Dmacomb 5..23

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Dmacomb 5..23 Contents List of Figures vii List of Tables ix Notes on the Contributors xii Introductory Comments, De®nitions, and Research on Indexes of Monetary Services Michael T. Belongia 1 Part I New Results in Theory and Practice 1 Beyond the Risk-neutral Utility Function William A. Barnett and Yi Liu 11 2 Neural Networks with Divisia Money: Better Forecasts of Future In¯ation? Robert E. Dorsey 28 Part II Evidence from European Economies and the Planned EMU Area 3 Weighted Monetary Aggregates for the UK Leigh Drake, K. Alec Chrystal and Jane M. Binner 47 4 Weighted Monetary Aggregates for Germany Heinz Herrmann, Hans-Eggert Reimers and Karl-Heinz Toedter 79 5 Simple-sum versus Divisia Money in Switzerland: Some Empirical Results Robert Fluri and Erich Spoerndli 102 6 Weighted Dutch and German Monetary Aggregates: How Do They Perform as Monetary Indicators for the Netherlands? Norbert G. J. Janssen and Clemens J. M. Kool 120 7 Divisia Aggregates and the Demand for Money in Core EMU Martin M. G. Fase 138 Part III Evidence from the Paci®c Basin 8 Broad and Narrow Divisia Monetary Aggregates for Japan Kazuhiko Ishida and Koji Nakamura 173 v vi Contents 9 The Signals from Divisia Money in a Rapidly Growing Economy Jeong Ho Hahm and Jun Tae Kim 200 10 Divisia Monetary Aggregates for Taiwan Yen Chrystal Shih 227 11 Weighted Monetary Aggregates: Empirical Evidence for Australia G. C. Lim and Vance L. Martin 249 Part IV Evidence from North America 263 12 The Canadian Experience with Weighted Monetary Aggregates David Longworth and Joseph Atta-Mensah 265 13 Consequences of Money Stock Mismeasurement: Evidence from Three Countries Michael T. Belongia 292 Index 313 Introductory Comments, De®nitions, and Research on Indexes of Monetary Services Michael T. Belongia With apologies to Mark Twain, reporting practices of modern central banks beg the expression, `Lies, damned lies, and monetarydata .' Although demonstrably wrong in their construction, simple-sum measures of the money stock continue to be the of®cial data published by central banks and are used to guide policy decisions if monetary quantity variables are part of that process. Moreover, whether by tradition or ease of access, academic research also persists in using simple-sum monetary aggregates to test hypotheses about the effects of money on economic activity. In fairness to all involved, however, the conventional wisdom changes slowly. Indeed, less than thirty years have passed since Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, in MonetaryStatistics of the United States (1970) ended their discussion of the potential usefulness of weighted aggregates by concluding that, `So far there is only the barest beginning of an answer [of how to do it properly]' p. 152. Indeed, just prior to the publication of Friedman and Schwartz's book, two papers in the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review were dramatic in that they called attention to money at all ± the now-famous study by Leonall Andersen and Jerry Jordan (1968) reporting a primary linkage between money and nominal spending (and the ineffective- ness of ®scal actions), and Karl Brunner's (1968) introduction of the term `monetarism', with a summary of its main principles. In some senses, these papers also marked the mid-point of a sweeping change in orthodox economics. Only nine years earlier, a paper by Brunner and Anatol B. Balbach presented evidence on money and economic activity that, in many ways, was more compelling than that of the Andersen±Jordan study. Disregarded by attendees of the Western Economic Association meetings of 1959, this paper is virtually unknown today. By 1979, however, arguments and evidence that could have been drawn directly from Brunner and Balbach were the basis of a fundamentally new focus for monetary policy: Most of the world's major central banks adopted monetary aggregate targeting in their efforts to control an accelerating rate of in¯ation. In view of this history, it is perhaps not 1 2 Introduction surprising that superlative indexes of the money stock are going through a typical gestation period prior to their broad acceptance. And, while new ideas are accepted slowly, it can also be said that no debate in economics is really `new'. From the ®rst discussions of the Equation of Exchange, economists knew that ®nding a measure for `M' was of central importance to empirical work. Schumpeter's (1954) Historyof Economic Analysis, for example, cites numerous views on the de®nition of money from both European and American perspectives over the period 1870±1911. Still, by the early 1930s, Lauchlin Currie was compelled to create his own money supply data to test the hypothesis that restrictive money growth caused the Great Depression. Why? As he put it at the time: It is a rather