Government-Business Collaboration in Industrial Policy: What Factors Determine Its Success?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Government-Business Collaboration in Industrial Policy: What Factors Determine Its Success? Government-business collaboration in industrial policy: what factors determine its success? Erkki Karo1 and Rainer Kattel2 Ragnar Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Abstract In this paper we discuss the question of what factors in development policy create specific forms of policy capacity and under what circumstances development-oriented complementarities or mismatches between the public and private sectors emerge. We develop the notion of policy capacity into a concept that reflects the variety of modes of making policy that originate from co-evolutionary processes between political and policy ideas, public management and private-sector dynamism. We argue that the interactions between these factors are reflected in three interlinked policy choices, each fundamentally evolutionary in nature: policy choices on understanding the nature and sources of technical change and innovation; policy choices on the ways of financing economic growth, in particular technical change; and third, policy choices on the nature of public management to deliver and implement both previous sets of policy choices. We argue that the way these choices create the division of tasks between public and private sector (e.g., how much and how will government finance and support private sector innovation activities) determines also the eventual embeddedness between state and market actors and types of collaborations feasible (from highly engaged and embedded to more distant and formal/hierarchical) in a particular setting. We illustrate our argument with brief cases studies of economic development in East Asia and Eastern Europe. 1 Erkki Karo is a Research Fellow at Ragnar Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance, Tallinn University of Technology (Estonia). His research concentrates on governance of development and innovation policies in developing and catching-up economies. Contact: [email protected]. 2 Rainer Kattel is a Professor at Ragnar Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance, Tallinn University of Technology (Estonia). He has published on topics bridging the fields of public administration, economics and innovation. His most recent books include: Lember, V., Kattel, R. and Kalvet, T., eds (2013), Public Procurement for Innovation: International Perspectives (Springer); Kattel, R., Burlamaqui, L. and Castro, A.C., eds (2012), Knowledge governance: reasserting the public interest. London (Anthem Press); Kattel, R., Kregel, J. and Reinert, E.S., eds (2009) Ragnar Nurkse: Trade and Development (Anthem Press). Contact: [email protected]. 1 Introduction Debates on technological and economic development have since at least the ‘developmental state’ era in East Asia dealt among other issues with the question of how do develop institutional settings that support economic-development-oriented government-business collaborations (see Johnson 1982; Amsden 1989; Wade 1990; Evans 1995), but also that control for the threats of cronyism and corruption potentially stemming from these same relations (see Gomez 2002; Kang 2002). The studies with a more positive perspective argue that industrial policy of the developmental state was in essence based on a mix of formal and informal collaborative mechanisms between state and business ranging from governments granting policy loans, guaranteeing other loans, procuring industrial products to providing ‘administrative guidance’ in the form of informal counseling, negotiations, commitments etc. These same studies also argued that development-orientated linkages and collaborations grew out of specific forms of bureaucracies and its’ closeness to the business sector (relations of co-dependence, or if looked from the side of public sector, embedded autonomy); or in other words, government-business collaborations could be seen as natural forms of capitalist development. At the same time, many of the mentioned collaborative instruments have temporal limitations: given the political constraints of globalization (i.e., spread of WTO rules) and economic dynamics of globalization (i.e., emergence of global production and innovation networks) many of the traditional instruments of industrial policy are by now outright illegal in the new international policy context (see Wade 2003), or have become ineffective as businesses tend to become less local and more linked to global competitive dynamics (see Ernst 2009; Yeung 2010; 2013). Thus, 2 there is no agreement (and indeed cannot be) on what kind collaborative relationships, and what kind of role of the state, is optimal. Also, especially in the context of developing economies, we have learned that business-government