Microfoundational Programs

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Microfoundational Programs Microfoundational Programs Kevin D. Hoover HOPE Center Working Paper No. 2010-01 May 16, 2010 Duke University Center for the History of Political Economy Microfoundational Programs* Kevin D. Hoover Department of Economics and Department of Philosophy Duke University Box 90097 Durham, NC 27708-0097 Tel. (919) 660-1876 E-mail [email protected] Revised, 16 May 2010 *Prepared for the First International Symposium on the History of Economic Thought: “The Integration of Micro and Macroeconomics from a Historical Perspective,” University of São Paulo, Brazil, 3-5 August 2009. I thank Pedro Garcia Duarte, Gilberto Tadeu Lima, Thomas Mayer, Raul Cristóvão dos Santos, and two anonymous referees for comments on an earlier draft. Abstract of Microfoundational Programs by Kevin D. Hoover Department of Economics and Department of Philosophy Duke University The substantial questions of macroeconomics itself are very old, going back to the origins of economics itself. But professional self-consciousness of the distinction between macroeconomics and microeconomics dates only to the 1930s. The distinction was drawn quite independently of Keynes, yet Keynes’s General Theory led to its widespread adoption. The question of the relationship of microeconomics to macroeconomics encapsulated in the question of whether macroeconomics requires microfoundations was not raised for the first time in the 1960s or ‘70s, as is sometimes thought, but goes back to the very foundations of macroeconomics. There are in fact at least three microfoundational programs: a Marshallian program with its roots directly in Keynes’s own theorizing in the General Theory ; a fixed-price general-equilibrium theory, which includes some work of Patinkin, Clower, and Barro and Grossman; and the more recent representative-agent microfoundations, starting with Lucas and the new classicals in the early 1970s. This paper will document the development of each of these microfoundational programs and their interrelationship, especially in relationship to the programs of general-equilibrium theory and econometrics, whose modern incarnations both date from exactly the same period in the 1930s. JEL Codes: B2, B22, E1 Keywords: microfoundations of macroeconomics, general equilibrium, aggregation, representative agent, fixed-price models, econometric models Hoover, “Microfoundational Programs” 16 July 2009 1. Three Programs At least since the early 1980s with the ascent of the new classical macroeconomics, only macroeconomic models with explicit microfoundations have been regarded as fully acceptable. 1 Typical graduate textbooks – and, increasingly, undergraduate textbooks – open with dynamic optimization problems that are meant to connect the ordinary microeconomics of the consumer and firm to the behavior of aggregate data and to classic macroeconomic concerns such as the business cycle, growth, inflation, and interest rates (see inter alia Romer 1996, Blanchard and Fischer 1989, Barro 1984). How did microfoundations become the sine qua non of sound macroeconomics? There are many ways to tell this story – and, indeed, it has been told before. Here I will tell it from the perspective of the currently dominant practice. This is an exercise in economy rather than in Whig history. The story features neither triumph nor inevitable progress; rather it seeks to know why current practice is the way it is; and, as a result, it omits or minimizes alternative paths, including heterodox programs, such as post-Keynesian macroeconomics, and heterodox criticisms, such as those lodged by the Austrian school, as well as mainly pointing to certain aspects that are already well discussed elsewhere. 2 Lucas’s well-known article “Understanding Business Cycles” (1977) exemplified a widely accepted understanding of the emergence of modern microfoundations. In Lucas’s telling, modern macroeconomics began with John Maynard Keynes’s General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936). Keynes, according to Lucas, rejects a dynamic analysis of business cycles in favor of a static account of output determination (pp. 215-216); he rejects equilibrium theory (p. 219); and individual optimization – at least in the labor market (p. 220). Keynes’s theoretical strategy gives a boost to the nascent program of aggregative econometric modeling: The decision on the part of the most prestigious theorist of his day freed a generation of economists from the discipline imposed by equilibrium theory, and . this freedom was rapidly and fruitfully exploited by macroeconometricians. [p. 220] 1 See Hoover (1988) for an account of the new classical macroeconomics and the role of microfoundations in it. 2 See Harcourt 1977; Horwitz 2000; Weintraub 1977, 1979; Janssen 1993; Hartley 1997. 