Autoregressive Unit Root

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Autoregressive Unit Root RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Lecture 11 Unit Roots and Cointegration Brooks (4th edition): Chapter 8 1 Spurious Regression • Suppose yt and xt are non-stationary, I(1). That is, we differentiate them and the changes become stationary, or I(0). We regress yt against xt: What happens? • The usual t-tests on regression coefficients can show statistically significant coefficients, even if in reality it is not so. • This the spurious regression problem (Granger and Newbold (1974)): We find a statistically significant relation between unrelated variables. • In a Spurious Regression contexts, the regression errors would be highly correlated and the standard t-statistic will be wrongly calculated because the variance of the errors is not consistently estimated. 1 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression – Simulated Example Example: We simulate two independent random walks (RW1,t, RW2,t) and then regress one against the other: RW1,t = μ + β RW2,t + εt, With test the true H0: β = 0. sim_rw1 <- arima.sim(list(order=c(0,1,0)), sd=.5, n=500) # simulate RW series 1 sim_rw2 <- arima.sim(list(order=c(0,1,0)), sd=.5, n=500) # simulate RW series 2 Spurious Regression – Simulated Example Example: fit_sim_rw <- lm(sim_rw1 ~ sim_rw2) # Regression of two RWs res_sim_rw <- fit_sim_rw$residuals # Extract residuals > summary(fit_sim_rw) Coefficients: Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(>|t|) (Intercept) -4.61541 0.13188 -35.00 <2e-16 *** sim_rw2 -0.47384 0.04076 -11.62 <2e-16 *** Reject H0: β = 0. --- Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1 Residual standard error: 2.356 on 499 degrees of freedom Multiple R-squared: 0.2131, Adjusted R-squared: 0.2115 F-statistic: 135.1 on 1 and 499 DF, p-value: < 2.2e-16 Note: Very significant t-value (& F-goodness of fit stat), and a good R2. But, the model makes no sense. 2 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression – Real Examples Examples: (1) Egyptian infant mortality rate (Y), 1971-1990, annual data, on Gross aggregate income of American farmers (I) and Total Honduran money supply (M): 2 Yt = 179.9 - .2952 It -.0439 Mt, R = .918, DW = .4752, F = 95.17 (16.63) (-2.32) (-4.26) Corr(Yt, Xi,t) = .8858, -.9113, -.9445 (2). US Export Index (Y), 1960-1990, annual data, on Australian males’ life expectancy (X): 2 Yt = -2943. + 45.7974 Xt, R = .916, DW = .3599, F = 315.2 (-16.70) (17.76) Corr(Yt, Xt) = .9570 (3) Total Crime Rates in the US (Y), 1971-1991, annual data, on Life expectancy of South Africa (X): 2 Yt = -24569 + 628.9 Xt, R = .811, DW = .5061, F = 81.72 (-6.03) (9.04) Corr(Yt, Xt) = .9008 Spurious Regression – Real Examples Examples (continuation): (2). US Export Index (Y), 1960-1990, annual data, on Australian males’ life expectancy (X): 2 Yt = -2943. + 45.7974 Xt, R = .916, DW = .3599, F = 315.2 (-16.70) (17.76) Corr(Yt , Xt) = .9570 Australian males’ life expectancy US Exports Note: It looks like the trend is the common element between Yt & Xt. 3 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression – Statistical Implications • Suppose yt and xt are unrelated I(1) variables. We run the regression: y t x t t • True value of β=0. The above is a spurious regression and εt ∼ I(1). • Technical points: Phillips (1986) derived the following results: - β → 0 & β → Non-normal RV not necessarily centered at 0. This is the spurious regression phenomenon. -The OLS t-statistics for testing H0: β=0 diverge to ±∞ as T → ∞. Thus, with a large enough T it will appear that β is significant. - The usual R2 → 1 as T → ∞. The model appears to have good fit well, even though it is a bad (nonsense) model. Spurious Regression – Detection and Solutions • Given the statistical implications, the typical symptoms are: -High R2, t-values, & F-values. -Low DW values. • Q: How do we detect a spurious regression (between I(1) series)? - Check the correlogram of the residuals. (Lecture 9.) - Test for a unit root on the residuals. (This lecture.) 