translated attributes,” See Is All There Is [WYSIATI], Kahneman 2011). Bond are closely related to each other and highly corre- et al. (2008) have shown that people often overlook lated. Nevertheless, each translation also highlights key personal objectives when making choices because different aspects of the same attribute. A fundamental they possess a myopic mental representation of the decision faced by policy makers is to determine how choice. Assuming that consideration of personal objec- much information should be presented to people to tives is beneficial to effective decision making (Keeney help them make better decisions for themselves and 1992), these findings imply that people often end up for society. On the one hand, more information could with suboptimal decision outcomes that are not fully 1 Ungemach et al.: Translated Attributes as Choice Architecture 2 Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–15, © 2017 INFORMS Figure 1. (Color online) The Current U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Fuel Economy and Environment Label for Gasoline Vehicles aligned with personal objectives. Bond et al. (2008) global attribute, we identify and test two different pro- have suggested that recognition of important per- cesses by which translated attributes affect decisions. sonal objectives may be assisted through guides that Specifically, we distinguish the established effects of describe additional features of products such as con- noncompensatory heuristics such as counting superi- sumer reports. We propose that translated attributes ority across attributes and using the majority rule (e.g., play a similar role in improving choice: they allow Alba and Marmorstein 1987, Russo and Dosher 1983, people to recognize important personal objectives that Zhang et al. 2006), and our own novel explanation: would otherwise be overlooked. Therefore, our gen- activation of relevant objectives and direction toward eral hypothesis is that translated attributes have the achieving them through decision signposts. potential to influence preferences because they serve as decision “signposts” helping people first recognize 1.1. Translated Attributes as Decision Signposts and then pursue options congruent with their personal On a roadside, a signpost has two important fea- objectives. tures: First, it indicates the presence of a destination Previous literature has shown that partitioning a that might be of personal relevance, such as a nearby global attribute into components can increase the town. Second, it points out how to reach the destina- weight accorded to that global attribute (Dawes 1979, tion by providing the actual direction and distance Fischhoff et al. 1978, Weber et al. 1988). For exam- to travel. Similarly, translated attributes possess both ple, the global attribute “job security” can be split into features. First, translated attributes can produce acti- component attributes such as “stability of the firm” vation of personally relevant objectives. This implies and “personal job security.” Although related to par- that a translated attribute will have the most impact titioning, the notion of translated attributes has three on those who have objectives matching those aspects features that distinguish it from this earlier literature. highlighted by the translated attribute. Second, a deci- First, translated attributes are monotone transforma- sion signpost conveys direction toward achieving those tions of each other and highly correlated, whereas com- objectives by explicitly describing the degree to which Downloaded from informs.org by [128.112.72.171] on 19 May 2017, at 12:21 . For personal use only, all rights reserved. ponents of a global attribute described in the attribute different options meet the person’s objectives. splitting literature may not be correlated at all. Sec- People have many objectives that can arise from dif- ond, translated attributes differ from derived attributes ferent sources, such as values and goals. Values are used in advertising, such as a car being described as stable dispositions that structure and guide specific “masculine,” because translated attributes all map onto beliefs, norms, and attitudes (Feather 1995, Rokeach actual physical properties of the object. Third, and 1973). Goals are motivational constructs directed to most importantly, whereas the attribute splitting lit- achieve a desirable end state (van Osselaer and erature demonstrates the phenomenon that the sum Janiszewski 2012). Goals direct movement that leads to of component attributes attracts more weight than the degrees of achievement allowing progress (and failure) Ungemach et al.: Translated Attributes as Choice Architecture Management Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–15, © 2017 INFORMS 3 to be gauged (Huang et al. 2012). Goals, such as loos- partitioning of options and attributes (Fox et al. 2005; ing 5 lbs over the summer, are typically more specific for reviews, see Johnson et al. 2012 and Camilleri and and temporary than values, such as living healthily. Larrick 2015). These interventions, sometimes referred Values can direct which goals are considered impor- to as “nudges,” often operate beneath conscious aware- tant, and
Recommended publications
  • The Behavioural Science of Online Harm and Manipulation, and What to Do About It