1 Hoover, “Microfoundational Programs” 16 July 2009 Lucas is, of course, aware that many Keynesian economists did consider the microeconomic basis for various components of the Keynesian model – the consumption function, the money-demand function, the investment function, the Phillips curve, and, in Lucas’s own work with Rapping, the labor-supply function – but these exercises fell short of incorporating the discipline of the optimization problem into the general- equilibrium framework (Lucas 1981, pp. 2-3; Lucas 2004, pp. 20-21; Lucas and Rapping 1969, 1970). The microeconomics of the various functions mainly served to suggest a list of regressors to “explain” their target variables. The regressions themselves were, in effect, merely rules of thumb – decisions rules for particular stable environments. Lucas (1977, pp. 220-221) did not deny that macroeconometric models constructed in this manner could well mimic the behavior of the actual economy, but appealing to the main theme of his famous article “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique” (1976), he argued that the regressions would not isolate the invariants in the economy and that conditional forecasting (policy analysis) requires such invariants. Lucas (1980a, p. 286; 1987, p. 108) was willing to excuse the theoretical choices of Keynesian economists as the product of the exigencies of the Great Depression and the absence of appropriate tools. But economists after the development of the Arrow-Debreu contingent-claims framework can no longer be excused. New classical microfoundations begins with the optimization problems of individual agents. These are incorporated into a dynamic general-equilibrium model based in the contingent-claims framework. Dynamics in an uncertain world requires the formation of expectations. Rather than taking expectations to be exogenously given or based on arbitrary rules of thumb, the rational-expectations hypothesis assumes that self-interested agents will somehow find expectations that are consistent with a true model of the economic process. They may make expectational errors, but they will not make systematic errors. The rational-expectations hypothesis, because it incorporates – implicitly, at least – the whole model of the economy imposes consistency restrictions across the various equations. No part of the system is independent from the other parts. In Lucas’s account, modern microfoundations begins with the new classical revolution of the 1970s, the opening shot of which was the introduction of rational expectations into otherwise standard macromodels (e.g., Lucas 1972b; Sargent and Wallace 1975, 1976). While many economists find the perfectly competitive 2 Hoover, “Microfoundational Programs” 16 July 2009 general-equilibrium model too perfect and seek to capture some features with a Keynesian flavor by introducing realistic barriers to smoothly functioning markets, even these new Keynesians accept the main lines of Lucas’s story and support a nearly identical view of the nature and necessity of microfoundations (see, for example, Blanchard 2000). Call this common view the mainstream narrative. 3 There is – as there usually is in Whig histories – some truth to this story. But in telling a story of linear progress, the mainstream narrative misses a more complicated and more interesting story and misrepresents key elements. The microfoundations of macroeconomics was a problem long before the new classical revolution and long before the term “microfoundations” was current. Indeed, Keynes himself had a distinct approach to microfoundations. As I reconstruct the development of microfoundations, it comprises a prehistory and three distinct microfoundational programs. One program, which I associate with Lawrence Klein was mainly concerned with accessible data. The data was aggregate, and Klein wanted to know that its behavior was compatible with the economic behavior of individuals. Call this the aggregation program . A second program was theoretical. Taking macroeconomics to describe (theoretically or econometrically) robust features of the economy, it asked whether a fully disaggregated, general-equilibrium model could generate those features as a characteristic of the normal operation of the system. Call this the general-equilibrium program . The aggregation and general-equilibrium programs seek non-eliminative microfoundations. If they were perfectly successful, we would nonetheless continue to use macroeconomics. In contrast, Lucas advocates eliminative microfoundations: If these developments succeed, the term “macroeconomics” will simply disappear from use, and the modifer “micro” will become superfluous. We will simply speak, as did Smith, Ricardo, Marshall, and Walras, of economic theory. [Lucas 1987, pp. 107-108] 4 For reasons that will become clearer
Recommended publications
  • The Microeconomic Foundations of Aggregate Production Functions
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF AGGREGATE PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS David Baqaee Emmanuel Farhi Working Paper 25293 http://www.nber.org/papers/w25293 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 2018, Revised November 2019 We thank Maria Voronina for excellent research assistance. We thank Natalie Bau and Elhanan Helpman for useful conversations. This paper was written for the 2018 BBVA lecture of the European Economic Association. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2018 by David Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Microeconomic Foundations of Aggregate Production Functions David Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi NBER Working Paper No. 25293 November 2018, Revised November 2019 JEL No. E0,E1,E25 ABSTRACT Aggregate production functions are reduced-form relationships that emerge endogenously from input-output interactions between heterogeneous producers and factors in general equilibrium. We provide a general methodology for analyzing such aggregate production functions by deriving their first- and second-order properties. Our aggregation formulas provide non- parameteric characterizations of the macro elasticities of substitution between factors and of the macro bias of technical change in terms of micro sufficient statistics.