4 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression – Detection and Solutions • Statistical solution: When series (yt & Xt) are I(1), work with first differences, instead: Δyt = yt –yt-1 & Δ Xt = Xt– Xt-1 If the relation between the series yt and Xt exists, should be the same in levels (yt, Xt) or first differences (Δyt, ΔXt). Levels: yt = Xt + εt (*) Lagged Levels: yt-1 = Xt-1 + εt-1 (**) Subtract (**) from (*): We have a regression with 1st differences: First Differences: Δyt = ΔXt + ut,where ut = εt - εt-1 Now, we have a valid regression, since both Δyt & ΔXt are I(0). But, the economic interpretation of the regression changes. Spurious Regression – Simulated Example Example: We regress the two RW in first differences: diff_rw1 <- diff(sim_rw1) # First differences for RW 1 diff_rw2 <- diff(sim_rw2) # First differences for RW 2 fit_diff_rw <- lm(diff_rw1 ~ diff_rw2) > summary(fit_diff_rw) Coefficients: Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(>|t|) (Intercept) -0.003199 0.023481 -0.136 0.8917 diff_rw2 0.106339 0.044773 2.375 0.0179 * Reject H0: β = 0. --- Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1 Residual standard error: 0.525 on 498 degrees of freedom Multiple R-squared: 0.0112, Adjusted R-squared: 0.009215 F-statistic: 5.641 on 1 and 498 DF, p-value: 0.01792 Note: Still significant (by chance), but the coefficient changes sign. Clear indication that something is wrong with regression. 5 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression – Remarks • The message from spurious regression: Regression of I(1) variables can produce nonsense. Q: Does it make sense a regression between two I(1) variables? Yes, only if the regression errors are I(0). That is, when the variables are cointegrated. I(1) Process – Autoregressive Unit Root • A shock is usually used to describe an unexpected change in a variable or in the value of the error terms at a particular time period. • When we have a stationary system, the effect of a shock will die out gradually. But, when we have a non-stationary system, the effect of a shock is permanent. • We have two types of non-stationarity. In an AR(1) model we have: yt = μ +1 yt-1 + εt. - Unit root: | 1 | = 1: homogeneous non-stationarity - Explosive root: | 1 | > 1: explosive non-stationarity • In the last case, a shock to the system become more influential as time goes on. It is not seen in real life. We will not consider them. 6 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 I(1) Process – Autoregressive Unit Root • Consider the AR(p) process: 1 2 p (L) yt t where (L) 11L L 2 .... p L As we discussed before, if one of the roots equals 1, Φ(1)=0, or 1 2 .... p 1 • We say yt has a unit root. In this case, yt is non-stationary. Example: AR(1): yt = μ +1 yt-1 + εt. Unit root: 1 = 1. H0 (yt non-stationarity): 1 = 1 (or, 1 –1 = 0) H1 (yt stationarity): 1 < 1 (or, 1 –1 < 0) • A t-test seems natural to test H0. But, the ergodic theorem & MDS CLT do not apply: the t-statistic does not have the usual distributions. Autoregressive Unit Root – Testing • Now, let’s reparameterize the AR(1) process. Subtract yt-1 from yt: yt -yt-1 = μ +1 yt-1 -yt-1 + εt. Δyt = μ + (1 –1) yt-1 + εt = μ + α0 yt-1 + εt • Unit root test: H0 (unit