Reformulating Technical Change and Growth Theory Gary Jefferson Economics Department, Brandeis University

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Reformulating Technical Change and Growth Theory Gary Jefferson Economics Department, Brandeis University Reformulating Technical Change and Growth Theory Gary Jefferson Economics Department, Brandeis University Working Paper Series 2017| 111 ` Reformulating Technical Change and Growth Theory* Gary H. Jefferson [email protected] Brandeis University February 28, 2017 For review and comment only Suggestions will be most welcome Abstract This paper clarifies certain errors and inconsistencies that have become embedded in the conventional neoclassical growth model. The paper demonstrates that characterizing technical change in the Solow model as “purely Harrod-neutral labor augmenting” seriously compromises the role of capital and neoclassical principles in framing the process of economic growth. The basic argument of this paper is that by ignoring the actual elements of the so-called “degeneration” of Hicks-neutral or other capital-labor augmenting technical change, conventional presentations of the Solow model have foreclosed avenues for a deeper understanding of key features of economic growth. The paper develops the paradigm of Hick-Harrod technical change that is consistent with steady state growth under a wide range of values of the substitution elasticity, while also enabling a simplification of conditions required for the steady state. By endogenizing significant aspects of the growth process, the model opens the door to possibilities for a more unified theory of neoclassical growth, endogenous growth, and growth accounting. *The author deeply appreciates the opportunity to have presented portions of this paper in seminars in the Economics Department at Brandeis and at the Department of Economics at the University of Macau. In particular, the author appreciates the helpful suggestions and support of George Hall, as well as suggestions from Michael Coiner, Adam Jaffe, Fung Kwan, James Mirrlees, Dwight Perkins, Tom Rawski, Jian Su, and Tony Yezer. The author alone is responsible for the content of this paper. 1 “There are always aspects of economic life that are left out of any simplified model. There will therefore be problems on which it throws no light at all; worse yet, there may be problems on which it appears to throw light, but on which it actually propagates error.” Robert M. Solow (2000, pp. 1,2) “If I have seen further it is by standing on the shoulders of giants.” Sir Issac Newton (1676) 2 1. Introduction The economics literature is amply sprinkled with congratulatory assessments of the achievements of growth theory. According to Aghion and Howitt (2007, p. 79): Fifty years after its publication, the Solow model remains the unavoidable benchmark in growth economics, the equivalent of what the Modigliani–Miller theorem is to corporate finance, or the Arrow–Debreu model is to microeconomics…. In Chapter 8 of his tome, Introduction to Modern Economic Growth Theory, Acemoglu (2009) variously refers to the Solow model as “the workhorse model of macroeconomics” (p. 26) and “the most important model in macroeconomics” (p. 317). Finally, in their paper, Jones and Romer (2010, p. 225) assert a conclusive consensus framing the canonical growth model: “There is no longer any interesting debate about the features that a model must contain to explain [the Kaldor facts]. These features are embedded in one of the great successes of growth theory in the 1950s and 1960s, the neoclassical growth model.” Specifically, the model seeks to capture within a single economic framework the following six stylized facts of growth summarized by Kaldor (1961): output per capita grows over time; the capital-labor ratio grows over time; capital’s marginal product is roughly constant over time; the capital output ratio is roughly constant over time; capital and labor’s factor income shares are roughly constant over time; and the growth of output per capita differs substantially across countries. While Solow’s model (1956) explains or is consistent with five of these six stylized facts, it does an inadequate job of modeling and explaining the last of the facts; that is the difference in the growth of living standards across countries. As such, it is also largely unable to explain differences in cross-country levels of output per capita (Romer, 1994b). The inability of the neoclassical growth model to embed a parameter or equation to explain these differences has given rise to an abundance of endogenous growth literature, which while rich and diverse has not yet resulted in a single, widely-accepted account of the creation and diffusion of technical change comparable to the consensus enjoyed by Solow’s seminal innovation. In addition, Kaldor’s list of stylized growth facts omits one critical fact of long-run growth: that is, the phenomenon in which the quality of capital progresses over time. That this 3 measure of technical advance should not be included in an economist’s list of stylized facts is not altogether surprising, since the sine qua non of the economist’s measure of quality improvement is the factor’s marginal product. Kaldor correctly