    [Show full text]
  • Where Modern Macroeconomics Went Wrong
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHERE MODERN MACROECONOMICS WENT WRONG Joseph E. Stiglitz Working Paper 23795 http://www.nber.org/papers/w23795 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 2017, Revised November 2017 I wish to acknowledge the helpful comments of David Vines and Matthieu Teachout, and the editorial assistance of Debarati Ghosh and Eamon Kircher-Allen. Many of the ideas contained here were developed over years of collaboration with a large number of co-authors, including Andy Weiss, Carl Shapiro, Richard Arnott, Martin Guzman, Marcus Miller, Stefano Battiston, Mauro Gallegati, Domenico delli Gatti, Hamid Rashid, and, most importantly, Bruce Greenwald. Discussions of inadequacies of the DSGE model with Anton Korinek, Rob Johnson, Arjun Jaradayev, John Geanakopolis, and Robert Solow have been invaluable. I am also indebted to Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde for his comments on an earlier version of this paper. Financial support was provided by Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET) and Columbia Business School. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2017 by Joseph E. Stiglitz. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Where Modern Macroeconomics Went Wrong Joseph E. Stiglitz NBER Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Reductionism in Economics: Intentionality and Eschatological Justification in the Microfoundations of Macroeconomics A
    Reductionism in Economics 14 May 2015 Title: Reductionism in Economics: Intentionality and Eschatological Justification in the Microfoundations of Macroeconomics Author: Kevin D. Hoover Professor of Economics and Philosophy Department of Economics Department of Philosophy Duke University Contact Information: Department of Economics Duke University P.O. Box 90097 Durham, NC 27708-0097 Telephone: (919) 660-1876 E-mail: [email protected] Acknowledgements: Presented the conference on Reduction and Emergence in the Sciences at the Center for Advanced Studies at LMU (CASLMU), Ludwigs-Maximilliana Universität, Munich 14-16 November 2013. I thank Alex Rosenberg and three anonymous referees for comments on an earlier draft. Abstract: Macroeconomists overwhelmingly believe that macroeconomics requires microfoundations, typically understood as a strong eliminativist reductionism. Microfoundations aims to recover intentionality. In the face of technical and data constraints macroeconomists typically employ a representative-agent model, in which a single agent solves microeconomic optimization problem for the whole economy, and take it to be microfoundationally adequate. The characteristic argument for the representative-agent model holds that the possibility of the sequential elaboration of the model to cover any number of individual agents justifies treating the policy conclusions of the single-agent model as practically relevant. This eschatological justification is examined and rejected. 1 Reductionism in Economics 14 May 2015 I. Reductionism and the Practice of Macroeconomics A value of the philosophy of science for a field such as macroeconomics is that it brings into the light the nature of some of the unreflective practices of macroeconomists and allows them to be held up to critical scrutiny. I would like to consider macroeconomics from a broadly pragmatic perspective.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomics with Heterogeneity: a Practical Guide
    Economic Quarterly—Volume 97, Number 3—Third Quarter 2011—Pages 255–326 Macroeconomics with Heterogeneity: A Practical Guide Fatih Guvenen What is the origin of inequality among men and is it authorized by natural law? —Academy of Dijon, 1754 (Theme for essay competition) he quest for the origins of inequality has kept philosophers and sci- entists occupied for centuries. A central question of interest—also highlighted in Academy of Dijon’s solicitation for its essay competi- T1 tion —is whether inequality is determined solely through a natural process or through the interaction of innate differences with man-made institutions and policies. And, if it is the latter, what is the precise relationship between these origins and socioeconomic policies? While many interesting ideas and hypotheses have been put forward over time, the main impediment to progress came from the difficulty of scientifi- cally testing these hypotheses, which would allow researchers to refine ideas that were deemed promising and discard those that were not. Economists, who grapple with