root process): α0 = 1 –1 = 0 H1(stationary process): α0 < 0. • Under H0 (unit root process): α0 = 0, the model is stationary in Δyt. Then, if yt has a unit root: Δyt = μ + εt. That is, Δyt is a stationary process with a drift and WN innovations. If we reject H0 (unit root): α0=0, then yt is a stationary AR(1) process: yt = μ + 1 yt-1 + εt. 7 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Autoregressive Unit Root – Testing • We have a linear regression framework: Δyt = μ + α0 yt-1+ εt. • The natural test for H0 (unit root process): α0 = 1 – 1 = 0: A t-test. ϕ 1 ϕ • We call this t-test the Dickey-Fuller (DF) test. • As mentioned above, under H0, the t-test does not have the usual t- distribution. We use a distribution tabulated (simulated) by DF. Autoregressive Unit Root – Testing • We derived the DF test from an AR(1) process for yt, but yt may follow a more general AR(p) process: (L)yt t We rewrite the process using the Dickey-Fuller reparameterization:: yt 0 yt1 1yt1 2yt2 .... p1yt( p1) t Note: Both AR(p) formulations are equivalent. • It can be shown that (1) = -α0. (Roots of (L)=0 equal to 1!) A unit root hypothesis can be stated, again, as H0: α0 = 0. H1: α0 < 0. • Like in the DF test, we have a linear regression framework. A t-test for H0 (unit root) is the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test. 8 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Autoregressive Unit Root – Testing: DF • The Dickey-Fuller (DF) test is a special case of the ADF: No lags are included in the regression. • From our previous AR(1) process, we have: y t 1 y t 1 t 0 y t 1 t • If α0 = 0, yt has a unit root: H0 :0 0 H1 :0 0 (|0 | 0) ˆ 1 • We can test H0 with a t-test: t 1 SE ˆ Note: There is another associated test with H0, the ρ-test: (T-1) (-1). Autoregressive Unit Root – Testing: DF • is not asymptotically normally distributed and tФ=1 is not asymptotically standard normal.
Recommended publications
  • Vector Error Correction Model, VECM Cointegrated VAR Chapter 4
    Vector error correction model, VECM Cointegrated VAR Chapter 4 Financial Econometrics Michael Hauser WS18/19 1 / 58 Content I Motivation: plausible economic relations I Model with I(1) variables: spurious regression, bivariate cointegration I Cointegration I Examples: unstable VAR(1), cointegrated VAR(1) I VECM, vector error correction model I Cointegrated VAR models, model structure, estimation, testing, forecasting (Johansen) I Bivariate cointegration 2 / 58 Motivation 3 / 58 Paths of Dow JC and DAX: 10/2009 - 10/2010 We observe a parallel development. Remarkably this pattern can be observed for single years at least since 1998, though both are assumed to be geometric random walks. They are non stationary, the log-series are I(1). If a linear combination of I(1) series is stationary, i.e. I(0), the series are called cointegrated. If 2 processes xt and yt are both I(1) and yt − αxt = t with t trend-stationary or simply I(0), then xt and yt are called cointegrated. 4 / 58 Cointegration in economics This concept origins in macroeconomics where series often seen as I(1) are regressed onto, like private consumption, C, and disposable income, Y d . Despite I(1), Y d and C cannot diverge too much in either direction: C > Y d or C Y d Or, according to the theory of competitive markets the profit rate of firms (profits/invested capital) (both I(1)) should converge to the market average over time. This means that profits should be proportional to the invested capital in the long run. 5 / 58 Common stochastic trend The idea of cointegration is that there is a common stochastic trend, an I(1) process Z , underlying two (or more) processes X and Y .