startling conclusion that the growth of money under the Federal Reserve System has been largely a matter of accident or, at best, an incidental by-product of the system's other policies. In this connection it is highly signi®cant that while an enormous mass of statistical data is available on the composition of member bank assets, there does not exist in any of the system's publications, so far as I am aware, a series of money.1 It was not until 1948 however, that monetary data for the USA were published by the Federal Reserve Board. It also is notable that those initial data were not revised and improved at the Board, but rather were guided by work by William Abbott under the direction of Homer Jones at St Louis. To many, all this Sturm und Drang produced one of the greater ironies in the history of economic thought: after two decades of effort to get the data reported, to convince people that money mattered, and to push central banks towards the adoption of monetary aggregates as intermediate targets ± everything went wrong. Previously stable velocity functions shifted quickly and erratically. The strong connection between money growth and in¯ation all but disappeared. Wildly alarmist warnings of a resurgent in¯ation were embarrassingly wrong. The role of a quantity variable in implementing monetary policy was discredited. Some observers have interpreted the events since 1980 as a clear repudiation of using monetary quantity variables for the conduct of policy. Others have remained steadfast in their belief that money has potent effects on economic activity, but admit that the published quantity data are erroneous indicators of what the central bank is doing. Still another group has focused on the possibility that fundamental problems of measurement may be responsible for the recent monetary turmoil. This volume is directed to providing empirical evidence on this last proposition. Progress on monetary measurement since 1970 After Friedman and Schwartz concluded that weighted monetary aggregates had intuitive appeal but were, as yet, not well de®ned in theory, a solution to Michael T. Belongia 3 the problem developed rather quickly. Using Erwin Diewert's (1976, 1978) results on aggregation and index number theory, William Barnett (1978) derived a measure of `prices' (user costs) for the ¯ow of monetary services from a stock of monetary assets. With these prices and the readily-available quantity data for monetary asset stocks, Barnett (1980) then applied an index from Diewert's class of superlative indexes ± the Divisia ± to create weighted monetary aggregates for the USA.2 The principles behind his new measures and a step-by-step guide to their construction were discussed at greater length in Barnett (1982). Although alternative superlative indexes could serve the same purpose, Barnett's careful and thorough examination of the Divisia index led to its adoption in most applications of weighted monetary aggregates.3 De®nitions of common concepts To avoid redundancies across papers in this book, some common de®nitions are provided here for general reference. Unless speci®cally noted otherwise in an individual chapter, the expressions below are those employed in each study. For greater detail on technical issues associated with adjusting data to match these general expressions, the reader is referred to Farr and Johnson (1985), Dietrich and Kliesen (1992), and the country-speci®c documentation in the individual chapters. A Divisia index of monetary service ¯ows is expressed as: Pk à à ÁlnDivMt 0:5 sit si;tÀ1 Álnqit , where sit is the share of total i1 th expenditures on monetary services allocated to the i asset at time t and qit is the quantity of balances in the ith asset category. The expenditure shares are Pk à à de®ned as: sit uit qit = uit qit , where uit is the user cost (rental price) of the i1 th à i asset. Nominal user costs are determined as uit {(Rt À rit )} / (1 Rt )} Pt , where Rt is the rate of return on a benchmark asset, rit is the own-rate of return th to the i asset and Pt is a cost-of-living index. The marginal tax rate also is included in Barnett's (1978) original derivation but, in the absence of a consistent time series for this concept (at least in the USA), it has been omitted in most subsequent studies.4 With the rit and qit readily-observable from market data and the use of the CPI or the GDP De¯ator as a proxy for Pt , treatment of Rt has been the major consideration of many researchers attempting to construct Divisia indexes.5 Indeed, of the three most frequent criticisms of Divisia monetary aggregates, discussions of the benchmark return have been among the most persistent.6 As the return on a completely illiquid asset (one that is incapable of producing any monetary services), Rt should be something akin to the rate of return on human capital in a world without slavery.