collaborations may very often not lead do development-oriented processes and outcomes. Most economic research explains the success or failures by either good or poor state capacities (see Grindle 1996; Reinert 2007; Acemoglu and Robinson 2012). In sum, both development-oriented and failed settings of industrial policy and government- business collaborations are somehow linked to state capacities. In this paper we see the dynamism of government-business linkages and collaborations as natural outcome of techno-economic developments (see Perez 2002). We try to show that understanding the role of the state in this setting requires a dynamic or evolutionary understanding of how state capacities stem from different institutional settings and from the feedback linkages between these settings and private sector dynamism. In the next section we unpack the concept of state/policy capacity and link it to our approach to development policy debates. Thereafter we propose a co- evolutionary framework to understand policy capacity in the context of development policy. We illustrate our argument with brief discussions of how East Asian and Eastern European have built and transformed its’ development strategies and business-government interactions. Using our framework, we show what kind of policy capacity has been created by, and evolved in, specific co-evolutionary processes; or how political vision, public policies and their management and private- sector dynamism came together in specific contexts. 3 1. Unpacking and contextualizing state and policy capacity To build our analytical perspective, we contend that strictly speaking there is no such thing as policy – policies exist, that is they become reality, only through their implementation. Implementation means concrete people in a concrete organization with their values, legal and power basis, coalitions and interactions with other public- and private sector organizations. These public-sector organizations – the part of the public sector that we can call public management – have their rules how they recruit and promote people, how they understand their own, and others’ performance and accountability, indeed their entire set of tasks. Further, as concrete people, managers and civil servants are the ones implementing policy, and they are the ones having contact with the subjects of a given policy – in case of economic and technology policy, private companies mostly, but also universities, labor unions, industry associations, etc. So, often implementation becomes crucial for what the given policy is and does. Because of learning and feedback mechanisms between civil servants and private-sector actors, entrepreneurs and others actors in the policy-implementation phases, implementation also becomes key for how the given policy is evaluated, and changed if needed. Thus, the realization of policy ideas through implementation is conditioned by different factors from culture to geography to time. We argue that it is impossible to understand state and policy capacity, how it is generated, maintained and changed, without public management. Thus, we use state and policy capacity as a concept as it is used in public administration/management literature, referring to meso- and micro-level processes of public-policy-making, and not in a much wider sense often used in mainstream institutional literature following 4 Douglass North (1990) and others (i.e., looking at policy capacities as factors on the macro-level political deliberations between different actors – executive, legislative etc – where public policy implementation institutions, or bureaucracies, enter only occasionally and as tools of political deliberations). Thus, we distinguish between different concepts that reveal the political, policy and administrative underpinnings of public policies (based on Painter and Pierre 2005: 2-7; also Karo and Kattel 2010): • The broadest concept can be defined as state capacity, that is, achieving appropriate outcomes such as sustainable economic development and welfare (based on values such as legitimacy, accountability, compliance, consent). In essence, development-policy discourse refers to this when discussing the capacity of the government to implement theoretically sound or ideal-type policies (for a broader critical discussion, see Grindle 1996, 2010). It can also be viewed as the legitimacy and extent of government involvement in a policy area, or the legitimacy (external and self-created) to intervene in private-sector activities through different means available to public authorities. From the perspective of public management this concept can be unpacked by distinguishing two subsidiary concepts that are both preconditions for state capacity. • Policy capacity refers to the ability to make intelligent policy choices (based on values such as coherence, credibility, decisiveness, resoluteness).