notes that over the long-run, capital’s marginal product and its economic return have remained roughly constant. Yet, through the lens of casual observation, capital’s constant economic return does not negate the fact that the machinery and processes driving manufacturing activity, as well as its production outcomes, such as communi- cation and transportation equipment, including air and space travel, are far more accessible, efficient, and inexpensive than they had been in the Stone Age. It is precisely this progressive improvement in the quality of capital, the essence of the Industrial Revolution that has been most responsible for capital deepening and rising living standards. This critical stylized fact of economic growth – quality improvements in capital – is entirely absent from Solow’s model. The ability of the basic neoclassical model to incorporate quality-augmenting technical change for capital has been seriously impaired by a central principle of steady state growth; that is the requirement that in the steady state technical change must take the form of “purely labor – augmenting” Harrod-neutral technical change. This characterization of technical change has its origins in Uzawa’s Growth Theorem (1961) in which he shows that if in the steady state the capital-output ratio is fixed and if output and capital together grow faster than the natural growth of labor, then the “effective” supply of labor must be balanced by labor-augmenting technical change. Hence, technical change in the steady state must be “represented” as being of the purely labor-augmenting variety. As elaborated by Jones and Scrimgeour (2005, p. 4), “As is well- known, in the case of Cobb-Douglas production, capital- and labor-augmenting technical change are equivalent. One sometimes sees the theorem interpreted as saying that technical change must be labor augmenting or the production function must be Cobb-Douglas. This is equivalent to the statement of the (Uzawa) theorem as given.” i.e., that in the steady state technical change must be represented as labor augmenting (italics added). Thus, given that with the Cobb-Douglas function, all the alternative forms of technical change degenerate in the steady state to the labor-augmenting mode and that the Cobb-Douglas function is limited to the restrictive case of a unitary substitution elasticity (i.e., σ = 1), the literature has rendered “purely labor-augmenting” Harrod-neutral technical change as a canonical feature of the neoclassical growth model. Hence, within the environment of a Cobb-Douglas production function with σ = 1, the growth literature seems to have adopted the presumption of 4 technical change equivalency. Many attempt clarifying explanations for this restrictive interpretation of technical change. Grossman et al. (2016) explain: “The ‘problem,’ it would seem, stems from the model’s assumption of an inelastic supply of effective labor that does not adjust to capital deepening over time.” Jones and Scrimgeour (2005) are more explicit about the passive role of the capital stock whose function it is to “inherit” or endogenously submit to the conditions presented to it by exogenous change, which is purely labor-centric. Hence the “workhorse” of neoclassical growth theory and the “workhorse” of production technology, the Cobb-Douglas production function, share an uneasy relationship that has resulted in a deeply unsettling outcome: the basic model of neoclassical growth cannot account for or accommodate to a fundamental and inescapable stylized fact of long-run economic growth – that is, quality improvements in the ever-expanding realm of capital goods. Given this dependence of our basic textbooks account of economic growth as “purely labor augmenting,” it is understandable why both Solow and Acemoglu have raised serious reservations regarding the assumption of the nature of technical change in long-run growth. According to Solow (2000, p. 31,32), “…it is possible to give theoretical reasons why technological progress might be forced to assume the particular form (“called labor-augmenting”) required for the existence of a steady state. They are excessively fancy reasons, not altogether believable.” Acemogulu (2009, pp. 62) simply characterizes the assumption as “At some level…distressing.” Arguably the Solow model co-exists with both a weak-form of the Uzawa Theorem and a strong form. According to the weak form, within the “neighborhood of the equilibrium path,” technical change must be represented as labor-augmenting Harrod-neutral technical change.1 Presumably, provided that it “degenerates” to Harrod-neutral technical change within the steady state, beyond the neighborhood of the steady state, other than a purely labor-augmenting bias is permissible. The strong form of the Uzawa Theorem, that which generally appears in the standard textbook presentation, is that in all phases of neoclassical growth, technical change is to be characterized as of the “purely labor-augmenting” Harrod-neutral variety. A large literature, of course, has developed that focuses on the role of capital in endogenous growth; that is, the role of both physical and human capital as inputs to the process of knowledge production and as outputs of knowledge production.