the same questions today, have three important advantages that can allow us to make progress. First, modern quantitative economics pro- vides a wide set of powerful tools, which allow researchers to build “laborato- ries” in which various hypotheses regarding the origins and consequences of For helpful discussions, the author thanks Dean Corbae, Cristina De Nardi, Per Krusell, Serdar Ozkan, and Tony Smith. Special thanks to Andreas Hornstein and Kartik Athreya for detailed comments on the draft. David Wiczer and Cloe Ortiz de Mendivil provided excellent research assistance. The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • Quantitative Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households∗
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 420 January 2009 Quantitative Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households∗ Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Kjetil Storesletten University of Oslo, Frisch Centre (Oslo) and CEPR Giovanni L. Violante New York University, CEPR, and NBER ABSTRACT Macroeconomics is evolving from the study of aggregate dynamics to the study of the dynamics of the entire equilibrium distribution of allocations across individual economic actors. This article reviews the quantitative macroeconomic literature that focuses on household heterogeneity, with a special emphasis on the “standard” incomplete markets model. We organize the vast literature according to three themes that are central to understanding how inequality matters for macroeconomics. First, what are the most important sources of individual risk and cross-sectional heterogeneity? Second, what are individuals’ key channels of insurance? Third, how does idiosyncratic risk interact with aggregate risk? ∗Heathcote: [email protected]; Storesletten: [email protected]; Violante: [email protected]. Heathcote and Violante thank the National Science Foundation (Grant SES-0418029). The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. 1 Introduction The embrace of heterogeneity by macroeconomists is rooted in the “rational expectations rev- olution.” Until the 1970s, the field of macroeconomics concentrated on estimating systems of ad hoc aggregate relationships (“Cowles macroeconometrics”) and largely abstracted from in- dividual behavior and differences across economic agents. Lucas, Sargent, and Wallace, among others, transformed the agenda in macroeconomics, shifting the focus to dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models grounded in optimal individual decision making.
    [Show full text]
  • Agent-Based Computational Economics: Simulation Tools for Heterodox Research
    Agent-Based Computational Economics: Simulation Tools for Heterodox Research *DRAFT* Jonathan F. Cogliano∗ Xiao Jiangy December 12, 2013 Abstract This chapter introduces Agent-Based Modeling (ABM) as a re- search tool that possesses advantages for heterodox research programs. We introduce the approach in four steps. First, we discuss the unique- ness of ABMs, which lies primarily in the flexibility to incorporate vastly heterogeneous agents and to address models with high degrees of freedom. Second, we argue that the flexibility of ABMs makes them an appropriate tool for the questions raised by Classical and (Post- )Keynesian economists. To demonstrate this point we briefly sketch two ABMs, one which constructs an environment that captures the Classical-Marxian processes of gravitation, thereby opening new path- ways in value theory, and the other is a nuanced analysis of Keynesian effective demand problems and the existence of chaotic cycles in a capi- talist economy. The last section revisits the flexibility of ABMs in order to discuss their capability of incorporating dimensions from across the broad variety of heterodox research programs. Keywords: Agent-Based Model; Computational Simulation; Heterodox Economics; Gravitation; Chaotic Cycles. JEL Classification Numbers: B5, C63. ∗[email protected]. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Dickinson College, Althouse 112, P.O. Box 1773, Carlisle, PA 17013. [email protected]. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Denison Univer- sity, Granville, OH 43023. 1 Introduction This chapter introduces Agent-Based Modeling (ABM) as a research tool that possesses advantages for current heterodox research programs. An ABM consists of a computer simulation of many interacting heterogeneous agents that produces an economic phenomena of interest.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Wrong with Representative Agent Equilibrium Models?