Recommended publications
  • Ardo Hansson: Working Together for the Good of the EU and Estonia
    Ardo Hansson: Working together for the good of the EU and Estonia Opening speech by Mr Ardo Hansson, Governor of the Bank of Estonia (Eesti Pank), to the Ragnar Nurkse Lecture for the 95th Anniversary of Eesti Pank, Tallinn, 4 November 2014. * * * Professor Balcerowicz, President of the Riigikogu, Chair of the Supervisory Board of Eesti Pank, Excellencies, Ladies and Gentlemen, Thank you for being here today to mark the 95th anniversary of Eesti Pank and to honour Ragnar Nurkse, the world's best-known economist from Estonia to date. Eesti Pank was founded when the Republic of Estonia was only a year old and Ragnar Nurkse was a model eleven-year-old pupil at the Tallinn Cathedral School. In the words of Juhan Kukk, the Minister of Finance of the time, founding Eesti Pank as the issuer of the national currency and tying the currency to gold showed the same great “bravery and belief in national and economic independence” as engaging in the War of Independence did. Ragnar Nurkse started his studies in the University of Tartu, but he soon moved to continue them in the School of Economics of the University of Edinburgh and later in Vienna. He was recognised in his home country for his work, as is shown by the worried letter that Jüri Jaakson, Governor of Eesti Pank at the time, sent him in spring 1938. Nurkse was working in Geneva at the time for the League of Nations, the forerunner of the United Nations. The letter says: “The rise in the cost of living in the past three years has been larger than has been seen in many other countries that compete with us in foreign markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Keegan D. Mcbride EDUCATION RESEARCH AND
    Last Updated: 25.06.2020 Keegan D. McBride [email protected] Linkedin: https://www.linkedin.com/in/keeganmcbride Website: www.keeganmcbride.ee Github: https://github.com/keeganmcbride/ EDUCATION PhD in Public Administration Sep 2017 – June 2020 Tallinn University of Technology, Ragnar Nurkse Department of Innovation and Governance (Tallinn, Estonia) PhD Working Title: “Open Government Data Co-Created Public Services” Thesis available at: https://digikogu.taltech.ee/et/Item/e75082ae-9115-48c0-9526-09466e8a6698 Main Research Interests: Open Data, e-Government, Digitalization, Small States, Complexity, Machine Learning, Data Analytics MSc E-Governance Technologies and Services Sep 2015 – Jun 2017 Cum Laude Tallinn University of Technology, Department of Software Science (Tallinn, Estonia) Thesis Title: “Government as a Platform: Exploiting Open Government Data to Drive Public Service Co-Creation” GPA: 4.7 (5.0 Scale) BA Political Science and International Relations Sep 2011 – Dec 2014 Magna Cum Laude Montana State University, Department of Political Science (Bozeman, Montana, United States) University of Tartu, Baltic Sea Region Studies – For Fall 2013 (Tartu, Estonia) Major GPA: 3.87 (4.0 Scale) International Education KU Leuven,, Public Governance Institute (Leuven, Belgium) March 2018 University of Tartu, Baltic Sea Region Studies (Tartu, Estonia) Fall 2013 RESEARCH AND WORK EXPERIENCE Manager Aug 2019 – Present GovAiLab, Tallinn University of Technology (Tallinn, Estonia) Manager Dec 2018 – Aug 2019 DigiGovLab, Tallinn University
    [Show full text]
  • Kattel Et Al
    3rd International Conference on Public Policy (ICPP3) June 28-30, 2017 – Singapore Panel T06P01 Public Sector Innovation: Organizational and Institutional Trends in the Post-New Public Management Era Innovation Bureaucracy: Does the organization of government matter when promoting innovation? Author(s) Rainer Kattel, Wolfgang Drechsler, Erkki Karo All Ragnar Nurkse School of innovation and Governance, Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia; [email protected] Innovation Bureaucracy: Does the organization of government matter when promoting innovation? Abstract: Current research on how to organize the roles of government in promoting innovation converges around a rather simplified single-organization explanation: support of innovation requires either (Weberian) elite expert organizations or (Schumpeterian) fluid peripheral organizations. We show that looking at history of innovation bureaucracy, a more complex picture emerges: historically we find a rich organizational variety in how governments have organized different innovation promoting activities. We show that historically this organizational variety is, first, driven by highly diverse public-private relationships; second, the variety is of evolutionary nature; third, the diversity of organizations itself is an important factor in success and failure of innovation policies. Combining analytical lenses created by Weber and management literature on capabilities and ambidexterity, we build analytical framework to understand how organizational variety of innovation bureaucracy evolves
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 18.Qxd
    TECHNOLOGY GOVERNANCE Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 18 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] The Economics of Failed, Failing, and Fragile States: Productive Structure as the Missing Link Erik S. Reinert, The Other Canon Foundation & Tallinn University of Technology, Yves Ekoué Amaïzo, UNIDO, Vienna 1 and Rainer Kattel , Tallinn University of Technology Jnauary 2009 1 Contact authors: [email protected], [email protected] and [email protected]. The research for this paper was partially funded by the Estonian Science Foundation, grant no 6703. 1. Introduction: Lost Theoretical Insights from US Secretary of State George Marshall. More than sixty years ago, on 5 June 1947, US Secretary of State George Marshall gave a speech at Harvard University announcing what was to be called the Marshall Plan. The Marshall Plan was probably the most suc- cessful development plan in human history, re-industrializing and industrial- izing countries from Norway and Sweden in the North to Greece and Turkey in the South-East. At about the same time, a similar process based on the same principles re-industrialized and industrialized East Asia, spreading from Japan in the North-East towards the South-West. In this way a cordon san- itaire of wealthy countries was created around the communist world, stemming the communist tide that was rising at the time of Marshall’s speech. One country to benefit from the Marshall-type ideology was South Korea, a country that in 1950 was poorer (GDP per capita estimated at $ 770) than Somalia (GDP per capita estimated at $ 1057; Maddisson 2003), which today is an example of a failed state (see Figure 1 below).