Recommended publications
  • Theory of Wages
    THE THEORY OF WAGES BY J. R. HICKS, M.A., B.LrTT. Fellow of AU Srnd• CoUeue and Drum'IMTUl ProfeiBQ7' of Political Economv in the Uniwrlity of OxfQ7'd PALGRAVE MACMILLAN 1963 Copyright © J. R. Hicks 1963 First Edition 1932 Second Edition 1963 Softcover reprint of the hardcover 2nd edition 1963 978-0-333-02764-6 MACMILLAN AND COMPANY LIMITED StMartin's Street London WC 2 also Bombay Calcutta Madras Melbourne THE MACMILLAN COMPANY OF CANADA LIMITED Toronto ISBN 978-1-349-00191-0 ISBN 978-1-349-00189-7 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-1-349-00189-7 PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION THIS is only the second (regular) edition of a book which was first published in 1932 and which has been out of print in the United Kingdom for more than twenty years. I let it go out of print because my own views upon its subject had changed so much that I no longer desired to be represented by it. It has, however, been made clear to me that there is still a demand for it; not, I hope, because anyone wants to use the greater part of it as a source of direct instruction, but because there are several parts of it which are still alive in the sense that they provide convenient starting-points for much more modern discussion. References to it have indeed become too frequent for it to be left unavailable. That is the reason why I have finally decided that it ought to appear in a new edition; it also explains why the new edition has had to take so peculiar a form.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring the Bias of Technological Change*
    Measuring the Bias of Technological Change∗ Ulrich Doraszelski† Jordi Jaumandreu‡ University of Pennsylvania and CEPR Boston University and CEPR This version: February 2009 New version coming soon: January 2012. Abstract When technological change occurs, it can increase the productivity of capital, labor, and the other factors of production in equal terms or it can be biased towards a specific factor. Whether technological change favors some factors of production over others is an empirical question that is central to economics. The literatures in industrial organization, productivity, and economic growth rest on very specific assumptions about the bias of technological change. Yet, the evidence is sparse. In this paper we propose a general framework for estimating production functions. Using firm-level panel data, we are able to directly assess the bias of technological change by measuring, at the level of the individual firm, how much of technological change is factor neutral and how much of it is labor augmenting. We further relate the speed and the direction of technological change to firms’ R&D activities. ∗We thank Pol Antràs, Matthias Doepke, Michaela Draganska, Chad Jones, Dale Jorgenson, Larry Katz, Pete Klenow, Zhongjun Qu, Matthias Schündeln, and John Van Reenen for helpful discussions. Jaumandreu aknowledges the support of the SCI-FI GLOW European project. Doraszelski and Jaumandreu gratefully aknowledge financial support .from the National Science Foundation under Grant No. 0924380/0924282. †Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA. E-mail: [email protected]. ‡Department of Economics, Boston University, 270 Bay State Road, Boston, MA 02215, USA. E-mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Marx on Absolute and Relative Wages
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Marx on absolute and relative wages Levrero, Enrico Sergio Roma Tre University, Department of Economics September 2009 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/20976/ MPRA Paper No. 20976, posted 26 Feb 2010 06:51 UTC Marx on absolute and relative wages Enrico Sergio Levrero, Department of Economics, Roma Tre University∗ Introduction 1. The aim of this paper is to clarify some aspects of Marx’s analysis of the determinants of wages and of the peculiarity of labour as a commodity, concentrating upon three related issues. The first is that of Marx’s notion of the subsistence (or natural) wage rate: subsistence wage will be shown to stem, according to Marx, from socially determined conditions of reproduction of an efficient labouring class. The second issue refers to the distinction between the natural and the market wage rate that can be found in Marx, and his critique of Ricardo’s analysis of the determinants of the price of labour. Here the “law of population peculiar to capitalist mode of production” (that is, Marx’s industrial reserve army mechanism) will be considered, both with respect to cyclical fluctuations of wages and to their trend over time. Moreover, a classification of the social and institutional factors affecting the average wage rate will be advanced. Finally, Marx’s analysis of the effects of technical progress on both absolute and relative wages will be considered, also relating it back to the long-standing debate on the Marxian law of the falling rate of profit, and addressing some possible scenarios of the trend of wages and distribution.