    What Is Wrong With Representative Agent Equilibrium Models? Luca Pezzo, Washington University in St. Louis * December 30, 2016 Abstract Despite the ability to match an increasing number of data moments, equilibrium models, employing the widely used Representative Agent simplifying construct, do not properly t the data, why? Using a exible econometric model I provide, as a function of a set of key drivers capturing violations to the models' key assumptions, a joint model-free test for the Representative Agent Equilibrium Models (RAEMs) in the literature as well as the conditional probability of their failures over time. I nd such probabilities to be counter-cyclical, right- skewed and on average high (around 47%). RAEMs are rejected in periods of high illiquidity (market frictions) where the investors' level of disagreement (asymmetric information) is above the median and aggregate expectations are irrationally downward biased. These periods are followed by a decreasing demand to hold the market and, inconsistently with RAEMs predictions, low realized returns. During economic recessions, models are more likely to fail due to market frictions, while in normal times by the asymmetry in information. *Olin Business School, Washington University in St. Louis, Email: [email protected]. I am thankful to my advisor P.H. Dybvig, T.A. Maurer, F. Corielli, O. Kadan, M. Ringgenberg, G.Zhou, A. Manela and my fellow PhD students for helpful comments and discussions. All remaining errors are my own. 1 1 Introduction The Representative Agent and the Rational Expectation paradigm are two pillars of the neo- classical equilibrium models based on micro foundation and individual rationality.
    [Show full text]
  • Quantitative Macroeconomic Models with Heterogeneous Agents
    Quantitative Macroeconomic Models with Heterogeneous Agents Per Krusell∗ Princeton University Anthony A. Smith, Jr.∗ Yale University March 2006 ∗We would like to thank Torsten Persson for valuable comments, Rafael Lopes de Melo for research assistance, and the National Science Foundation for financial support. 1 Introduction The present paper reviews recent research aimed at constructing a theoretical model of the macroeconomy with five key elements: (i) it is based on rational decision making by consumers and firms using standard microeconomic theory beginning with assumptions on preferences and technology; (ii) it is dynamic, so that savings and investment decisions are determined by intertemporal decisions; (iii) it has stochastic aggregate shocks which lead to macroeconomic upswings and downswings; (iv) it considers general equilibrium, so that factor prices and interest rates are endogenous; and (v) it has a heterogeneous population structure where consumers differ in wealth and face idiosyncratic income shocks against which they cannot fully insure. As argued by Lucas (1976), the four first elements seem necessary in any model that aims to evaluate the effects and desirability of economic policy, and they are by now standard and rather broadly accepted as very important if not indispensable. What is new in the present work is the fifth element: heterogeneity. The incorporation of a cross-section of consumers, with an accompanying nontrivial de- termination of the wealth distribution and of individual wealth transitions, is important for
    [Show full text]
  • The Representative Agent in Microeconomics: a Samuelson-Koopmans Thread?
    The Representative Agent in Microeconomics: A Samuelson-Koopmans Thread? Hugo Chu∗ Abstract This article asks whether the representative agent might have emerged as the outcome of transfor- mations that occurred in microeconomics in the 1930s and 1940s, specially, in the subfield of demand theory. To tell this story, I begin with a particular historical interpretation of this subfield, pro- pounded by Wade Hands and Philip Mirowski in the 1990s, known as the Hotelling-Schultz Impasse. Although this impasse was abandoned by the end of the 1930s, the testing of the Symmetry Restric- tions and the validity of the Integrability Conditions continued to draw the attention of different research centers. The Cowles Commission, and its research director, Tjalling Koopmans, played an important role during this stage and, more to the point, in the subsequent emergence of the repre- sentative agent in microeconomics through their approach to aggregation problems. The significance of Paul Samuelson's introduction of homothetic preferences into General Equilibrium theory and its connection to Koopmans's writings during the 1950s is also emphasized. Keywords: Representative Agent, Aggregation Problems, Tjalling Koopmans Resumo Esse trabalho investiga se o agente representativo pode ter surgido como resultado das transforma¸c~oes que ocorreram na microeconomia nos anos de 1930 e 1940. Para construir esta narrativa, eu come¸co com uma interpreta¸c~aoespec´ıficaproposta por Wade Hands e Philip Mirowski nos anos de 1990, conhecido como o Impasse de Hotelling-Schultz. Embora esse impasse tenha sido abandonado na d´ecadade 1930, o teste de restri¸c~aode Slutsky e a validade da condi¸c~aode Integrabilidade contin- uaram a chamar a aten¸c~aode diferentes centros de pesquisas.