    [Show full text]
  • NSE KARO.Pdf
    This article was downloaded by: [Professor Judith Clifton] On: 18 June 2015, At: 08:40 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Journal of Economic Policy Reform Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/gpre20 Economic development and evolving state capacities in Central and Eastern Europe: can “smart specialization” make a difference? Erkki Karoa & Rainer Kattela a Ragnar Nurkse School of Innovation and Governance, Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn, Estonia Published online: 08 Apr 2015. Click for updates To cite this article: Erkki Karo & Rainer Kattel (2015) Economic development and evolving state capacities in Central and Eastern Europe: can “smart specialization” make a difference?, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, 18:2, 172-187, DOI: 10.1080/17487870.2015.1009068 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/17487870.2015.1009068 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content.
    [Show full text]
  • The Baltic States and the Crisis of 2008-2011 Rainer Kattel and Ringa
    The Baltic States and the Crisis of 2008-2011 Rainer Kattel and Ringa Raudla1 This essay explores how the Baltic republics responded to the crisis of 2008–2011.We argue that while there are significant differences in how the Baltic economies responded to the crisis, these responses not only remain within the neo-liberal policy paradigm characteristic of the region from the early 1990s, but that the crisis radicalised Baltic economies and particularly their fiscal stance. We show that there are a number of unique features in all three Baltic republics’ political economies that made such a radicalisation possible. However, these unique features make it almost impossible for the Baltic experience to be replicable anywhere else in Europe. 1. Introduction Europe, and the rest of the developed world along with it, seems to be mired in a debate over whether austerity brings growth or not. While there seem to be less and less candidates for actual European cases where fiscal retrenchment resulted in economic recovery and growth, the Baltic states persistently attempt to claim that austerity works. All three countries were painfully hit by the global financial crisis in 2008-2009 and topped the global charts in GDP contraction; all three responded to the crisis by adopting a series of austerity measures. In 2010, the Baltic states started to recover and recorded GDP growth between 5.5% and 7.6% in 2011. In the light of such temporal sequences of events, there has been a temptation in the policy circles both inside the Baltic states but also internationally to draw a causal conclusion and to claim that it was the austerity that led to growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Industrial Restructuring and Innovation Policy in Central and Eastern Europe Since 1990.Pdf
    TECHNOLOGY GOVERNANCE Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 23 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] Industrial Restructuring and Innovation Policy in Central and Eastern Europe since 1990 1 Rainer Kattel , Erik S. Reinert and Margit Suurna, Tallinn University of Technology May 2009 1 Corresponding author, email: [email protected]. Research for this study was partially supported by the Estonian Ministry of Education and Research (targeted financing grant no SF0140094s08), the Estonian Ministry of Economic Affairs and Communication (I-PUP grant) and the Estonian Science Foundation (grants no 7577, 6703 and 8097). 1. Introduction Until very recently, economic development in Central and Eastern European (CEE) countries2 has been seen by most analysts in both academic and pol- icy circles as a largely positive if not a very positive story. For example, at the end of 2005, Business Week ran a cover story titled “Central Europe – Rise of a Powerhouse”. It has become commonplace to argue that the suc- cess of CEE development is mainly due to neoliberal economic policies (lib- eralized markets, balanced public budget, price stability, low tax burden, and strongly market oriented reforms in all socio-economic sectors) pursued by these countries since the early 1990s. In other words, CEE countries have been poster countries for Washington Consensus policies. Indeed, as we show below, during the entire decade of the1990s, industrial restruc- turing and embryonic innovation policies in CEE were largely dominated by Washington Consensus thinking.