    [Show full text]
  • Neutral Technical Progress and the Measure of Value: Along the Kaldor-Kennedy Line
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Neutral Technical Progress and the Measure of Value: along the Kaldor-Kennedy line Up Sira Nukulkit Working Paper No: 2018-05 August 2018 University of Utah Department of Economics 260 Central Campus Dr. Gardner Commons, Rm 4100 Tel: (801) 581-7481 Fax: (801) 585-5649 http://www.econ.utah.edu Neutral technical progress and the measure of value: along the Kaldor-Kennedy line Up Sira Nukulkit Department of Economics University of Utah [email protected] Abstract In this paper, I investigate the question of "the effect of progress upon distribution" based on the analyses of Hicks, Robinson, Harrod, Salter, Kaldor, Samuelson, and Kennedy. The paper aims to address a neglected and controversial theoretical argument on neutral technical progress related to the measure of value that preceded and then continued to the period of the Cambridge Capital Theory Controversy. I focus on Kennedy's writings and his solutions to the complications between the measure of value and technical progress. Important intuitions behind the measure of value are crucial to the formulation of neutral technical progress in both the post-Keynesian and the neoclassical-Keynesian endogenous growth models. The paper concludes with mathematical illustrations of neutral technical progress theories. Keywords: Neutral balanced growth, Capital controversy, Growth and distribution JEL Classification: B22, O33, E12 Acknowledgements: I am grateful to Codrina Rada, Cihan Bilginsoy, Neal Wilson, two anonymous referees, friends and colleagues in Utah for their comments, suggestions and supports. Neutral technical progress and the measure of value: along the Kaldor-Kennedy line In this paper, I investigate the question of "the effect of progress upon distribution" based on the analyses of Hicks, Robinson, Harrod, Salter, Kaldor, Samuelson, and Kennedy.
    [Show full text]
  • John Bates Clark As a Pioneering Neoclassical Economist Thomas C
    “A Certain Rude Honesty”: John Bates Clark as a Pioneering Neoclassical Economist Thomas C. Leonard John Bates Clark (1847–1938), the most eminent American economist of a century ago, was, in his own day, caricatured as an apologist for laissez-faire capitalism (Veblen 1908).1 The caricature has shown stay- ing power, a measure, perhaps, of the relative paucity of scholarship on Clark and his work. Recent Clark research signals a welcome attempt at a more accurate portrait (Morgan 1994; Henry 1995; Persky 2000). But some revisionists would remake Clark the apologist for capital into Clark the Progressive exemplar. Robert Prasch (1998, 2000), for exam- ple, depicts Clark as a Progressive paragon, which groups him with the greatreformers of Progressive-Era politicaleconomy—Social Gospel- ers such as Richard T. Ely and his protégé John R. Commons, labor leg- islation activists such as Clark’s junior colleague Henry Rogers Seager Correspondence may be addressed to Thomas C. Leonard, Department of Economics, Fisher Hall, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544; e-mail: [email protected]. I wish to ac- knowledge the gracious hospitality of Rolf Ohlsson and the Department of Economic History at Lund University, Lund, Sweden. This essay benefited from conversations with Benny Carls- son, the comments of Deirdre McCloskey and Bob Goldfarb, and the thoughtful criticisms of two anonymous referees. 1. All successful caricatures contain an element of truth, and Clark surely invited contro- versy when he argued thatworkers paid theirmarginal productgetwhatthey
    [Show full text]
  • Recent Declines in Labor's Share in Us Income: a Preliminary Neoclassical Account
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RECENT DECLINES IN LABOR'S SHARE IN US INCOME: A PRELIMINARY NEOCLASSICAL ACCOUNT Robert Z. Lawrence Working Paper 21296 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21296 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 June 2015 This paper received funding from the Peterson Institute for International Economics and the MasterCard Center for Inclusive Growth The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2015 by Robert Z. Lawrence. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Recent Declines in Labor's Share in US Income: A Preliminary Neoclassical Account Robert Z. Lawrence NBER Working Paper No. 21296 June 2015 JEL No. D3,D33 ABSTRACT As shown in the 1930s by Hicks and Robinson the elasticity of substitution (σ) is a key parameter that captures whether capital and labor are gross complements or substitutes. Establishing the magnitude of σ is vital, not only for explaining changes in the distribution of income between factors but also for undertaking policy measures to influence it. Several papers have explained the recent decline in labor’s share in income by claiming that σ is greater than one and that there has been capital deepening.