    The behavioural science of online harm and manipulation, and what to do about it An exploratory paper to spark ideas and debate Elisabeth Costa and David Halpern The Behavioural Insights Team |The behavioural science of online harm and manipulation, and what to do about it 1 Acknowledgements We would like to thank Lucie Martin, Ed Flahavan, Andrew Schein and Lucy Makinson for outstanding research assistance. This paper was improved by lively discussions and useful comments from Elspeth Kirkman, Cass Sunstein, Tony Curzon-Price, Roger Taylor, Stephen Dunne, Kate Glazebrook, Louise Barber, Ross Haig, Aisling Colclough, Aisling Ni Chonaire, Hubert Wu, Nida Broughton, Ravi Dutta-Powell, Michael Kaemingk, Max Kroner Dale, Jake Appel, Matthew Davies, Flo Farghly, Toby Park, Carolin Reiner, Veronika Luptakova, Ed Fitzhugh and Pantelis Solomon. © Behavioural Insights Ltd. Not to be reproduced without the permission of the Behavioural Insights Team 2 The Behavioural Insights Team |The behavioural science of online harm and manipulation, and what to do about it Contents 03 Executive summary 11 1. Introduction 12 2. Challenges 13 2.1. The potential to exploit consumer biases online 16 2.2. Understanding and accepting the ‘terms of engagement’ online 18 2.3. Trust simulations 20 2.4. Attention wars 21 2.5. Predicting our preferences 24 2.6. More than markets: morals, ethics and social networks 24 Patterns of association 25 Economy of regard 26 Civility and online harassment 26 Mental health 28 2.7. Emerging problems 28 Fake news and deep fakes 28 Personalised pricing and price discrimination 29 Biased algorithms and AI tools 30 New monopolies 32 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Nudge Theory
    Nudge Theory http://www.businessballs.com/nudge-theory.htm Nudge theory is a flexible and modern concept for: • understanding of how people think, make decisions, and behave, • helping people improve their thinking and decisions, • managing change of all sorts, and • identifying and modifying existing unhelpful influences on people. Nudge theory was named and popularized by the 2008 book, 'Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness', written by American academics Richard H Thaler and Cass R Sunstein. The book is based strongly on the Nobel prize- winning work of the Israeli-American psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. This article: • reviews and explains Thaler and Sunstein's 'Nudge' concept, especially 'heuristics' (tendencies for humans to think and decide instinctively and often mistakenly) • relates 'Nudge' methods to other theories and models, and to Kahneman and Tversky's work • defines and describes additional methods of 'nudging' people and groups • extends the appreciation and application of 'Nudge' methodology to broader change- management, motivation, leadership, coaching, counselling, parenting, etc • offers 'Nudge' methods and related concepts as a 'Nudge' theory 'toolkit' so that the concept can be taught and applied in a wide range of situations involving relationships with people, and enabling people to improve their thinking and decision- making • and offers a glossary of Nudge theory and related terms 'Nudge' theory was proposed originally in US 'behavioral economics', but it can be adapted and applied much more widely for enabling and encouraging change in people, groups, or yourself. Nudge theory can also be used to explore, understand, and explain existing influences on how people behave, especially influences which are unhelpful, with a view to removing or altering them.
    [Show full text]
  • A Menu for Change
    A Menu for Change Using behavioural science to promote sustainable diets around the world The Behavioural Insights Team / A Menu for Change 2 The Behavioural Insights Team / A Menu for Change Toby Park, Head of Energy & Sustainability, The Behavioural Insights Team [email protected] Acknowledgements This report has benefitted from several individuals’ contributions. With particular thanks for substantive research support and contributions to early content and the structure of the report, to Emma Garnett (University of Cambridge) and Brittney Titus (University of Oxford), both supporting us while at placement at BIT. With thanks also to Elisabeth Costa (BIT), Dr Filippo Bianchi (BIT), Dr Jessica Barker (BIT), and Dr Christian Reynolds (University of Sheffield) for their valuable feedback and comments. This is a long report. We hope you’ll read it cover-to-cover, but if not, it’s written to allow you to dip into individual sections. Look out for the short orange descriptions at the beginning of each chapter to keep track of where you are. Sections 1.1-1.2 introduce the problem, and make the rationale for shifting global diets. This will be familiar ground for environmental scientists. Section 1.3 looks at the current state, and emerging trends, in diets around the world, and Section 1.4 highlights the many historical occasions when diets have radically changed through technological innovation or deliberate intervention from government and industry. Section 1.5 acknowledges the sensitivities of this topic, and offers some reflections on how we might navigate public and political consent. We don’t have all the answers here but give a series of recommendations for building public support and developing effective policy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Code of the Platform