Recommended publications
  • Culture and Materialism : Raymond Williams and the Marxist Debate
    CULTURE AND MATERIALISM: RAYMOND WILLIAMS AND THE MARXIST DEBATE by David C. Robinson B.A. (Honours1, Queen's University, 1988 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS (COMMUNICATIONS) in the ,Department of Communication @ David C. Robinson 1991 SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY July, 1991 All rights reserved. This work may not be reproduced in whole or in part, by photocopy or other means, without permission of the author. APPROVAL NAME: David Robinson DEGREE: Master of Arts (Communication) TITLE OF THESIS: Culture and Materialism: Raymond Williams and the Marxist Debate EXAMINING COMMITTEE: CHAIR: Dr. Linda Harasim Dr. Richard S. Gruneau Professor Senior Supervisor Dr. Alison C. M. Beale Assistant Professor Supervisor " - Dr. Jerald Zaslove Associate Professor Department of English Examiner DATE APPROVED: PARTIAL COPYRIGHT LICENCE I hereby grant to Simon Fraser University the right to lend my thesis or dissertation (the title of which is shown below) to users of the Simon Fraser University Library, and to make partial or single copies only for such users or in response to a request from the library of any other university, or other educational institution, on its own behalf or for one of its users. I further agree that permission for multiple copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by me or the Dean of Graduate Studies. It is understood that copying or publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission. Title of Thesis/Dissertation: Culture and Materialism: Raymond Williams and the Marxist Debate Author : signature David C.
    [Show full text]
  • Getting It Wrong
    Getting It Wrong Getting It Wrong How Faulty Monetary Statistics Undermine the Fed, the Financial System, and the Economy William A. Barnett The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England © 2012 Massachusetts Institute of Technology All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher. MIT Press books may be purchased at special quantity discounts for business or sales promotional use. For information, please email [email protected] or write to Special Sales Department, The MIT Press, 55 Hayward Street, Cambridge, MA 02142. This book was set in Palatino by Graphic Composition, Inc., Bogart, GA. Printed and bound in the United States of America. Library of Congress Cataloging- in- Publication Data Barnett, William A. Getting it wrong : how faulty monetary statistics undermine the Fed, the financial system, and the economy / William A. Barnett ; foreword by Apostolos Serletis. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978- 0- 262- 01691- 9 (hbk. : alk. paper) — ISBN 978- 0- 262- 51688- 4 (pbk. : alk. paper) 1. Monetary policy—United States. 2. Finance—Mathematical models. 3. Financial crises. 4. Econometrics. 5. United States—Economic policy—2009– I. Title. HB139.B3755 2012 332.401'5195—dc23 2011021050 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Dedicated to the memory of the great econometrician, Henri Theil, 1924–2000 Contents Foreword: Macroeconomics
    [Show full text]
  • Theology, Economics, and Economic Development
    Theology, Economics, and Economic Development Peter N. Ireland* Boston College November 2010 Nothing to me the life of Gyges and his glut of gold. I neither envy nor admire him, as I watch his life and what he does. I want no pride of tyranny; it lies far off from where I look. Archilochus of Paros1 Introduction In my work as an economist, I rarely consider what anyone might call the “big picture.” Instead, my research focuses on very specific aspects of very specific problems, most having to do with the details of Federal Reserve policy and how it has affected the United States economy during the post-World War II period. It deals, that is, with the activities of one particular government agency within one particular country during one particular historical episode. And since economists are social scientists who, for the most part, lack the ability to conduct controlled experiments, I spend most of my time collecting and analyzing statistically data in attempts to find support for ceteris paribus theoretical arguments based on actual events in which the ceteris are definitely not paribus.2 Implications, conclusions, and recommendations must therefore be * I would like to thank participants in Boston College’s Seminar on Catholic Intellectual Traditions for numerous conversations that helped clarify my thoughts on these and many related issues. Please address correspondence to: Peter N. Ireland, Boston College, Department of Economics, 140 Commonwealth Avenue, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467-­‐3859. Tel: (617) Greek 552 Lyrics-­‐3687. Fax: (617) -­‐ 552 2308. Email: [email protected]. 1http://www2.bc.edu/~irelandp.