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 6A: Unit Root and ARIMA Models
    Lecture 6a: Unit Root and ARIMA Models 1 Big Picture • A time series is non-stationary if it contains a unit root unit root ) nonstationary The reverse is not true. • Many results of traditional statistical theory do not apply to unit root process, such as law of large number and central limit theory. • We will learn a formal test for the unit root • For unit root process, we need to apply ARIMA model; that is, we take difference (maybe several times) before applying the ARMA model. 2 Review: Deterministic Difference Equation • Consider the first order equation (without stochastic shock) yt = ϕ0 + ϕ1yt−1 • We can use the method of iteration to show that when ϕ1 = 1 the series is yt = ϕ0t + y0 • So there is no steady state; the series will be trending if ϕ0 =6 0; and the initial value has permanent effect. 3 Unit Root Process • Consider the AR(1) process yt = ϕ0 + ϕ1yt−1 + ut where ut may and may not be white noise. We assume ut is a zero-mean stationary ARMA process. • This process has unit root if ϕ1 = 1 In that case the series converges to yt = ϕ0t + y0 + (ut + u2 + ::: + ut) (1) 4 Remarks • The ϕ0t term implies that the series will be trending if ϕ0 =6 0: • The series is not mean-reverting. Actually, the mean changes over time (assuming y0 = 0): E(yt) = ϕ0t • The series has non-constant variance var(yt) = var(ut + u2 + ::: + ut); which is a function of t: • In short, the unit root process is not stationary.
    [Show full text]
  • Econometrics Basics: Avoiding Spurious Regression
    Econometrics Basics: Avoiding Spurious Regression John E. Floyd University of Toronto July 24, 2013 We deal here with the problem of spurious regression and the techniques for recognizing and avoiding it. The nature of this problem can be best understood by constructing a few purely random-walk variables and then regressing one of them on the others. The figure below plots a random walk or unit root variable that can be represented by the equation yt = ρ yt−1 + ϵt (1) which can be written alternatively in Dickey-Fuller form as ∆yt = − (1 − ρ) yt−1 + ϵt (2) where yt is the level of the series at time t , ϵt is a series of drawings of a zero-mean, constant-variance normal random variable, and (1 − ρ) can be viewed as the mean-reversion parameter. If ρ = 1 , there is no mean-reversion and yt is a random walk. Notice that, apart from the short-term variations, the series trends upward for the first quarter of its length, then downward for a bit more than the next quarter and upward for the remainder of its length. This series will tend to be correlated with other series that move in either the same or the oppo- site directions during similar parts of their length. And if our series above is regressed on several other random-walk-series regressors, one can imagine that some or even all of those regressors will turn out to be statistically sig- nificant even though by construction there is no causal relationship between them|those parts of the dependent variable that are not correlated directly with a particular independent variable may well be correlated with it when the correlation with other independent variables is simultaneously taken into account.
    [Show full text]
  • VAR, SVAR and VECM Models
    VAR, SVAR and VECM models Christopher F Baum EC 823: Applied Econometrics Boston College, Spring 2013 Christopher F Baum (BC / DIW) VAR, SVAR and VECM models Boston College, Spring 2013 1 / 61 Vector autoregressive models Vector autoregressive (VAR) models A p-th order vector autoregression, or VAR(p), with exogenous variables x can be written as: yt = v + A1yt−1 + ··· + Apyt−p + B0xt + B1Bt−1 + ··· + Bsxt−s + ut where yt is a vector of K variables, each modeled as function of p lags of those variables and, optionally, a set of exogenous variables xt . 0 0 We assume that E(ut ) = 0; E(ut ut ) = Σ and E(ut us) = 0 8t 6= s. Christopher F Baum (BC / DIW) VAR, SVAR and VECM models Boston College, Spring 2013 2 / 61 Vector autoregressive models If the VAR is stable (see command varstable) we can rewrite the VAR in moving average form as: 1 1 X X yt = µ + Di xt−i + Φi ut−i i=0 i=0 which is the vector moving average (VMA) representation of the VAR, where all past values of yt have been substituted out. The Di matrices are the dynamic multiplier functions, or transfer functions. The sequence of moving average coefficients Φi are the simple impulse-response functions (IRFs) at horizon i. Christopher F Baum (BC / DIW) VAR, SVAR and VECM models Boston College, Spring 2013 3 / 61 Vector autoregressive models Estimation of the parameters of the VAR requires that the variables in yt and xt are covariance stationary, with their first two moments finite and time-invariant.