    [Show full text]
  • S New View, Induced Innovations, and Directed Technological Change
    Localised and Biased Technologies: Atkinson and Stiglitz's New View, Induced Innovations, and Directed Technological Change The MIT Faculty has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Acemoglu, Daron. “Localised and Biased Technologies: Atkinson and Stiglitz’s New View, Induced Innovations, and Directed Technological Change.” The Economic Journal 125, no. 583 (March 2015): 443–463. As Published http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/ECOJ.12227 Publisher Wiley Blackwell Version Final published version Citable link http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/113631 Terms of Use Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 International Detailed Terms http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/ The Economic Journal, 125 (March), 443–463. Doi: 10.1111/ecoj.12227 © 2015 The Authors. The Economic Journal published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of Royal Economic Society. Published by John Wiley & Sons, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. LOCALISED AND BIASED TECHNOLOGIES: ATKINSON AND STIGLITZ’S NEW VIEW, INDUCED INNOVATIONS, AND DIRECTED TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE* Daron Acemoglu This study revisits the important ideas proposed by Atkinson and Stiglitz’s seminal 1969 paper on technological change. After linking these ideas to the induced innovation literature of the 1960s and the more recent directed technological change literature, it explains how these three complementary but different approaches are useful in the study of a range of current research areas – though they may also yield different answers to important questions. It concludes by highlighting several important areas where these ideas can be fruitfully applied in future work.
    [Show full text]
  • Corrections to Hicks' Formula and Marshall's Four Rules
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Chirinko, Robert S.; Mallick, Debdulal Working Paper The elasticity of derived demand, factor substitution and product demand: corrections to Hicks' formula and Marshall's four rules CESifo Working Paper, No. 1742 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Chirinko, Robert S.; Mallick, Debdulal (2006) : The elasticity of derived demand, factor substitution and product demand: corrections to Hicks' formula and Marshall's four rules, CESifo Working Paper, No. 1742, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/25787 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring the Bias of Technological Change∗
    Measuring the Bias of Technological Change∗ Ulrich Doraszelski† Jordi Jaumandreu‡ University of Pennsylvania Boston University This draft: March 19, 2015 First draft: December 13, 2008 Abstract Technological change can increase the productivity of the various factors of produc- tion in equal terms or it can be biased towards a specific factor. We directly assess the bias of technological change by measuring, at the level of the individual firm, how much of it is labor augmenting and how much is factor neutral. To do so, we develop a framework for estimating production functions when productivity is multi-dimensional. Using panel data from Spain, we find that technological change is biased, with both its labor-augmenting and its factor-neutral component causing output to grow by about 2% per year. ∗We thank Pol Antr`as, Matthias Doepke, Michaela Draganska, Jos´eCarlos Fari˜nas, Ivan Fernandez-Val, Paul Grieco, Chad Jones, Dale Jorgenson, Larry Katz, Pete Klenow, Jacques Mairesse, Ariel Pakes, Amil Petrin, Zhongjun Qu, Devesh Raval, Juan Sanchis, Matthias Sch¨undeln, and John Van Reenen for helpful discussions and Sterling Horne, Mosha Huang, Thomas O’Malley, and Dan Sacks for research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the National Science Foundation under Grants No. 0924380 and 0924282. An Online Appendix with additional results and technical details is available from the authors upon request. †Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620 Locust Walk, Philadel- phia, PA 19104, USA. E-mail: [email protected]. ‡Department of Economics, Boston University, 270 Bay State Road, Boston, MA 02215, USA. E-mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Algebraic Production Functions and Their Uses Before Cobb-Douglas