    [Show full text]
  • Heterodox Economics Newsletter Issue 209 — February 13, 2017 — Web1 — Pdf2 — Heterodox Economics Directory3
    Heterodox Economics Newsletter Issue 209 — February 13, 2017 — web1 — pdf2 — Heterodox Economics Directory3 ”What I am worried about most of all, is what we don’t see. So, I am worried about the analysis that is never seen, that never becomes a paper and it doesn’t become a paper, because it can’t become a paper. And it can’t become a paper, because that’s not what a paper in economics is all about. I am quite worried about and we know such vacuums exist.” These wise words resemble a sentiment familiar to many heterodox economists as they give a shallow description of the paradigmatic constraints encountered within the eco- nomics discipline. However, they are taken from a statement by George A. Akerlof, which he happened to give at the recent ASSA-convention in Chicago. Specifically, Ak- erlof took part in a session comprised of leading mainstream ”active senior scholars” (quoting James Heckman’s introduction) discussing the ”curse of the top 5”, that is, the dominance of a set of five leading mainstream journals (QJE, JPE, AER, Econometrica and Review of Econ Studies) in terms of prestige and intellectual recognition (you can watch it here4 ). For once, this statement and the associated session indicate that there is still some reflexivity within the dominant economic approach - even if embracing this kind of reflexivity seems restricted to ”Bank of Sweden”-prize winners. Although there is, of course, no direct reference to heterodox or pluralist economics and no mentioning of the history of economic thought, most participants show a honest concern for the narrowing impact of the incentive structure within the discipline, which is reinforced by the general trends for metric-based evaluation in scientific institutions.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle Since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today
    Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today Hylton Hollander∗ and Lars Christenseny May 23, 2017 Preliminary Draft Abstract To justify the operational procedures of central banks since the 2008 global financial crisis, reputable academics and practitioners proclaim the independence of interest rate policy from all things monetary. This policy debate can be traced as far back as Thorn- ton (1802), Pigou(1917), Tinbergen(1939, 1951), and Poole(1970). Central to this debate is the effect of the choice by the monetary authority between reserves and in- terest rate manipulation. Using U.S. data spanning 50 years, we estimate a dynamic general equilibrium model and show that the type of monetary policy regime has sig- nificant implications for the role of monetary aggregates and interest rate policy on the U.S. business cycle. The interaction between money supply and demand and the type of monetary regime in our model does remarkably well to capture the dynamics of the U.S. business cycle. The results suggest that the evolution toward a stricter interest rate targeting regime renders central bank balance sheet expansions superfluous. In the context of the 2007−09 global financial crisis, a more flexible interest rate targeting regime would have led to a significant monetary expansion and more rapid economic recovery in the U.S. JEL codes: E32, E41, E42, E52, E58, N12 Keywords: monetary regimes, monetary policy, money demand, US business cycle ∗Corresponding author: Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University, Stellenbosch, 7602, South Africa. E-mail address: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • An Interview with William A. Barnett