    [Show full text]
  • Rainz 24.Qxd
    TECHNOLOGY GOVERNANCE Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 24 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] The Copying Paradox: Why Converging Policies but Diverging Capacities for Development in Eastern European Innovation Systems? 1 Erkki Karo and Rainer Kattel August 2009 1 Corresponding author, email: [email protected]. Research for this study was partially supported by the Estonian Ministry of Education and Research (targeted financing grant no SF0140094s08), Estonian Ministry of Economic Affairs and Communication (I-PUP grant) and the Estonian Science Foundation (grants no 7577, 6703 and 7441). Abstract This paper analyses the development of Eastern European innovation systems since the 1990s by looking together at the theoretical and empirical accounts of two discourses that have had a siginificant impact on the development of innovation systems: innova- tion policy and public administration and management. We propose a framework for analysing the development of innovation policies distinguishing between two concepts - policy and administrative capacity – that are necessary for innovation policy making and implementation. Using the framework we show how the Eastern European innova- tion systems have, because of past legacies and international policy transfer, developed a highly specific understanding of innovation policy based on the initial impact of the Washington Consensus policies and later the European Union. We argue that because of the interplay between the principles and policy reccomendations of the two interna- tional discourses we can see the emergence of a ‘copying paradox’ in Eastern European innovation systems: that is, despite the perception of policy convergence, we can wit- ness a divergence in the policy from the intended results, and as a result can talk about limited and de-contextualised policy-making capacities.
    [Show full text]
  • Assessing Divergent Development Trajectories: Schumpeterian Competition, Finance and Financial Governance* Leonardo Burlamaqui** Rainer Kattel***
    Assessing divergent development trajectories: Schumpeterian competition, finance and financial governance* Leonardo Burlamaqui** Rainer Kattel*** Recebido: 29/01/2015 Versão Revisada (entregue): 24/08/2015 Aprovado: 28/08/2015 ABSTRACT The paper offers four propositions for discussion. First, it argues that instead of the often- assumed convergence among nations, history shows us that divergence is a more appropriate way to conceptualize development trajectories; and that this is especially visible in the last century. Secondly, the paper suggests that “convergence” and “catch-up” are, from a Schumpeterian perspective, theoretically inadequate concepts as they frame development narratives similarly to the Rostovian idea of a linear path towards some sort of “development equilibrium”. Thirdly, we outline this schumpeterian framework, centered on the concept of leapfrogging through innovation and finance. The paper concludes by pointing out that macrofinancial coherence and “robust” economic governance (the role of the State playing a key role here) are essential dimensions – although scarcely researched of such alternative framework – for understanding development trajectories. KEYWORDS | Development; Finance; Competition; Leapfrogging; Schumpeter JEL-CODES: O1; O33; O38 * This is a substantial further development of our previous paper, Burlamaqui and Kattel (2014). The authors would like to thank Jan Kregel for comments to an earlier draft of the paper and to the two anonymous reviewers whose sharp questions and suggestions helped us to refine a number of points. The usual disclaimers apply. ** Universidade do Estado do Rio de Janeiro, Rio de Janeiro (RJ), Brasil. E-mail: [email protected] *** Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia. E-mail: [email protected] AT Rev. Bras. Inov., Campinas (SP), 15 (1), p.