    [Show full text]
  • Commodity Prices and Unit Root Tests
    Commodity Prices and Unit Root Tests Dabin Wang and William G. Tomek Paper presented at the NCR-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk Management St. Louis, Missouri, April 19-20, 2004 Copyright 2004 by Dabin Wang and William G. Tomek. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies. Graduate student and Professor Emeritus in the Department of Applied Economics and Management at Cornell University. Warren Hall, Ithaca NY 14853-7801 e-mails: [email protected] and [email protected] Commodity Prices and Unit Root Tests Abstract Endogenous variables in structural models of agricultural commodity markets are typically treated as stationary. Yet, tests for unit roots have rather frequently implied that commodity prices are not stationary. This seeming inconsistency is investigated by focusing on alternative specifications of unit root tests. We apply various specifications to Illinois farm prices of corn, soybeans, barrows and gilts, and milk for the 1960 through 2002 time span. The preponderance of the evidence suggests that nominal prices do not have unit roots, but under certain specifications, the null hypothesis of a unit root cannot be rejected, particularly when the logarithms of prices are used. If the test specification does not account for a structural change that shifts the mean of the variable, the results are biased toward concluding that a unit root exists. In general, the evidence does not favor the existence of unit roots. Keywords: commodity price, unit root tests.
    [Show full text]
  • Error Correction Model
    ERROR CORRECTION MODEL Yule (1936) and Granger and Newbold (1974) were the first to draw attention to the problem of false correlations and find solutions about how to overcome them in time series analysis. Providing two time series that are completely unrelated but integrated (not stationary), regression analysis with each other will tend to produce relationships that appear to be statistically significant and a researcher might think he has found evidence of a correct relationship between these variables. Ordinary least squares are no longer consistent and the test statistics commonly used are invalid. Specifically, the Monte Carlo simulation shows that one will get very high t-squared R statistics, very high and low Durbin- Watson statistics. Technically, Phillips (1986) proves that parameter estimates will not converge in probability, intercepts will diverge and slope will have a distribution that does not decline when the sample size increases. However, there may be a general stochastic tendency for both series that a researcher is really interested in because it reflects the long-term relationship between these variables. Because of the stochastic nature of trends, it is not possible to break integrated series into deterministic trends (predictable) and stationary series that contain deviations from trends. Even in a random walk detrended detrended random correlation will finally appear. So detrending doesn't solve the estimation problem. To keep using the Box-Jenkins approach, one can differentiate series and then estimate models such as ARIMA, given that many of the time series that are commonly used (eg in economics) seem stationary in the first difference. Forecasts from such models will still reflect the cycles and seasonality in the data.
    [Show full text]
  • Don't Jettison the General Error Correction Model Just
    RAP0010.1177/2053168016643345Research & PoliticsEnns et al. 643345research-article2016 Research Article Research and Politics April-June 2016: 1 –13 Don’t jettison the general error correction © The Author(s) 2016 DOI: 10.1177/2053168016643345 model just yet: A practical guide to rap.sagepub.com avoiding spurious regression with the GECM Peter K. Enns1, Nathan J. Kelly2, Takaaki Masaki3 and Patrick C. Wohlfarth4 Abstract In a recent issue of Political Analysis, Grant and Lebo authored two articles that forcefully argue against the use of the general error correction model (GECM) in nearly all time series applications of political data. We reconsider Grant and Lebo’s simulation results based on five common time series data scenarios. We show that Grant and Lebo’s simulations (as well as our own additional simulations) suggest the GECM performs quite well across these five data scenarios common in political science. The evidence shows that the problems Grant and Lebo highlight are almost exclusively the result of either incorrect applications of the GECM or the incorrect interpretation of results. Based on the prevailing evidence, we contend the GECM will often be a suitable model choice if implemented properly, and we offer practical advice on its use in applied settings. Keywords time series, ecm, error correction model, spurious regression, methodology, Monte Carlo simulations In a recent issue of Political Analysis, Taylor Grant and Grant and Lebo identify two primary concerns with the Matthew Lebo author the lead and concluding articles of a GECM. First, when time series are stationary, the GECM symposium on time series analysis. These two articles cannot be used as a test of cointegration.