    CENTER FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY . An Interview with William A. Barnett By Apostolos Serletis 1120 Avenue of the Americas, 4th Floor New York, NY 10036 T 212.626.2660 www.centerforfinancialstability.org -0- CENTER FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY NEW YORK An Interview with William A. Barnett By Apostolos Serletis University of Calgary February, 2017 Copyright 2017 by Center for Financial Stability. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced or transmitted without the author’s written permission. Layout by Kurt Schuler and Lauren Cooper Published 2017 by the Center for Financial Stability 1120 Avenue of the Americas, 4th Floor, New York, NY 10036 http://www.centerforfinancialstability.org Keywords: Divisia monetary aggregates, Minflex Laurent model, Generalized Barnett model, Asymptotically Ideal Model (AIM), bifurcation, chaos and nonlinear dynamics. The Center for Financial Stability (CFS) is a private, nonprofit institution focusing on global finance and markets. Its research is nonpartisan. This publication reflects the judgments and recommendations of the author(s). They do not necessarily represent the views of members of the Advisory Board or Trustees, whose involvement in no way should be interpreted as an endorsement of the report by either themselves or the organizations with which they are affiliated. Table of Contents About William A. Barnett…………………………………………………………..….......………....p. 1 1. Work before Economics…………………………..……………...……………….....…….…...…..p. 4 2. Graduate Study……………………………………...……………………..……..…………….….p. 5 3. Early Research at the Federal Reserve Board……………………………………….......………p. 8 4. Monetary and Financial Aggregation……..………………………………………..…………...p. 13 5. Demand Systems and Flexible Functional Forms……............................................…..……….p. 18 6. Nonlinear and Complex Dynamics………………………..………………….…..……………..p. 23 7. Founding of Journals, Monograph Series, and Societies……………………………………....p.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol
    Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 2 pp. 1101-1115 1. Introduction The mainstream approach to monetary policy in the last thirty years is focusing on short term interest rates and downplays the significant role of monetary aggregates. The reason for the abandonment of monetary aggregates was not theoretical but empirical: the established link between money and inflation was severed in recent decades when capital and financial markets’ innovation produced new interest bearing assets that rendered monetary aggregates inaccurate and less relevant. These empirical findings put money and its growth rate in the backstage of empirical macroeconomic forecasting. The failure of money to forecast macroeconomic variables though may be explained by the “Barnett critique”1: the use so far, by central banks and economists in general, of the traditional simple-sum monetary aggregates. Barnett (1997) linked the deserved decline in the policy-importance of monetary aggregates to the specific restrictions of simple sum aggregation: the various monetary components are assigned an equal and intertemporally constant weight. Central banks facing inaccuracies and paradoxes using simple-sum aggregates as their key policy variable, abandoned money all together. Barnett (1978, 1980) developed and advocates the use of the theoretically correct in terms of economic aggregation and index number theory Divisia2 monetary aggregates. The simple sum aggregation method used widely by central banks, economists and investors even today, has been criticized heavily in the literature since Fisher (1922), Moroney and Wilbratte (1976), the seminal paper of Barnett (1980) and also Barnett (1997), Boughton (1981), Batten and Thornton (1985), Fisher and Fleissig (1995), Schunk (2001), Darrat et al.