    THE CODE OF THE PLATFORM Abbey Stemler* Joshua E. Perry** Todd Haugh*** Digital platform-based businesses such as Uber, eBay, and Google have become ubiquitous in our daily lives. They have done so by expertly harnessing technology to bring supply- and demand-side users together for commercial and social exchange. Users are happy to let these platform companies play “matchmaker” because transaction costs are lowered—it is easier to find or give a ride, buy or sell a product, or obtain almost any kind of information than ever before— and platforms are happy to be at the center of the exchange, taking advantage of network effects to become wildly successful. Despite the success of these platforms, however, there is an increasing unease with the methods that platforms use to sustain their multi-sided markets—namely, users question whether they are being manipulated by some of their favorite companies. This Article offers a first-of-its kind analysis into both the legality and ethicality of platform companies, specifically their use of technologically enhanced * Assistant Professor of Business Law and Ethics, Indiana University, Kelley School of Business; Faculty Associate, Berkman Klein Center for Internet and Society at Harvard University; Consultant, World Bank Group; Affiliate, Ostrom Workshop. ** Associate Professor of Business Law and Ethics and Glaubinger Chair for Undergraduate Leadership, Indiana University, Kelley School of Business. *** Assistant Professor of Business Law and Ethics, Indiana University, Kelley School of Business; Board Member, the Poynter Center for the Study of Ethics and American Institutions; Supreme Court Fellow, Supreme Court of the United States. The authors would like to thank the University of Pennsylvania Law School’s conference on the Harmonization of Business Law, the Northeast Privacy Scholars Workshop at Fordham University School of Law, and the Law and Ethics of Big Data colloquium at Babson College for helpful comments on early drafts of this Article.
    [Show full text]
  • The Heteronomy of Choice Architecture
    Original citation: Mills, Chris. (2015) The heteronomy of choice architecture. Review of Philosophy and Psychology, 6 (3). pp. 495-509. Permanent WRAP URL: http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/91069 Copyright and reuse: The Warwick Research Archive Portal (WRAP) makes this work by researchers of the University of Warwick available open access under the following conditions. Copyright © and all moral rights to the version of the paper presented here belong to the individual author(s) and/or other copyright owners. To the extent reasonable and practicable the material made available in WRAP has been checked for eligibility before being made available. Copies of full items can be used for personal research or study, educational, or not-for profit purposes without prior permission or charge. Provided that the authors, title and full bibliographic details are credited, a hyperlink and/or URL is given for the original metadata page and the content is not changed in any way. Publisher’s statement: “The final publication is available at Springer via http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s13164-015- 0242-7 A note on versions: The version presented here may differ from the published version or, version of record, if you wish to cite this item you are advised to consult the publisher’s version. Please see the ‘permanent WRAP url’ above for details on accessing the published version and note that access may require a subscription. For more information, please contact the WRAP Team at: [email protected] warwick.ac.uk/lib-publications The Heteronomy of Choice Architecture Review of Philosophy and Psychology 6, no.
    [Show full text]
  • Decision Opportunity & Choice Architecture
    FACULTY OF ENGINEERING AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Department of Industrial Development, IT and Land Management Decision Opportunity & Choice Architecture On the risk of basement floods David Snällfot 2015 Student thesis, Master degree (one year), 15 HE Decision, Risk and Policy Analysis Master Programme in Decision, Risk and Policy Analysis Supervisor: Fredrik Bökman Examiner: Eva Boo-Höglund Decision Opportunity & Choice Architecture On the risk of basement floods by David Snällfot Faculty of Engineering and Sustainable Development University of Gävle S-801 76 Gävle, Sweden Email: [email protected] Abstract In the paper I propose a decision opportunity for the problem of basement flooding caused by heavy precipitation: property owners can mitigate this risk before it materializes. Implementing the decision opportunity requires an active choice. Social science findings suggest comprehensive and pervasive information processing deficiencies together with contextual influences strongly affect decision behavior. Presenting the decision opportunity in a way that limits negative interference from these behavioral problems is therefore a key theme of the paper. I adopt the PrOACT approach to analyze and resolve these distinct problems. This involves exploring relevant objectives for property owners and for the presentation of the decision opportunity. I consider several technical as well as behavioral alternatives. Backwater valves represent the main group of the former and choice architectural tool sets the latter. Backwater valves block sewage backflow while choice architecture concerns how to present a choice given behavioral problems. By considering the consequences of these alternatives on the relevant objectives the process of eliminating dominated alternatives is pursued, followed by making tradeoffs which enable the identification of suggested choices.