    [Show full text]
  • Unit Roots and Cointegration in Panels Jörg Breitung M
    Unit roots and cointegration in panels Jörg Breitung (University of Bonn and Deutsche Bundesbank) M. Hashem Pesaran (Cambridge University) Discussion Paper Series 1: Economic Studies No 42/2005 Discussion Papers represent the authors’ personal opinions and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or its staff. Editorial Board: Heinz Herrmann Thilo Liebig Karl-Heinz Tödter Deutsche Bundesbank, Wilhelm-Epstein-Strasse 14, 60431 Frankfurt am Main, Postfach 10 06 02, 60006 Frankfurt am Main Tel +49 69 9566-1 Telex within Germany 41227, telex from abroad 414431, fax +49 69 5601071 Please address all orders in writing to: Deutsche Bundesbank, Press and Public Relations Division, at the above address or via fax +49 69 9566-3077 Reproduction permitted only if source is stated. ISBN 3–86558–105–6 Abstract: This paper provides a review of the literature on unit roots and cointegration in panels where the time dimension (T ), and the cross section dimension (N) are relatively large. It distinguishes between the ¯rst generation tests developed on the assumption of the cross section independence, and the second generation tests that allow, in a variety of forms and degrees, the dependence that might prevail across the di®erent units in the panel. In the analysis of cointegration the hypothesis testing and estimation problems are further complicated by the possibility of cross section cointegration which could arise if the unit roots in the di®erent cross section units are due to common random walk components. JEL Classi¯cation: C12, C15, C22, C23. Keywords: Panel Unit Roots, Panel Cointegration, Cross Section Dependence, Common E®ects Nontechnical Summary This paper provides a review of the theoretical literature on testing for unit roots and cointegration in panels where the time dimension (T ), and the cross section dimension (N) are relatively large.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 18 Cointegration
    RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Lecture 18 Cointegration 1 Spurious Regression • Suppose yt and xt are I(1). We regress yt against xt. What happens? • The usual t-tests on regression coefficients can show statistically significant coefficients, even if in reality it is not so. • This the spurious regression problem (Granger and Newbold (1974)). • In a Spurious Regression the errors would be correlated and the standard t-statistic will be wrongly calculated because the variance of the errors is not consistently estimated. Note: This problem can also appear with I(0) series –see, Granger, Hyung and Jeon (1998). 1 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression - Examples Examples: (1) Egyptian infant mortality rate (Y), 1971-1990, annual data, on Gross aggregate income of American farmers (I) and Total Honduran money supply (M) ŷ = 179.9 - .2952 I - .0439 M, R2 = .918, DW = .4752, F = 95.17 (16.63) (-2.32) (-4.26) Corr = .8858, -.9113, -.9445 (2). US Export Index (Y), 1960-1990, annual data, on Australian males’ life expectancy (X) ŷ = -2943. + 45.7974 X, R2 = .916, DW = .3599, F = 315.2 (-16.70) (17.76) Corr = .9570 (3) Total Crime Rates in the US (Y), 1971-1991, annual data, on Life expectancy of South Africa (X) ŷ = -24569 + 628.9 X, R2 = .811, DW = .5061, F = 81.72 (-6.03) (9.04) Corr = .9008 Spurious Regression - Statistical Implications • Suppose yt and xt are unrelated I(1) variables. We run the regression: y t x t t • True value of β=0. The above is a spurious regression and et ∼ I(1).