    [Show full text]
  • Not Going Away: Representative-Agent Models and Microfoundations in the Making of a New Consensus in Macroeconomics1
    Not Going Away: Representative-Agent Models and Microfoundations in the Making 1 of a New Consensus in Macroeconomics Pedro Garcia Duarte ([email protected]) Department of Economics (FEA-USP), University of São Paulo ABSTRACT: Macroeconomics, or the science of economic aggregate fluctuations, has always been portrayed as a field composed by competing schools and in a somewhat recurrent state of disarray. Nowadays, macroeconomists are proud to announce that a new synthesis is what characterizes their field: there are no longer fights and disarray, but rather convergence and progress. I want to discuss how modern macroeconomists see the emergence of such consensus and, therefore, how they see the history of their sub-discipline. In particular, I shall stress the role played in the making of such consensus by both the hypothesis of a representative agent and by a particular understanding of the microfoundations that macroeconomics need. I then use De Vroey‘s (2004) Marshall-Walras divide to analyze further the new neoclassical synthesis. 1 Very first draft prepared for the First International Symposium on the History of Economics (ISHET): ―The Integration of Micro and Macroeconomics from a Historical Perspective‖, University of São Paulo, São Paulo, SP, 3- 5 August 2009. Please, do not circulate or quote without permission. Comments are welcome. P. G. Duarte 1 Not Going Away: Representative-Agent Models and Microfoundations in the Making of a New Consensus in Macroeconomics Macroeconomics is now, as it has always been, the subject of intense controversy. Robert Solow (1979, 340) When the outside world tells us that no two economists ever agree on anything, it is talking about macroeconomics.
    [Show full text]
  • Agent-Based Computational Economics (Ace) and African Modelling: Perspectives and Challenges
    AGENT-BASED COMPUTATIONAL ECONOMICS (ACE) AND AFRICAN MODELLING: PERSPECTIVES AND CHALLENGES GODWIN CHUKWUDUM NWAOBI PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS/RESEARCH DIRECTOR [email protected] +234-8035925021 www.quanterb.org QUANTITATIVE ECONOMIC RESEARCH BUREAU PLOT 107 OKIGWE ROAD P.O. BOX 7173, ABA. ABIA STATE NIGERIA WEST AFRICA [email protected] 1 ABSTRACT In recent years, the government, of African Countries has assumed major responsibilities for economic reforms and growth. In attempting to describe their economies, economists (policymakers) in many African Countries have applied certain models that are by now widely known: Linear programming models, input-output models, macro-econometric models, vector auto regression models and computable general equilibrium models. Unfortunately, economies are complicated systems encompassing micro behaviors, interaction patterns and global regularities. Whether partial or general in scope, studies of economic systems must consider how to handle difficult real-world aspects such as asymmetric information, imperfect competition, strategic interaction, collective learning and multiple equilibria possibility. This paper therefore argues for the adoption of alternative modeling (bottom-up culture-dish) approach known as AGENT-BASED Computational Economics (ACE), which is the computational study of African economies modeled as evolving systems of autonomous interacting agents. However, the software bottleneck (what rules to write for our agents) remains the primary challenge ahead. KEY WORDS: artificial intelligence,
    [Show full text]
  • Part 1 Microfoundations of Macroeconomics
    Gillman-2100090 book August 23, 2010 9:4 1 PART 1 MICROFOUNDATIONS OF MACROECONOMICS 1 Overview of the book 3 Gillman-2100090 book August 23, 2010 9:4 2 Thus the history of the individual firm cannot be made in the history of an industry any more than the history of an individual man can be made into the history of mankind. And yet the history of mankind is the outcome of the history of individuals and the aggregate production for a general market is the outcome of the motives which induce individual producers to expand or contract their production. It is just here that our device of a representative firm comes to aid. (Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, 8th Edition pp. 380–381) ‘Thus the representative firm is in a sense an average firm.’ (Ibid., p. 265). Gillman-2100090 book August 23, 2010 9:4 3 CHAPTER 1 Overview of the book 1.1 Introduction This chapter provides an overview of the book within different dimensions. First it moti- vates how it is an extension of the microfoundation approach of using general equilibrium theory for macroeconomics. It highlights new elements of the text in terms of providing aggregate demand and supply analysis in the dynamic context, and in explaining business cycles with basic comparative statics of goods and time endowment changes. The role of human capital in the text is explained and then the text is outlined in terms of fundamental margins of economic activity. Concepts of permanent income and wealth are traced across the chapters of the book, in a section providing a summary mathemat- ical reference section.
    [Show full text]