    [Show full text]
  • Bifurcation of Macroeconometric Models and Robustness of Dynamical Inferences
    SAE./No.32/April 2015 Studies in Applied Economics Bifurcation of MacroeconoMetric Models and roBustness of dynaMical inferences William A. Barnett and Guo Chen Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and Study of Business Enterprise !Bifurcation!of!Macroeconometric!Models!and!Robustness!of!Dynamical!Inferences! William!A.!Barnett!! University!of!Kansas,!Lawrence,!and!Center!for!Financial!Stability,!New!York!City! Guo!Chen!! University!of!Kansas,!Lawrence,!Kansas! April!20,!2015! ! About!the!Series! The!Studies(in(Applied(Economics!series!is!under!the!general!direction!of!Prof.!Steve!H.!Hanke,!CoMDirector!of! the!Institute!for!Applied!Economics,!Global!Health!and!the!Study!of!Business!Enterprise!([email protected]).!! ! About!the!Authors! Dr.!William!A.!Barnett!([email protected])!is!an!eminent!economic!scientist!and!originator!of!the! Divisia!monetary!aggregates!and!the!“Barnett!Critique.”!He!is!Oswald!Distinguished!Professor!of! Macroeconomics!at!the!University!of!Kansas!Department!of!Economics!and!Core!Faculty!Member!of!the! Center!for!Global!and!International!Studies!at!the!University!of!Kansas,!as!well!as!Senior!Fellow!of!the!IC2! Institute!at!the!University!of!Texas!at!Austin!and!Fellow!of!the!Institute!for!Applied!Economics!at!Johns! Hopkins!University.!He!is!Founder!and!Editor!of!the!Cambridge!University!Press!journal,!Macroeconomic( Dynamics,!and!Founder!and!Editor!of!the!Emerald!Press!monograph!series,!International(Symposia(in( Economic(Theory(and(Econometrics.!Dr.!Barnett!recently!founded!the!Society!for!Economic!Measurement!and!
    [Show full text]
  • Supplementary Appendix: Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle Since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today
    Supplementary Appendix: Monetary Regimes, Money Supply and the US Business Cycle since 1959: Implications for Monetary Policy Today Hylton Hollander∗ and Lars Christenseny August 8, 2018 ∗Corresponding author: Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University, Stellenbosch, 7602, South Africa. E-mail address: [email protected]. yResearch Associate, Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University. Founder and owner of Markets and Money Advisory. Senior Fellow at London's Adam Smith Institute. 1 A Implications of the `liquidity trap' hypothesis and the FTPL In the current economic state of low interest rates and ineffective monetary policy some notable hypotheses have gained traction. One strand of literature, in particular, posits a theory of price level determination based on the interaction between fiscal policy and monetary policy. Cochrane (2014) and Leeper(2016) form the argument by identifying three basic approaches to monetary policy and price level determination: money supply and demand in the spirit of the monetarist MV≡PY tradition; interest-rate controlling New-Keynesian models; and the fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL). Their important critique, as previously raised by Sargent and Wallace(1985), is that the economy is satiated with money when the return on money (or reserves) equals the return on risk-free assets (e.g., Treasury bills). That is, any amount of money will be held at this point, and exchanging treasuries for money has no effect on the economy|the price level is therefore indeterminant. In response to this state of the world, Cochrane(2014) and Leeper(2016) show that a determinant equilibrium necessitates an \active" fiscal policy.1 Indeed, Cochrane(2014) correctly emphasizes that this holds only in the current international monetary system of fiat money and central banks.
    [Show full text]
  • Chinese Divisia Monetary Index and GDP Nowcasting William A. Barnett and Biyan Tang1 October 17, 2015
    Chinese Divisia Monetary Index and GDP Nowcasting William A. Barnett and Biyan Tang1 October 17, 2015 Abstract Since China’s enactment of the Reform and Opening-Up policy in 1978, China has become one of the world’s fastest growing economies, with an annual GDP growth rate exceeding 10% between 1978 and 2008. But in 2015, Chinese GDP grew at 7 %, the lowest rate in five years. Many corporations complain that the borrowing cost of capital is too high. This paper constructs Chinese Divisia monetary aggregates M1 and M2, and, for the first time, constructs the broader Chinese monetary aggregates, M3 and M4. Those broader aggregates have never before been constructed for China, either as simple-sum or Divisia. The results shed light on the current Chinese monetary situation and the increased borrowing cost of money. GDP data are published only quarterly and with a substantial lag, while many monetary and financial decisions are made at a higher frequency. GDP nowcasting can evaluate the current month’s GDP growth rate, given the available economic data up to the point at which the nowcasting is conducted. Therefore, nowcasting GDP has become an increasingly important task for central banks. This paper nowcasts Chinese monthly GDP growth rate using a dynamic factor model, incorporating as indicators the Divisia monetary aggregate indexes, Divisia M1 and M2 along with additional information from a large panel of other relevant time series data. The results show that Divisia monetary aggregates contain more indicator information than the simple sum aggregates, and thereby help the factor model produce the best available nowcasting results.