    [Show full text]
  • Testing for Unit Root in Macroeconomic Time Series of China
    Testing for Unit Root in Macroeconomic Time Series of China Xiankun Gai Shan Dong Province Statistical Bureau Quan Cheng Road 221 Ji Nan, China [email protected];[email protected] 1. Introduction and procedures The immense literature and diversity of unit root tests can at times be confusing even to the specialist and presents a truly daunting prospect to the uninitiated. In order to test unit root in macroeconomic time series of China, we have examined the unit root throry with an emphasis on testing principles and recent developments. Unit root tests are important in examining the stationarity of a time series. Stationarity is a matter of concern in three important areas. First, a crucial question in the ARIMA modelling of a single time series is the number of times the series needs to be first differenced before an ARMA model is fit. Each unit root requires a differencing operation. Second, stationarity of regressors is assumed in the derivation of standard inference procedures for regression models. Nonstationary regressors invalidate many standard results and require special treatment. Third, in cointegration analysis, an important question is whether the disturbance term in the cointegrating vector has a unit root. Consider a time series data as a data generating process(DGP) incorporated with trend, cycle, and seasonality. By removing these deteriministic patterns, the remaining DGP must be stationry. “Spurious” regression with a high R-square but near-zero Durbin-Watson statistic, often found in time series litreature, are mainly due to the use of nonstationary data series. Given a time series DGP, testing for random walk is a test for stationary.
    [Show full text]
  • Estimation of Vector Error Correction Model with Garch Errors: Monte Carlo Simulation and Application
    ESTIMATION OF VECTOR ERROR CORRECTION MODEL WITH GARCH ERRORS: MONTE CARLO SIMULATION AND APPLICATION Koichi Maekawa* Hiroshima University of Economics [email protected] Kusdhianto Setiawan# Faculty of Economics and Business Universitas Gadjah Mada [email protected] ABSTRACT The standard vector error correction (VEC) model assumes the iid normal distribution of disturbance term in the model. This paper extends this assumption to include GARCH process. We call this model as VEC-GARCH model. However as the number of parameters in a VEC-GARCH model is large, the maximum likelihood (ML) method is computationally demanding. To overcome these computational difficulties, this paper searches for alternative estimation methods and compares them by Monte Carlo simulation. As a result a feasible generalized least square (FGLS) estimator shows comparable performance to ML estimator. Furthermore an empirical study is presented to see the applicability of the FGLS. Presented on INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE ON ECONOMIC MODELING – ECOMOD 2014 Bali, July 16-18, 2014 This manuscript consists of two parts. On Part I we developed the estimation method and on Part II we applied the new method for testing international CAPM. (*) the author of part I of this manuscript (#) the co-author of part I and author of part II of this manuscript, presenter of the paper in the conference PART I ESTIMATION METHOD DEVELOPMENT 1. INTRODUCTION Vector Error correction (VEC) model is often used in econometric analysis and estimated by maximum likelihood (ML) method under the normality assumption. ML estimator is known as the most efficient estimator under the iid normality assumption. However there are disadvantages such that the normality assumption is often violated in real date, especially in financial time series, and that ML estimation is computationally demanding for a large model.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes on Time Series
    Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Time Series Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2013 1 What is a Time Series? A time series is a realization of a sequence of a variable indexed by time. The notation we will use to denote this is xt; t = 1; 2;:::;T . A variable is said to be \random" if its realizations are stochastic. Unlike cross-sectional data, time series data can typically not be modeled as independent across observations (i.e. independent across time). Rather, time series are persistent in the sense that observations of random variables are typically positively correlated across time. Most of what we do in macro involves variables with such dependence across time. Before discussing the unique issues presented by time series data, we quickly review expectations and first and second moments. 2 Expectations The expected value of xt is denoted by E(xt) and is the weighted average of possible realizations of xt. Denote the set of possible realizations by Ωx, and the probability density function of x as p(x). Essentially the expected value is just possible realizations times the probability of each realization. X E(xt) = xp(x) (1) x2Ωx This is a linear operator. As such, it has the following properties, where a is a constant: E(a) = a (2) E(axt) = aE(xt) (3) E(xt + yt) = E(xt) + E(yt) (4) Non-linear operators cannot \go through" an expectation operator: 1 E(xtyt) 6= E(xt)E(yt) (5) E(g(xt)) 6= g(E(xt)) (6) We are often interested in conditional expectations, which are expectations taken conditional on some information.
    [Show full text]