    [Show full text]
  • Reinert Kattel 14.Qxd
    TECHNOLOGY GOVERNANCE Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 14 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] European Eastern Enlargement as Europe’s Attempted Economic Suicide?1 2 3 Erik S. Reinert and Rainer Kattel July 2007 1 This article is drawn from our earlier research (Reinert and Kattel 2004; and Reinert 2006). For a full exposition of the history of economic policy, see Reinert 2007. Research for this article has been partially funded by Estonian Science Foundation, Grant No.6703. 2 The Other Canon Foundation (Norway) and Tallinn University of Technology (Estonia). 3 Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia. Corresponding author email: [email protected]. Abstract We argue that the process of European economic integration has made a qualitative shift: from a Listian symmetrical economic integration to an integrative and asymmetrical integration. This shift started in the early 1990s with the integration of the former Soviet economies into the economies of Europe and the world as a whole, reached its climax with the Eastern enlargement of the Union in 2004, and now forms the foun- dation of the renewed Lisbon Strategy. This change is measurably threat- ening European welfare: the economic periphery in the first instance, and potentially the core countries as well. Two parallel processes aggravate this development: the timing of the enlargement at this particular phase of the evolving techno-economic paradigm; and the creation of the European Monetary Union along the so-called Maastricht route towards convergence and fiscal stability.
    [Show full text]
  • Deindustrialisation Reconsidered: Structural Shifts and Sectoral Heterogeneity
    Deindustrialisation reconsidered: Structural shifts and sectoral heterogeneity Fiona Tregenna South African Research Chair in Industrial Development University of Johannesburg Antonio Andreoni Associate Professor of Industrial Economics at University College London Head of Research at the UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose UCL Institute for Innovation and WORKING PAPER Public Purpose WP 2020—06 About the Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose The UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose (IIPP) aims to develop a new framework for creating, nurturing and evaluating public value in order to achieve economic growth that is more innovation-led, inclusive and sustainable. We intend this framework to inform the debate about the direction of economic growth and the use of mission-oriented policies to confront social and technological problems. Our work will feed into innovation and industrial policy, financial reform, institutional change, and sustainable development. A key pillar of IIPP's research is its understanding of markets as outcomes of the interactions between different actors. In this context, public policy should not be seen as simply fixing market failures but also as actively shaping and co-creating markets. Re-focusing and designing public organisations around mission-led, public purpose aims will help tackle the grand challenges facing the 21st century. IIPP is housed in The Bartlett, a leading global Faculty of the Built Environment at University College London (UCL), with its radical thinking about space, design and sustainability. This report can be referenced as follows: Tregenna, F. and Andreoni, A. (2020). Deindustrialisation reconsidered: Structural shifts and sectoral heterogeneity. UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose, Working Paper Series (IIPP WP 2020-06).
    [Show full text]
  • Download Flyer
    ANTHEM PRESS INFORMATION SHEET Ragnar Nurkse Trade and Development Edited by Rainer Kattel, Jan A. Kregel and Erik S. Reinert Pub Date: July 2011 Category: BUSINESS & ECONOMICS / Binding: Paperback Development / General Price: £25 / $40 BISAC code: BUS092000 ISBN: 9780857283979 BIC code: KCM Extent: 504 pages Rights Held: World Size: 229 x 152mm / 9 x 6 Illustrations: 25+ figures and tables Description Reprints Nurkse’s most important works, making them widely available for an audience of economists, policy makers, researchers and students. Ragnar Nurkse (1907-1959) was one of the most important pioneers of development economics, and although his writings have been neglected in recent decades, leading development economists and international organizations such the United Nations are now turning to Nurkse in search for new inspiration, due to the failure of neoclassical economics to adequately explain the experience of poor and developing countries. Until now, however, all Nurkse’s published works were out of print, and the most recent editions stem from the early 1960s. Ragnar Nurkse, Trade and Development reprints Nurkse’s most important works, making them widely available for an audience of economists, policy makers, researchers and students. The works reprinted here include two essays never printed before in this format: Growth in Underdeveloped Countries, (1952) and International Trade Theory and Development Policy (1957), as well as the collected essays from Equilibrium and Growth in the World Economy (1961), and the monograph Problems
    [Show full text]