    [Show full text]
  • The Choice Architecture of Choice Architecture: Toward a Non-Paternalistic Nudge Policy
    The Choice Architecture of Choice Architecture: Toward a Non-paternalistic Nudge Policy By David Colander and Andrew Qi Lin Chong October 2010 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 10-36 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE MIDDLEBURY, VERMONT 05753 http://www.middlebury.edu/~econ The Choice Architecture of Choice Architecture: Toward a Non-paternalistic Nudge Policy David Colander and Andrew Qi Lin Chong Middlebury College Abstract The paper seeks to recast the goal of nudge policy from a goal of achieving a specific result determined by government or by behavioral economists to a goal of giving individuals as much power as is practical to decide the choice architecture they face. We call a nudge with such a giving individuals “power over choice mechanisms” goal a non- paternalistic nudge policy. The goal of non-paternalistic nudge policy is not to achieve a better result as seen by government or by behavioral economists. The goal of non- paternalistic nudge policy is to achieve a better result as seen by the agents being nudged as revealed through their choices of choice architectures. We argue that non-paternalistic nudge policy fits much better with the values inherent in Classical liberalism than does libertarian paternalistic nudge policy. Key words: libertarian, paternalism, nudge policy, choice architecture, behavioral economics JEL Code: D02, D60 The Choice Architecture of Choice Architecture: Toward a Non-paternalistic Nudge Policy David Colander and Andrew Qi Lin Chong Behavioral economics adds a new dimension to economic policy; it allows for the possibility of influencing people’s decisions through a change in the choice architecture they face.
    [Show full text]
  • Nudging to Move: a Scoping Review of the Use of Choice Architecture Interventions to Promote Physical Activity in the General Population
    Nudging to Move A Scoping Review of the Use of Choice Architecture Interventions to Promote Physical Activity in the General Population Forberger, Sarah; Reisch, Lucia A.; Kampfmann, Teresa; Zeeb, Hajo Document Version Final published version Published in: International Journal of Behavioral Nutrition and Physical Activity DOI: 10.1186/s12966-019-0844-z Publication date: 2019 License CC BY Citation for published version (APA): Forberger, S., Reisch, L. A., Kampfmann, T., & Zeeb, H. (2019). Nudging to Move: A Scoping Review of the Use of Choice Architecture Interventions to Promote Physical Activity in the General Population. International Journal of Behavioral Nutrition and Physical Activity, 16(1), [77]. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12966-019-0844-z Link to publication in CBS Research Portal General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us ([email protected]) providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim. Download date: 29. Sep. 2021 Forberger et al. International Journal of Behavioral Nutrition and Physical Activity (2019) 16:77 https://doi.org/10.1186/s12966-019-0844-z REVIEW Open Access Nudging to move: a scoping review of the use of choice architecture interventions to promote physical activity in the general population S. Forberger1* , L. Reisch2,3 , T. Kampfmann1 and H.
    [Show full text]
  • Cognitive Bias & Choice Architecture
    Cognitive Bias & Choice Architecture Jamie Neville, University Housing Services The Inspiration Goals • To learn the basics of how people make decisions • To learn how we impact those decisions • To recognize the importance of being both ethical and intentional in how we present choices to our students Learning Outcomes • Develop a basic understanding of heuristics, cognitive bias, and choice architecture • Identify ways cognitive bias impact daily decision making • Utilize principles of choice architecture to enhance the decisions made by students • Understand the ethical issues associated with choice architecture APPROXIMATELY 6 ½ MILLION XBOX ONE CONSOLES WERE SOLD IN THE LAST HOLIDAY SEASON. HOW MANY PLAYSTATION 4 CONSOLES WERE SOLD IN THE SAME TIME FRAME? DID MAHATMA GHANDI DIE BEFORE OR AFTER AGE 100? Jargon • Heuristic – A shortcut or rule of thumb used to make a decision • Cognitive Bias – a flaw in judgment which is caused by memory, social attribution, emotional response, and statistical errors Anchoring • A heuristic that involves using a number or value as a starting point, and then adjusting one's answer away from this anchor • Did we fall victim to the anchoring heuristic? JCPenney IN 2012… IN 2015 How We Think Automatic Reflective • Uncontrolled • Controlled • Effortless • Deductive • Associative • Slow • Fast • Resource Demanding • Unconscious • Follows Rules COMMON HEURISTICS & COGNITIVE BIASES Representativeness • Placing something in a category because it has similarities to members of that category • Essentially, stereotyping
    [Show full text]
  • The Definition of Nudge and Libertarian Paternalism: Does the Hand Fit the Glove? Pelle Guldborg Hansen*