    Algebraic Production Functions and Their Uses Before Cobb-Douglas Thomas M. Humphrey undamental to economic analysis is the idea of a production function. It and its allied concept, the utility function, form the twin pillars of F neoclassical economics. Written P = f(L, C, T . .), the production function relates total product P to the labor L, capital C, land T (terrain), and other inputs that combine to produce it. The function expresses a technological relationship. It describes the maximum output obtainable, at the existing state of technological knowledge, from given amounts of factor inputs. Put differently, a production function is simply a set of recipes or techniques for combining inputs to produce output. Only efficient techniques qualify for inclusion in the function, however, namely those yielding maximum output from any given combination of inputs. Production functions apply at the level of the individual firm and the macro economy at large. At the micro level, economists use production functions to generate cost functions and input demand schedules for the firm. The famous profit-maximizing conditions of optimal factor hire derive from such micro- economic functions. At the level of the macro economy, analysts use aggregate production functions to explain the determination of factor income shares and to specify the relative contributions of technological progress and expansion of factor supplies to economic growth. For valuable comments on earlier drafts of this article, the author is indebted to his Richmond Fed colleagues Bob Hetzel, Ned Prescott, Pierre-Daniel Sarte, and Alex Wolman. The views expressed herein are the author’s and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • The Elasticity of Derived Demand, Factor Substitution and Product Demand: Corrections to Hicks’ Formula and Marshall’S Four Rules
    THE ELASTICITY OF DERIVED DEMAND, FACTOR SUBSTITUTION AND PRODUCT DEMAND: CORRECTIONS TO HICKS’ FORMULA AND MARSHALL’S FOUR RULES ROBERT S. CHIRINKO DEBDULAL MALLICK CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1742 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE JUNE 2006 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org • from the CESifo website: www.CESifo-group.deT T CESifo Working Paper No. 1742 THE ELASTICITY OF DERIVED DEMAND, FACTOR SUBSTITUTION AND PRODUCT DEMAND: CORRECTIONS TO HICKS’ FORMULA AND MARSHALL’S FOUR RULES Abstract Nearly 75 years ago, John Hicks introduced and formalized the concept of the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour and its relation to derived demand. The resulting formula has proven very useful in understanding the derived demand for productive factors, the distribution of factor incomes, and Marshall's Four Rules. This short paper notes that a slip occurred in the original derivation, presents a modified formula, and shows that Marshall's First Rule is no longer generally valid. JEL Code: D21, D33, J23, A2. Keywords: derived demand, substitution elasticity, John Hicks. Robert S. Chirinko Debdulal Mallick Department of Economics Department of Economics Emory University Emory University Atlanta, Georgia 30322-2240 Atlanta, Georgia 30322-2240 USA USA [email protected] May 2006 The authors thank Len Carlson, Hugo Mialon, and John van Reenan for helpful comments. All errors, omissions, and conclusions remain the sole responsibility of the authors. The Elasticity Of Derived Demand, Factor Substitution, And Product Demand: Corrections To Hicks' Formula And Marshall's Four Rules Nearly 75 years ago, John Hicks introduced and formalized the concept of the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour.
    [Show full text]
  • Pissarides-Lecture.Pdf
    EQUILIBRIUM IN THE LABOUR MARKET WITH SEARCH FRICTIONS Prize Lecture, December 8, 2010 by CHRISTOPHER A. PISSARIDES1 London School of Economics, UK. Research in the economics of the labour market when there are search frictions started in the 1960s, with influential contributions from George Stigler (1962), John McCall (1970) and the papers collected in Edmund Phelps et al. (1970). Of course, as is common in economics, this was not the first time that economists took seriously the role of search frictions in their research. Insightful discussions of the role of frictions in labour mar- ket equilibrium can be found much earlier, in books by John Hicks (1932) and William Hutt (1939). But it was not until the late 1960s that formal mathematical models of individual behaviour and labour market equilibrium appeared. The development of formal mathematical models with search frictions coincided with the time that I was looking for a topic for my PhD research.2 Two things about search impressed me most. In the Phelps volume, search was claimed as a microfoundation for the natural rate of unemployment, in- troduced just a year or two before by Milton Friedman (1968) and Edmund Phelps (1967), and for the inflation-unemployment trade-off (the Phillips curve). It was also claimed, by Axel Leijonhufvud (1968) in particular, that it could provide a microfoundation for Keynes’s concept of effective demand: the idea was that the job seeker could make her demand for goods effective only after she succeeded in locating a mutually acceptable job match. The articles in the Phelps volume, however, especially those by Phelps (1970) and Dale Mortensen (1970) which had explicit models of the Phillips curve, required a wage distribution to obtain the microfoundations of the Phillips curve.
    [Show full text]