    [Show full text]
  • Studies in Applied Economics
    SAE./No.91/October 2017 Studies in Applied Economics FINANCIAL FIRM PRODUCTION OF INSIDE MONETARY AND CREDIT CARD SERVICES: AN AGGREGATION THEORETIC APPROACH William A. Barnett and Liting Su Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and Study of Business Enterprise FINANCIAL FIRM PRODUCTION OF INSIDE MONETARY AND CREDIT CARD SERVICES: AN AGGREGATION THEORETIC APPROACH1 William A. Barnett University of Kansas, Lawrence, and Center for Financial Stability, NY City Liting Su University of Kansas, Lawrence, and Center for Financial Stability, NY City October 18, 2017 About the Series The Studies in Applied Economics series is under the general direction of Prof. Steve H. Hanke, Co-Director of the Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health and the Study of Business Enterprise ([email protected]). About the Authors Dr. William A Barnett ([email protected]) is an eminent economic scientist and originator of the Divisia monetary aggregates and the ‘Barnett Critique.” He is the Oswald Distinguished Professor of Macroeconomics at the University of Kansas Department of Economics and Core Faculty Member of the Center for Global and International Studies at the University of Kansas, as well as Senior Fell of the IC2 Institute at the University of Texas at Austin and Fellow of the Institute for Applied Economic, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise at The Johns Hopkins University. He is Founder and Editor of the Cambridge University Press journal Macroeconomic Dynamics, and Founder and Editor of the Emerald Press monograph series, International Symposia in Economic Theory and Econometrics. Dr. Barnett recently founded the Society for Economic Measurement and serves as president.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Monetary Aggregation
    The Theory of Monetary Aggregation Edited by WILLIAM A. BARNETT Washington University St. Louis, Missouri and APOSTOLOS SERLETIS University of Calgary Calgary, Canada CONTENTS vii Contents Preface xxiii W. Erwin Diewert Editors' Introduction xxix William A. Barnett and Apostolos Serletis PART 1: MONETARY INDEX NUMBER THEORY AND THE PRICE OF MONEY SECTION 1.1: EDITORS' OVERVIEW OF PART 1 3 William A. Barnett and Apostolos Serletis SECTION 1.2: DERIVATION OF THE USER COST OF MONETARY SERVICES 6 Chapter 1: The User Cost of Money 6 William A. Barnett 1 Introduction . 6 2 Assumptions and Notation . 7 3 Derivation . 9 SECTION 1.3: THE PRICE OF MONETARY SERVICES AND ITS USE IN MONETARY INDEX NUMBER THEORY 11 Chapter 2: Economic Monetary Aggregates: An Application of Index Number and Aggregation Theory 11 William A. Barnett 1 Introduction . 12 2 Objectives . 13 viii CONTENTS 3 The Consumer's Decision . 16 3.1 Intertemporal Allocation . 16 3.2 The User Cost of Monetary Assets . 20 3.3 Supernumerary Quantities . 20 3.4 Conditional Current Period Allocation . 22 4 Preference Structure over Financial Assets . 23 4.1 Blocking of the Utility Function . 23 4.2 Multi-stage Budgeting . 23 5 Recursive Estimation Approach . 25 6 Passbook Savings . 26 6.1 C.E.S. Specification . 26 6.2 Theoretical Index Number Properties . 28 6.3 Results with Passbook Savings . 29 7 Transaction Balances . 31 7.1 Specification . 31 7.2 Estimates . 33 7.3 Functional Index Numbers . 34 8 Implications of Estimates . 34 9 Empirical Selection of Blocking . 35 9.1 Conditions on Elasticities of Substitution .
    [Show full text]