    EJRR 1|2016 The Definition of Nudge and Libertarian Paternalism 155 The Definition of Nudge and Libertarian Paternalism: Does the Hand Fit the Glove? Pelle Guldborg Hansen* In recent years the concepts of ‘nudge’ and ‘libertarian paternalism’ have become popular https://doi.org/10.1017/S1867299X00005468 theoretical as well as practical concepts inside as well as outside academia. But in spite of . the widespread interest, confusion reigns as to what exactly is to be regarded as a nudge and how the underlying approach to behaviour change relates to libertarian paternalism. This article sets out to improve the clarity and value of the definition of nudge by reconcil- ing it with its theoretical foundations in behavioural economics. In doing so it not only ex- plicates the relationship between nudges and libertarian paternalism, but also clarifies how nudges relate to incentives and information, and may even be consistent with the removal of certain types of choices. In the end we are left with a revised definition of the concept of nudge that allows for consistently categorising behaviour change interventions as such and https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms that places them relative to libertarian paternalism. I. Introduction holds that policy makers should avoid regulations that limit choice (bans, caps, etc.) but can use be- “… ‘Soft Paternalism’ would refer to actions of gov- havioural science to direct people towards better ernment that attempt to improve people’s welfare choices.” (Regulatory Policy and Behavioural Eco- by influencing their choices without imposing ma- nomics, (Lunn 2014), OECD report) terial costs on those choices… We can understand soft paternalism, thus defined, as including nudges, Since the publication of Thaler and Sunstein’s andIwillusethetermsinterchangeablyhere.”(Cass Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth Sunstein Why Nudge? The Politics of Libertarian and Happiness1 the concepts of nudge and their par- , subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at Paternalism 2014, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Media and Nudging
    Anders Esmark First Draft. Please do not cite. University of Copenhagen Department of Political Science Unmasking the Informational Logics of Liberal Democracy - making sense of the 'nudge' agenda Introduction A growing number of contributions positioned at the intersection between public administration, policy studies, media sociology and information science have outlined the contours of a new governance paradigm, driven by the process of mediatization and the rise of the network society. This new governance paradigm includes e-governance (Budd & Harris, 2009; Finger & Fouzia, 2012) as well as network governance, communicative governance and good governance (Bang, 2003; Chadwick, 2013; Crozier, 2007; Fuchs, 2009; Hajer, 2009; Hajer & Wagenaar, 2003; Hale, 2011; Roberts, 2015). What these various incarnations of the new governance paradigm share, however, is the notion that state and government is undergoing what Castells has called the ‘imperative but often difficult’ transition from the modern state to a late modern ‘network state’ based on the adoption of the informational logic prevailing in the network society and the ‘information age’ (Castells, 2005, p. 17). The purpose of this article is to bring the question of political logic back in to this growing debate. Existing approaches generally assume that mediatization and the rise of network society force state and government to adopt and internalize the informational logic of network society, resulting in the rise of a new informational paradigm of government action including e-governance as well as the wider concepts of network governance and communicative governance. A more comprehensive 1 analysis of this development, however, requires an increased focus on the political logics the define the role of information and the use of media technology within the political system itself.
    [Show full text]
  • Nudging for Equality: Values in Libertarian Paternalism
    2_MCPHERSON_SMITH_MECOMPLETE 6/2/2009 11:45 PM NUDGING FOR EQUALITY: VALUES IN LIBERTARIAN PATERNALISM MATTHEW A. SMITH* MICHAEL S. MCPHERSON** TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction ............................................................................................... 323 I. Choice Architecture that Promotes Welfare ................................... 328 II. Choice Architecture that Promotes Values Other than Welfare ..... 330 A. Choice Architecture that Promotes Liberty ............................. 330 B. Choice Architecture that Promotes Equality ........................... 335 III. Which Values Should Choice Architecture Promote? .................... 339 Conclusion ................................................................................................. 341 INTRODUCTION In their recent book Nudge,1 Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein argue persuasively that default rules and framing effects affect people’s decisions and thus that default rules and framing effects should be designed to improve people’s welfare (where welfare is understood as their self-regarding interest).2 For example, if a medical procedure is described * Matthew A. Smith is a research associate at the Spencer Foundation in Chicago, Illinois, and is a graduate of Stanford University. ** Michael S. McPherson is the President of the Spencer Foundation in Chicago, Illinois, is the President Emeritus of Macalester College, and is the former Dean of Faculty and Professor of Economics at Williams College. He has been a Fellow of the Institute of Advanced Study
    [Show full text]